the Gain on Home A Note Bias and Tel: +27 Working April 2016

Similar documents
Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries

Dynamic Inconsistency and Non-preferential Taxation of Foreign Capital

Sequential Decision-making and Asymmetric Equilibria: An Application to Takeovers

Dynamic Inconsistency and Non-preferential Taxation of Foreign Capital

Tax Competition with and without Tax Discrimination against Domestic Firms 1

Upward Pricing Pressure formulations with logit demand and endogenous partial acquisitions

The E ciency Comparison of Taxes under Monopolistic Competition with Heterogenous Firms and Variable Markups

Subsidization to Induce Tipping

Tax Competition with Heterogeneous Capital Mobility

Tari s, Taxes and Foreign Direct Investment

Introducing FDI into the Eaton and Kortum Model of Trade

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2011 Examination. 2010/2011 Syllabus ONLY

Technology transfer in a linear city with symmetric locations

A folk theorem for one-shot Bertrand games

Lecture 6 Applications of Static Games of Incomplete Information

Intergenerational Bargaining and Capital Formation

Optimal Acquisition Strategies in Unknown Territories

Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin

Country Characteristics and Preferences over Tax Principles

A New Trade Theory of GATT/WTO Negotiations

For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market. June 2017

Trade Protection and the Location of Production

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

Online Shopping Intermediaries: The Strategic Design of Search Environments

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Ex post or ex ante? On the optimal timing of merger control Very preliminary version

Income-Based Price Subsidies, Parallel Imports and Markets Access to New Drugs for the Poor

UCLA Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Exam Micro-Economic Theory

Cash-Flow Taxes in an International Setting. Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w

Liability and Reputation in Credence Goods Markets

Acquisition and Disclosure of Information as a Hold-up Problem

Economic Growth and Development : Exam. Consider the model by Barro (1990). The production function takes the

Mossin s Theorem for Upper-Limit Insurance Policies

The taxation of foreign profits: a unified view WP 15/04. February Working paper series Michael P Devereux University of Oxford

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

Switching Costs, Relationship Marketing and Dynamic Price Competition

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

Some Problems. 3. Consider the Cournot model with inverse demand p(y) = 9 y and marginal cost equal to 0.

Depreciation: a Dangerous Affair

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

For Online Publication Only. ONLINE APPENDIX for. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market

Minimum Tax and Repeated Tax Competition

The major innovation in international tax matters in recent

A Nearly Optimal Auction for an Uninformed Seller

Test 1. ECON3161, Game Theory. Tuesday, September 25 th

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

research paper series

Dynamic games with incomplete information

Pure Strategies and Undeclared Labour in Unionized Oligopoly

Loss-leader pricing and upgrades

Using Executive Stock Options to Pay Top Management

Collusion in a One-Period Insurance Market with Adverse Selection

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

Why Do Most Countries Set High Tax Rates on Capital?

Equilibrium Audit Strategies Against Tax Treaty Shopping

Follower Payoffs in Symmetric Duopoly Games

Upward pricing pressure of mergers weakening vertical relationships

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports

Integrated Equilibrium in a Four-good Heckscher-Ohlin-Ricardo model

Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D

Regional versus Multilateral Trade Liberalization, Environmental Taxation and Welfare

Simple e ciency-wage model

The Taxation of Foreign Pro ts: a Uni ed View

Cross-border Mergers and Entry Modes of FDI In ows

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Bargaining Order and Delays in Multilateral Bargaining with Asymmetric Sellers

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

Integrated Equilibrium in a Four-good Heckscher-Ohlin-Ricardo model

Downstream R&D, raising rival s costs, and input price contracts: a comment on the role of spillovers

Lobby Interaction and Trade Policy

Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth

Playing games with transmissible animal disease. Jonathan Cave Research Interest Group 6 May 2008

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

Optimal Unemployment Bene ts Policy and the Firm Productivity Distribution

Lecture 10: Market Experiments and Competition between Trading Institutions

Strategic information acquisition and the. mitigation of global warming

Some Notes on Timing in Games

Should small countries fear deindustrialization?

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics

ISSN BWPEF Uninformative Equilibrium in Uniform Price Auctions. Arup Daripa Birkbeck, University of London.

Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 19/ Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

Solution to Tutorial 1

Physical Capital, Knowledge Capital and the Choice Between FDI and Outsourcing

Coordination of tax policies toward inward foreign direct investment

Problem Set 2 Answers

Combining Semi-Endogenous and Fully Endogenous Growth: a Generalization.

1. If the consumer has income y then the budget constraint is. x + F (q) y. where is a variable taking the values 0 or 1, representing the cases not

ECE 586GT: Problem Set 1: Problems and Solutions Analysis of static games

Bargaining, Competition and E cient Investment

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

A Political-Economy Theory of Trade Agreements

Rent Shifting, Exclusion and Market-Share Contracts

The exporters behaviors : Evidence from the automobiles industry in China

Credit Card Competition and Naive Hyperbolic Consumers

Effective Tax Rates and the User Cost of Capital when Interest Rates are Low

Using Trade Policy to Influence Firm Location. This Version: 9 May 2006 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE DO NOT CITE

Transcription:

University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series A Note on Home Bias and the Gain from Non-Preferential Taxation Kaushal Kishore University of Pretoria Working Paper: 206-32 April 206 Department of Economics University of Pretoria 0002, Pretoria South Africa Tel: +27 2 420 243

A note on home bias and the gain from non-preferential taxation Kaushal Kishore Department of Economics Tukkiewerf University of Pretoria Cnr Lynnwood and University Roads Hat eld 0083 April 20, 206 Abstract In a symmetric model of tax competition, we support the claim in Haupt and Peters (2005) that a non-preferential regime generates higher tax revenues compared to a preferential regime when investors have home bias. Further, we show that a complete ban on preferential taxation is desirable even when the capