Combining Real Options and game theory in incomplete markets.

Similar documents
The investment game in incomplete markets.

The investment game in incomplete markets

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets

The Investment Game under Uncertainty: An Analysis of Equilibrium Values in the Presence of First or Second Mover Advantage.

In reality; some cases of prisoner s dilemma end in cooperation. Game Theory Dr. F. Fatemi Page 219

Valuation of Exit Strategy under Decaying Abandonment Value

Real Options and Signaling in Strategic Investment Games

Real Option Analysis for Adjacent Gas Producers to Choose Optimal Operating Strategy, such as Gas Plant Size, Leasing rate, and Entry Point

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005

Incorporating Managerial Cash-Flow Estimates and Risk Aversion to Value Real Options Projects. The Fields Institute for Mathematical Sciences

Homework Assignments

Economics 171: Final Exam

ECE 586BH: Problem Set 5: Problems and Solutions Multistage games, including repeated games, with observed moves

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Exercises Solutions: Game Theory

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 2. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

Introduction to Real Options

Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 5: Repeated Games

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Prospect Theory, Partial Liquidation and the Disposition Effect

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

Capacity Expansion Games with Application to Competition in Power May 19, Generation 2017 Investmen 1 / 24

Lattice (Binomial Trees) Version 1.2

Prisoner s dilemma with T = 1

Fixed Income Financial Engineering

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Pricing Options with Binomial Trees

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

δ j 1 (S j S j 1 ) (2.3) j=1

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1

Game Theory: Normal Form Games

Université du Maine Théorie des Jeux Yves Zenou Correction de l examen du 16 décembre 2013 (1 heure 30)

Noncooperative Oligopoly

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Not 0,4 2,1. i. Show there is a perfect Bayesian equilibrium where player A chooses to play, player A chooses L, and player B chooses L.

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Replication strategies of derivatives under proportional transaction costs - An extension to the Boyle and Vorst model.

Futures and Forward Markets

S 2,2-1, x c C x r, 1 0,0

Calibration Lecture 4: LSV and Model Uncertainty

Early PD experiments

1 Solutions to Homework 4

B8.3 Week 2 summary 2018

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma

The Multistep Binomial Model

Simon Fraser University Spring 2014

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Martingale Pricing Applied to Dynamic Portfolio Optimization and Real Options

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

Put-Call Parity. Put-Call Parity. P = S + V p V c. P = S + max{e S, 0} max{s E, 0} P = S + E S = E P = S S + E = E P = E. S + V p V c = (1/(1+r) t )E

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers

Warm Up Finitely Repeated Games Infinitely Repeated Games Bayesian Games. Repeated Games

Binomial Option Pricing

Game Theory - Lecture #8

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

A brief introduction to evolutionary game theory

preferences of the individual players over these possible outcomes, typically measured by a utility or payoff function.

VII. Incomplete Markets. Tomas Björk

B6302 B7302 Sample Placement Exam Answer Sheet (answers are indicated in bold)

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers

Lecture 6 Dynamic games with imperfect information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

non linear Payoffs Markus K. Brunnermeier

CS 798: Homework Assignment 4 (Game Theory)

1. In this exercise, we can easily employ the equations (13.66) (13.70), (13.79) (13.80) and

Answer Key: Problem Set 4

Generalized Multi-Factor Commodity Spot Price Modeling through Dynamic Cournot Resource Extraction Models

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 3

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS

The Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model

Optimization Models in Financial Mathematics

Introductory Microeconomics

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology

REAL OPTIONS ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Advanced Microeconomics

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

2.1 Mean-variance Analysis: Single-period Model

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY HANDOUT ON PERFECT BAYESIAN EQUILIBRIUM- III Semi-Separating equilibrium

Time-Consistent and Market-Consistent Actuarial Valuations

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Transcription:

Combining Real Options and game theory in incomplete markets. M. R. Grasselli Mathematics and Statistics McMaster University Further Developments in Quantitative Finance Edinburgh, July 11, 2007

Successes and Limitations of Real Options Real options accurately describe the value of flexibility in decision making under uncertainty.

Successes and Limitations of Real Options Real options accurately describe the value of flexibility in decision making under uncertainty. According to a recent survey, 26% of CFOs in North America always or almost always consider the value of real options in projects.

Successes and Limitations of Real Options Real options accurately describe the value of flexibility in decision making under uncertainty. According to a recent survey, 26% of CFOs in North America always or almost always consider the value of real options in projects. This is due to familiarity with the option valuation paradigm in financial markets and its lessons.

Successes and Limitations of Real Options Real options accurately describe the value of flexibility in decision making under uncertainty. According to a recent survey, 26% of CFOs in North America always or almost always consider the value of real options in projects. This is due to familiarity with the option valuation paradigm in financial markets and its lessons. But most of the literature in Real Options is based on different combinations of the following unrealistic assumptions: (1) infinite time horizon, (2) perfectly correlated spanning asset, (3) absence of competition.

Successes and Limitations of Real Options Real options accurately describe the value of flexibility in decision making under uncertainty. According to a recent survey, 26% of CFOs in North America always or almost always consider the value of real options in projects. This is due to familiarity with the option valuation paradigm in financial markets and its lessons. But most of the literature in Real Options is based on different combinations of the following unrealistic assumptions: (1) infinite time horizon, (2) perfectly correlated spanning asset, (3) absence of competition. Though some problems have long time horizons (30 years or more), most strategic decisions involve much shorter times.

Successes and Limitations of Real Options Real options accurately describe the value of flexibility in decision making under uncertainty. According to a recent survey, 26% of CFOs in North America always or almost always consider the value of real options in projects. This is due to familiarity with the option valuation paradigm in financial markets and its lessons. But most of the literature in Real Options is based on different combinations of the following unrealistic assumptions: (1) infinite time horizon, (2) perfectly correlated spanning asset, (3) absence of competition. Though some problems have long time horizons (30 years or more), most strategic decisions involve much shorter times. The vast majority of underlying projects are not perfectly correlated to any asset traded in financial markets.

Successes and Limitations of Real Options Real options accurately describe the value of flexibility in decision making under uncertainty. According to a recent survey, 26% of CFOs in North America always or almost always consider the value of real options in projects. This is due to familiarity with the option valuation paradigm in financial markets and its lessons. But most of the literature in Real Options is based on different combinations of the following unrealistic assumptions: (1) infinite time horizon, (2) perfectly correlated spanning asset, (3) absence of competition. Though some problems have long time horizons (30 years or more), most strategic decisions involve much shorter times. The vast majority of underlying projects are not perfectly correlated to any asset traded in financial markets. In general, competition erodes the value of flexibility.

Alternatives The use of well known numerical methods (e.g finite differences) allows for finite time horizons.

Alternatives The use of well known numerical methods (e.g finite differences) allows for finite time horizons. As for the spanning asset assumption, the absence of perfect correlation with a financial asset leads to an incomplete market.

Alternatives The use of well known numerical methods (e.g finite differences) allows for finite time horizons. As for the spanning asset assumption, the absence of perfect correlation with a financial asset leads to an incomplete market. Replication arguments can no longer be applied to value managerial opportunities.

Alternatives The use of well known numerical methods (e.g finite differences) allows for finite time horizons. As for the spanning asset assumption, the absence of perfect correlation with a financial asset leads to an incomplete market. Replication arguments can no longer be applied to value managerial opportunities. The most widespread alternative to replication in the decision-making literature is to introduce a risk-adjusted rate of return, which replaces the risk free rate, and use dynamic programming.

Alternatives The use of well known numerical methods (e.g finite differences) allows for finite time horizons. As for the spanning asset assumption, the absence of perfect correlation with a financial asset leads to an incomplete market. Replication arguments can no longer be applied to value managerial opportunities. The most widespread alternative to replication in the decision-making literature is to introduce a risk-adjusted rate of return, which replaces the risk free rate, and use dynamic programming. This approach lacks the intuitive understanding of opportunities as options.

Alternatives The use of well known numerical methods (e.g finite differences) allows for finite time horizons. As for the spanning asset assumption, the absence of perfect correlation with a financial asset leads to an incomplete market. Replication arguments can no longer be applied to value managerial opportunities. The most widespread alternative to replication in the decision-making literature is to introduce a risk-adjusted rate of return, which replaces the risk free rate, and use dynamic programming. This approach lacks the intuitive understanding of opportunities as options. Finally, competition is generally introduced using game theory.

Alternatives The use of well known numerical methods (e.g finite differences) allows for finite time horizons. As for the spanning asset assumption, the absence of perfect correlation with a financial asset leads to an incomplete market. Replication arguments can no longer be applied to value managerial opportunities. The most widespread alternative to replication in the decision-making literature is to introduce a risk-adjusted rate of return, which replaces the risk free rate, and use dynamic programming. This approach lacks the intuitive understanding of opportunities as options. Finally, competition is generally introduced using game theory. Surprisingly, game theory is almost exclusively combined with real options under the hypothesis of risk-neutrality!

Related literature Real options and games: Smit and Ankum (1993), Dixit and Pindyck (1994), Grenadier (1996), Kulatikaka and Perotti (1998), Smit and Trigeorgis (2001), Imai and Watanabe (2006).

Related literature Real options and games: Smit and Ankum (1993), Dixit and Pindyck (1994), Grenadier (1996), Kulatikaka and Perotti (1998), Smit and Trigeorgis (2001), Imai and Watanabe (2006). Indifference pricing: Henderson and Hobson (2001), Musiela and Zariphopoulou (2004), Rogers and Scheinkman (2007).

A one period investment model Consider a two factor market where the discounted prices for the project V and a correlated traded asset S follow: (us 0, hv 0 ) with probability p 1, (us (S T, V T ) = 0, lv 0 ) with probability p 2, (1) (ds 0, hv 0 ) with probability p 3, (ds 0, lv 0 ) with probability p 4, where 0 < d < 1 < u and 0 < l < 1 < h, for positive initial values S 0, V 0 and historical probabilities p 1, p 2, p 3, p 4.

A one period investment model Consider a two factor market where the discounted prices for the project V and a correlated traded asset S follow: (us 0, hv 0 ) with probability p 1, (us (S T, V T ) = 0, lv 0 ) with probability p 2, (1) (ds 0, hv 0 ) with probability p 3, (ds 0, lv 0 ) with probability p 4, where 0 < d < 1 < u and 0 < l < 1 < h, for positive initial values S 0, V 0 and historical probabilities p 1, p 2, p 3, p 4. Let the risk preferences be specified through an exponential utility U(x) = e γx.

A one period investment model Consider a two factor market where the discounted prices for the project V and a correlated traded asset S follow: (us 0, hv 0 ) with probability p 1, (us (S T, V T ) = 0, lv 0 ) with probability p 2, (1) (ds 0, hv 0 ) with probability p 3, (ds 0, lv 0 ) with probability p 4, where 0 < d < 1 < u and 0 < l < 1 < h, for positive initial values S 0, V 0 and historical probabilities p 1, p 2, p 3, p 4. Let the risk preferences be specified through an exponential utility U(x) = e γx. An investment opportunity is model as an option with discounted payoff C t = (V e rt I ) +, for t = 0, T.

European Indifference Price The indifference price for the option to invest in the final period as the amount π that solves the equation max E[U(x +H(S T S 0 )] = max E[U(x π+h(s T S 0 )] (2) H H

European Indifference Price The indifference price for the option to invest in the final period as the amount π that solves the equation max E[U(x +H(S T S 0 )] = max E[U(x π+h(s T S 0 )] (2) H H Denoting the two possible pay-offs at the terminal time by C h and C l, the European indifference price is explicitly given by π = g(c h, C l ) (3) where, for fixed parameters (u, d, p 1, p 2, p 3, p 4 ) the function g : R R R is defined as g(x 1, x 2 ) = q ( ) γ log p 1 + p 2 p 1 e γx 1 + p2 e γx (4) 2 + 1 q ( ) p 3 + p 4 log γ p 3 e γx 1 + p4 e γx, 2 with q = 1 d u d.

Early exercise When investment at time t = 0 is allowed, it is clear that immediate exercise of this option will occur whenever its exercise value (V 0 I ) + is larger than its continuation value π C.

Early exercise When investment at time t = 0 is allowed, it is clear that immediate exercise of this option will occur whenever its exercise value (V 0 I ) + is larger than its continuation value π C. That is, from the point of view of this agent, the value at time zero for the opportunity to invest in the project either at t = 0 or t = T is given by C 0 = max{(v 0 I ) +, g((hv 0 e rt I ) +, (lv 0 e rt I ) + )}.

A multi period model Consider now a continuous-time two factor market of the form ds t = (µ 1 r)s t dt + σ 1 S t dw dv t = (µ 2 r)v t dt + σ 2 V t (ρdw + 1 ρ 2 dz).

A multi period model Consider now a continuous-time two factor market of the form ds t = (µ 1 r)s t dt + σ 1 S t dw dv t = (µ 2 r)v t dt + σ 2 V t (ρdw + 1 ρ 2 dz). We want to approximate this market by a discrete time processes (S n, V n ) following the one period dynamics (1).

A multi period model Consider now a continuous-time two factor market of the form ds t = (µ 1 r)s t dt + σ 1 S t dw dv t = (µ 2 r)v t dt + σ 2 V t (ρdw + 1 ρ 2 dz). We want to approximate this market by a discrete time processes (S n, V n ) following the one period dynamics (1). This leads to the following choice of parameters: u = e σ 1 t, h = e σ 2 t, d = e σ 1 t, l = e σ 2 t, p 1 + p 2 = e(µ 1 r) t d, p 1 + p 3 = e(µ 2 r) t l u d h l ρσ 1 σ 2 t = (u d)(h l)[p 1 p 4 p 2 p 3 ], supplemented by the condition p 1 + p 2 + p 3 + p 4 = 1.

Numerical Experiments - Act I We now investigate how the exercise threshold varies with the different model parameters.

Numerical Experiments - Act I We now investigate how the exercise threshold varies with the different model parameters. The fixed parameters are I = 1, r = 0.04, T = 10 µ 1 = 0.115, σ 1 = 0.25, S 0 = 1 σ 2 = 0.2, V 0 = 1

Numerical Experiments - Act I We now investigate how the exercise threshold varies with the different model parameters. The fixed parameters are I = 1, r = 0.04, T = 10 µ 1 = 0.115, σ 1 = 0.25, S 0 = 1 σ 2 = 0.2, V 0 = 1 Given these parameters, the CAPM equilibrium expected rate of return on the project for a given correlation ρ is ( ) µ1 r µ 2 = r + ρ σ 2. (5) σ 1

Numerical Experiments - Act I We now investigate how the exercise threshold varies with the different model parameters. The fixed parameters are I = 1, r = 0.04, T = 10 µ 1 = 0.115, σ 1 = 0.25, S 0 = 1 σ 2 = 0.2, V 0 = 1 Given these parameters, the CAPM equilibrium expected rate of return on the project for a given correlation ρ is ( ) µ1 r µ 2 = r + ρ σ 2. (5) The difference δ = µ 2 µ 2 is the below equilibrium rate of return shortfall and plays the role of a dividend rate paid by the project, which we fix at δ = 0.04. σ 1

Known Thresholds In the limit ρ ±1 (complete market), the closed form expression for the investment threshold obtained in the case T = gives V DP = 2.

Known Thresholds In the limit ρ ±1 (complete market), the closed form expression for the investment threshold obtained in the case T = gives V DP = 2. This should be contrasted with the NPV criterion (that is, invest whenever the net present value for the project is positive) which in this case gives V NPV = 1.

Known Thresholds In the limit ρ ±1 (complete market), the closed form expression for the investment threshold obtained in the case T = gives V DP = 2. This should be contrasted with the NPV criterion (that is, invest whenever the net present value for the project is positive) which in this case gives V NPV = 1. The limit γ 0 in our model corresponds to the McDonald and Siegel (1986) threshold, obtained by assuming that investors are averse to market risk but neutral towards idiosyncratic risk.

Known Thresholds In the limit ρ ±1 (complete market), the closed form expression for the investment threshold obtained in the case T = gives V DP = 2. This should be contrasted with the NPV criterion (that is, invest whenever the net present value for the project is positive) which in this case gives V NPV = 1. The limit γ 0 in our model corresponds to the McDonald and Siegel (1986) threshold, obtained by assuming that investors are averse to market risk but neutral towards idiosyncratic risk. For our parameters, the adjustment to market risks is accounted by CAPM and this threshold coincides with V DP = 2

Dependence on Correlation and Risk Aversion 2 2 1.9!=0.5 1.9 "=0!=2 1.8!=8 1.8 "=0.6 "=0.9 1.7 1.7 threshold 1.6 1.5 1.4 1.3 1.2 1.1 1!1!0.5 0 0.5 1 correlation threshold 1.6 1.5 1.4 1.3 1.2 1.1 1 0 2 4 6 8 10 risk aversion Figure: Exercise threshold as a function of correlation and risk aversion.

Dependence on Volatility and Dividend Rate 4.5 4.5 4 3.5!=0!=0.6!=0.9 4 3.5!=0!=0.6!=0.9 threshold 3 2.5 threshold 3 2.5 2 2 1.5 1.5 1 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 volatility 1 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 " Figure: Exercise threshold as a function of volatility and dividend rate.

Dependence on Time to Maturity 2 Low risk aversion!=0.5 1.8 Higher risk aversion!=4 1.9 1.7 1.8 1.7 1.6 1.6 1.5 threshold 1.5 1.4 "=0 "=0.6 threshold 1.4 1.3 1.3 1.2 "=0.9 1.2 "=0 "=0.6 1.1 1.1 "=0.9 1 0 10 20 30 40 50 time to maturity 1 0 10 20 30 40 50 time to maturity Figure: Exercise threshold as a function of time to maturity.

Values for the Option to Invest 1 0.9 0.8 0.7 (V!I) +!=0!=0.99 0.6 option value 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 2 V Figure: Option value as a function of underlying project value. The threshold for ρ = 0 is 1.1972 and the one for ρ = 0.99 is 1.7507.

Suspension, Reactivation and Scrapping Let us denote the value of an idle project by F 0, an active project by F 1 and a mothballed project by F M.

Suspension, Reactivation and Scrapping Let us denote the value of an idle project by F 0, an active project by F 1 and a mothballed project by F M. Then F 0 = option to invest at cost I F 1 = cash flow + option to mothball at cost E M F M = cash flow + option to reactivate at cost R + option to scrap at cost E S

Suspension, Reactivation and Scrapping Let us denote the value of an idle project by F 0, an active project by F 1 and a mothballed project by F M. Then F 0 = option to invest at cost I F 1 = cash flow + option to mothball at cost E M F M = cash flow + option to reactivate at cost R + option to scrap at cost E S We obtain its value on the grid using the recursion formula F k (i, j) = max{continuation value, possible exercise values}.

Suspension, Reactivation and Scrapping Let us denote the value of an idle project by F 0, an active project by F 1 and a mothballed project by F M. Then F 0 = option to invest at cost I F 1 = cash flow + option to mothball at cost E M F M = cash flow + option to reactivate at cost R + option to scrap at cost E S We obtain its value on the grid using the recursion formula F k (i, j) = max{continuation value, possible exercise values}. As before, the decisions to invest, mothball, reactivate and scrap are triggered by the price thresholds P S < P M < P R < P H.

Numerical Experiments - Act II We calculate these thresholds by keeping track of three simultaneous grids of option values.

Numerical Experiments - Act II We calculate these thresholds by keeping track of three simultaneous grids of option values. The fixed parameters now are µ 1 = 0.12, σ 1 = 0.2, S 0 = 1 σ 2 = 0.2, V 0 = 1 r = 0.05, δ = 0.05, T = 30 I = 2, R = 0.79, E M = E S = 0 C = 1, m = 0.01 ρ = 0.9, γ = 0.1

Dependence on Mothballing Sunk Cost 1.8 Thresholds Vs. Mothballing Sunk Cost, Increment Size: 0.1 1.6 1.4 1.2 Thresholds 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 Mothballing Sunk Cost

Dependence on Mothballing Running Cost 2.5 Thresholds Vs Mothballing Running Cost, Increment Size: 0.1 2 1.5 Thresholds 1 0.5 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 2 Mothballing Running Cost

Dependence on Correlation 1.6 Thresholds Vs Correlation, Increment Size: 0.1 1.4 1.2 Thresholds 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2!1!0.8!0.6!0.4!0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1

Dependence on Risk Aversion 5 Thresholds Vs Risk Aversion, Increment Size: 0.5, Rho fixed at 0.6 4.5 4 3.5 3 Thresholds 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0

Combining options and games For a systematic application of both real options and game theory in strategic decisions, we consider the following rules:

Combining options and games For a systematic application of both real options and game theory in strategic decisions, we consider the following rules: 1. Outcomes of a given game that involve a wait and see strategy should be calculated by option value arguments.

Combining options and games For a systematic application of both real options and game theory in strategic decisions, we consider the following rules: 1. Outcomes of a given game that involve a wait and see strategy should be calculated by option value arguments. 2. Once the solution for a given game is found on a decision node, its value becomes the pay-off for an option at that node.

Combining options and games For a systematic application of both real options and game theory in strategic decisions, we consider the following rules: 1. Outcomes of a given game that involve a wait and see strategy should be calculated by option value arguments. 2. Once the solution for a given game is found on a decision node, its value becomes the pay-off for an option at that node. In this way, option valuation and game theoretical equilibrium become dynamically related in a decision tree.

Symmetric Innovation Race - SIR (Smit/Trigeorgis 04) Consider an innovation race for a new electronic technology between firms A and B.

Symmetric Innovation Race - SIR (Smit/Trigeorgis 04) Consider an innovation race for a new electronic technology between firms A and B. Suppose that the total net present value from immediate investment is $26 million.

Symmetric Innovation Race - SIR (Smit/Trigeorgis 04) Consider an innovation race for a new electronic technology between firms A and B. Suppose that the total net present value from immediate investment is $26 million. If both firms invest, we assume that they share this value equally, whereas if only one firm invests immediately, it receives the total market value, while the other receives nothing.

Symmetric Innovation Race - SIR (Smit/Trigeorgis 04) Consider an innovation race for a new electronic technology between firms A and B. Suppose that the total net present value from immediate investment is $26 million. If both firms invest, we assume that they share this value equally, whereas if only one firm invests immediately, it receives the total market value, while the other receives nothing. Suppose that, in a complete market, the value of option to invest is $42 million.

Symmetric Innovation Race - SIR (Smit/Trigeorgis 04) Consider an innovation race for a new electronic technology between firms A and B. Suppose that the total net present value from immediate investment is $26 million. If both firms invest, we assume that they share this value equally, whereas if only one firm invests immediately, it receives the total market value, while the other receives nothing. Suppose that, in a complete market, the value of option to invest is $42 million. Since this is larger than the NPV, a monopolistic investor would wait, therefore owning an option worth $42 million.

Symmetric Innovation Race - SIR (Smit/Trigeorgis 04) Consider an innovation race for a new electronic technology between firms A and B. Suppose that the total net present value from immediate investment is $26 million. If both firms invest, we assume that they share this value equally, whereas if only one firm invests immediately, it receives the total market value, while the other receives nothing. Suppose that, in a complete market, the value of option to invest is $42 million. Since this is larger than the NPV, a monopolistic investor would wait, therefore owning an option worth $42 million. Therefore, if both firms wait, they each own an option worth $21 million.

Solution of the SIR game This symmetric innovation race can therefore be summarize as A B Invest Wait Invest (13,13) (26,0) Wait (0,26) (21,21)

Solution of the SIR game This symmetric innovation race can therefore be summarize as A B Invest Wait Invest (13,13) (26,0) Wait (0,26) (21,21) This is the business analogue of the Prisoner s dilemma, since the second row and second column are strictly dominated respectively by the first row and first column.

Solution of the SIR game This symmetric innovation race can therefore be summarize as A B Invest Wait Invest (13,13) (26,0) Wait (0,26) (21,21) This is the business analogue of the Prisoner s dilemma, since the second row and second column are strictly dominated respectively by the first row and first column. Therefore, the only NE is (Invest,Invest)!

Solution of the SIR game This symmetric innovation race can therefore be summarize as A B Invest Wait Invest (13,13) (26,0) Wait (0,26) (21,21) This is the business analogue of the Prisoner s dilemma, since the second row and second column are strictly dominated respectively by the first row and first column. Therefore, the only NE is (Invest,Invest)! As with the PD, an analysis of this game in extensive form, regardless of the order the players move (or even using information sets for simultaneous moves), would lead to exactly the same solution.

Solution of the SIR game This symmetric innovation race can therefore be summarize as A B Invest Wait Invest (13,13) (26,0) Wait (0,26) (21,21) This is the business analogue of the Prisoner s dilemma, since the second row and second column are strictly dominated respectively by the first row and first column. Therefore, the only NE is (Invest,Invest)! As with the PD, an analysis of this game in extensive form, regardless of the order the players move (or even using information sets for simultaneous moves), would lead to exactly the same solution. In this example, the unique NE is also stable with respect to changes in correlation and risk aversion.

Two stage competitive R&D Consider two firms contemplating investment on a project with V 0 = 100 and equal probabilities to move up to V u = 200 and down to V d = 50.

Two stage competitive R&D Consider two firms contemplating investment on a project with V 0 = 100 and equal probabilities to move up to V u = 200 and down to V d = 50. We take u = 3/2, h = 2, p 1 = p 4 = 127/256, p 2 = p 3 = 1/256, γ = 0.1, r = 0.

Two stage competitive R&D Consider two firms contemplating investment on a project with V 0 = 100 and equal probabilities to move up to V u = 200 and down to V d = 50. We take u = 3/2, h = 2, p 1 = p 4 = 127/256, p 2 = p 3 = 1/256, γ = 0.1, r = 0. Suppose now that firm A can do an R&D investment at cost I 0 = 25 at time t 0, whereas at time t 1 the firms can equally share the follow on cost I 1 = 80.

Two stage competitive R&D Consider two firms contemplating investment on a project with V 0 = 100 and equal probabilities to move up to V u = 200 and down to V d = 50. We take u = 3/2, h = 2, p 1 = p 4 = 127/256, p 2 = p 3 = 1/256, γ = 0.1, r = 0. Suppose now that firm A can do an R&D investment at cost I 0 = 25 at time t 0, whereas at time t 1 the firms can equally share the follow on cost I 1 = 80. We will assume that the technology resulting from the R&D investment is proprietary, so that the market share of firm A after the R&D phase is s = 3/5.

Two stage competitive R&D Consider two firms contemplating investment on a project with V 0 = 100 and equal probabilities to move up to V u = 200 and down to V d = 50. We take u = 3/2, h = 2, p 1 = p 4 = 127/256, p 2 = p 3 = 1/256, γ = 0.1, r = 0. Suppose now that firm A can do an R&D investment at cost I 0 = 25 at time t 0, whereas at time t 1 the firms can equally share the follow on cost I 1 = 80. We will assume that the technology resulting from the R&D investment is proprietary, so that the market share of firm A after the R&D phase is s = 3/5. Moreover, we assume that the market value continues to evolve from time t 1 to time t 2 following the same dynamics, that is, at time t 2 the possible market values in these two period tree are V uu = 400, V ud = 100, V dd = 25.

Analyzing the R&D game If demand is high at time t 1 (V u = 200), we have: B (follower) Invest Wait Invest (80,40) (120,0) A (leader) Wait (0,120) (42,22)

Analyzing the R&D game If demand is high at time t 1 (V u = 200), we have: B (follower) Invest Wait Invest (80,40) (120,0) A (leader) Wait (0,120) (42,22) If demands is low at time t 1 (V d = 60), we have: B (follower) Invest Wait Invest (-10,-20) (-30,0) A (leader) Wait (0,-30) (8,0)

Analyzing the R&D game If demand is high at time t 1 (V u = 200), we have: B (follower) Invest Wait Invest (80,40) (120,0) A (leader) Wait (0,120) (42,22) If demands is low at time t 1 (V d = 60), we have: B (follower) Invest Wait Invest (-10,-20) (-30,0) A (leader) Wait (0,-30) (8,0) Then C A = I 0 + g(80, 8) = 25 + 30 = 5 > 0,

Analyzing the R&D game If demand is high at time t 1 (V u = 200), we have: B (follower) Invest Wait Invest (80,40) (120,0) A (leader) Wait (0,120) (42,22) If demands is low at time t 1 (V d = 60), we have: B (follower) Invest Wait Invest (-10,-20) (-30,0) A (leader) Wait (0,-30) (8,0) Then C A = I 0 + g(80, 8) = 25 + 30 = 5 > 0, whereas C B = g(40, 0) = 15

Analyzing the R&D game If demand is high at time t 1 (V u = 200), we have: B (follower) Invest Wait Invest (80,40) (120,0) A (leader) Wait (0,120) (42,22) If demands is low at time t 1 (V d = 60), we have: B (follower) Invest Wait Invest (-10,-20) (-30,0) A (leader) Wait (0,-30) (8,0) Then C A = I 0 + g(80, 8) = 25 + 30 = 5 > 0, whereas C B = g(40, 0) = 15 Therefore the R&D investment is recommended for A.

Analyzing the R&D game If demand is high at time t 1 (V u = 200), we have: B (follower) Invest Wait Invest (80,40) (120,0) A (leader) Wait (0,120) (42,22) If demands is low at time t 1 (V d = 60), we have: B (follower) Invest Wait Invest (-10,-20) (-30,0) A (leader) Wait (0,-30) (8,0) Then C A = I 0 + g(80, 8) = 25 + 30 = 5 > 0, whereas C B = g(40, 0) = 15 Therefore the R&D investment is recommended for A. For comparison, the complete market results are C A = 10 and C B = 7.

A multi-period investment game Consider two firms L and F each operating a project with an option to re-invest at cost I and increase cash flow according to an uncertain demand dy t = µ(t, Y t )dt + σ(t, Y t )dw.

A multi-period investment game Consider two firms L and F each operating a project with an option to re-invest at cost I and increase cash flow according to an uncertain demand dy t = µ(t, Y t )dt + σ(t, Y t )dw. Suppose that the option to re-invest has maturity T, let t m, m = 0,..., M be a partition of the interval [0, T ] and denote by (x L (t m ), x F (t m ) {(0, 0), (0, 1), (1, 0), (1, 1)} the possible states of the firms after a decision has been at time t m.

A multi-period investment game Consider two firms L and F each operating a project with an option to re-invest at cost I and increase cash flow according to an uncertain demand dy t = µ(t, Y t )dt + σ(t, Y t )dw. Suppose that the option to re-invest has maturity T, let t m, m = 0,..., M be a partition of the interval [0, T ] and denote by (x L (t m ), x F (t m ) {(0, 0), (0, 1), (1, 0), (1, 1)} the possible states of the firms after a decision has been at time t m. Let D xi (t m)x j (t m) denote the cash flow per unit of demand of firm i.

A multi-period investment game Consider two firms L and F each operating a project with an option to re-invest at cost I and increase cash flow according to an uncertain demand dy t = µ(t, Y t )dt + σ(t, Y t )dw. Suppose that the option to re-invest has maturity T, let t m, m = 0,..., M be a partition of the interval [0, T ] and denote by (x L (t m ), x F (t m ) {(0, 0), (0, 1), (1, 0), (1, 1)} the possible states of the firms after a decision has been at time t m. Let D xi (t m)x j (t m) denote the cash flow per unit of demand of firm i. Assume that D 10 > D 11 > D 00 > D 01.

A multi-period investment game Consider two firms L and F each operating a project with an option to re-invest at cost I and increase cash flow according to an uncertain demand dy t = µ(t, Y t )dt + σ(t, Y t )dw. Suppose that the option to re-invest has maturity T, let t m, m = 0,..., M be a partition of the interval [0, T ] and denote by (x L (t m ), x F (t m ) {(0, 0), (0, 1), (1, 0), (1, 1)} the possible states of the firms after a decision has been at time t m. Let D xi (t m)x j (t m) denote the cash flow per unit of demand of firm i. Assume that D 10 > D 11 > D 00 > D 01. We say that there is FMA is (D 10 D 00 ) > (D 11 D 01 ) and that there is SMA otherwise.

Derivation of project values (1) Let V (x i (t m 1 ),x j (t m 1 )) i (t m, y) denote the project value for firm i at time t m and demand level y.

Derivation of project values (1) Let V (x i (t m 1 ),x j (t m 1 )) i (t m, y) denote the project value for firm i at time t m and demand level y. Denote by v (x i (t m),x j (t m)) i (t m, y) the continuation values: v (1,1) (1,1) g(v i (t m+1, y u ), (V (1,1) i (t m+1, y d )) i (t m, y) = D 11 y t + e r t v (1,0) (1,0) g(v L (t m+1, y u ), (V (1,0) L (t m+1, y d )) L (t m, y) = D 10 y t + e r t v (0,1) (0,1) g(v L (t m+1, y u ), (V (0,1) L (t m+1, y d )) L (t m, y) = D 01 y t + e r t v (1,0) (1,0) g(v F (t m+1, y u ), (V (1,0) F (t m+1, y d )) F (t m, y) = D 01 y t + e r t v (0,1) (0,1) g(v F (t m+1, y u ), (V (0,1) F (t m+1, y d )) F (t m, y) = D 10 y t + e r t v (0,0) (0,0) g(v i (t m+1, y u ), (V (0,0) i (t m+1, y d )) i (t m, y) = D 00 y t + e r t

Derivation of project values (2) For fully invested firms, the project values are simply given by V (1,1) i (t m, y) = v (1,1) i (t m, y).

Derivation of project values (2) For fully invested firms, the project values are simply given by V (1,1) i (t m, y) = v (1,1) i (t m, y). Now consider the project value for firm F when L has already invested and F hasn t: V (1,0) F (t m, y) = max{v (1,1) F (t m, y) I, v (1,0) F (t m, y)}.

Derivation of project values (2) For fully invested firms, the project values are simply given by V (1,1) i (t m, y) = v (1,1) i (t m, y). Now consider the project value for firm F when L has already invested and F hasn t: V (1,0) F (t m, y) = max{v (1,1) F (t m, y) I, v (1,0) F (t m, y)}. Similarly, the project value for L when F has invested and L hasn t is V (0,1) L (t m, y) = max{v (1,1) L (t m, y) I, v (0,1) L (t m, y)}.

Derivation of project values (3) Next consider the project value for L when it has already invest and F hasn t: { V (1,0) v (1,1) L (t m, y) = L (t m, y) if v (1,1) F (t m, y) I > v (1,0) F (t m, y), (t m, y) otherwise. v (1,0) L

Derivation of project values (3) Next consider the project value for L when it has already invest and F hasn t: { V (1,0) v (1,1) L (t m, y) = L (t m, y) if v (1,1) F (t m, y) I > v (1,0) F (t m, y), (t m, y) otherwise. v (1,0) L Similarly, the project value for F when it has already invest and L hasn t is { V (0,1) v (1,1) F (t m, y) = F (t m, y) if v (1,1) L (t m, y) I > v (0,1) L (t m, y), (t m, y) otherwise. v (0,0) F

Derivation of project values (4) Finally, the project values V (0,0) i are obtained as a Nash equilibrium, since both firms still have the option to invest.

Derivation of project values (4) Finally, the project values V (0,0) i are obtained as a Nash equilibrium, since both firms still have the option to invest. The pay-off matrix for the game is Firm F Invest Wait Invest (v (1,1) Firm L L I, v (1,1) F I ) (v (1,0) L I, v (1,0) F ) Wait (v (0,1) L, v (0,1) F I ) (v (0,0) L, v (0,0) F )

FMA: dependence on risk aversion. 200 Gamma = 0.01 Rho = 0.5 200 Gamma = 0.1 Rho = 0.5 150 150 100 100 Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F V00L V11L!I V10L!I V01L Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F V00L V11L!I V10L!I V01L!200 0 50 100 150 200 Demand!200 0 50 100 150 200 Demand 200 Gamma = 1 Rho = 0.5 200 Gamma = 2 Rho = 0.5 150 150 100 100 Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F V00L V11L!I V10L!I V01L Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F V00L V11L!I V10L!I V01L!200 0 50 100 150 200 Demand!200 0 50 100 150 200 250 300 Demand Figure: Project values in FMA case for different risk aversions.

FMA: dependence on correlation. 90 VL Gamma = 1 VF Gamma=1 Rho = 0.5 90 VL Gamma = 1 VF Gamma = 2 Rho = 0.5 80 80 70 70 Project Value 60 50 Project Value 60 50 40 40 30 V00F V00L 20!0.8!0.6!0.4!0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Correlation 30 V00F V00L 20!0.8!0.6!0.4!0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Correlation 90 VL Gamma = 2 VF Gamma = 1 Rho = 0.5 80 70 Project Value 60 50 40 30 V00F V00L 20!0.8!0.6!0.4!0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Correlation Figure: Project values in FMA case as function of correlation.

SMA: dependence on risk aversion 200 SMA Gamma=0.01 200 SMA Gamma=0.1 150 150 100 100 Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F V00L V11L!I V10L!I V01L Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F V00L V11L!I V10L!I V01L!200 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 Demand!200 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 Demand 200 SMA Gamma=1 200 SMA Gamma = 2 150 150 100 100 Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F V00L V11L!I V10L!I V01L!200 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 Demand Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F V00L V11L!I V10L!I V01L!200 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 Demand Figure: Project values in SMA case for different risk aversions.

SMA: dependence on correlation. 200 VL Gamma = 1 VF Gamma = 1 Y0=105 200 VL Gamma = 1 VF Gamma = 2 Y0=105 150 150 Project Value 100 Project Value 100 50 50 0 V00F V00L!0.8!0.6!0.4!0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Correlation 0 V00F V00L!0.8!0.6!0.4!0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Correlation 200 VL Gamma = 2 VF Gamma = 1 Y0=105 150 Project Value 100 50 0 V00F V00L!0.8!0.6!0.4!0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Correlation Figure: Project values in SMA case as function of correlation.

SMA x FMA 200 FMA/SMA Gamma=0.01 200 FMA/SMA Gamma=0.1 150 150 100 100 Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F FMA V00L FMA V11L!I V01L V00L SMA V00F SMA Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F FMA V00L FMA V11L!I V01L V00L SMA V00F SMA!200 0 50 100 150 200 Demand!200 0 50 100 150 200 Demand 200 FMA/SMA Gamma=1 200 FMA/SMA Gamma=2 150 150 100 100 Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F FMA V00L FMA V11L!I V01L V00L SMA V00F SMA Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F FMA V00L FMA V11L!I V01L V00L SMA V00F SMA!200 0 50 100 150 200 Demand!200 0 50 100 150 200 Demand Figure: Project values for FMA and SMA.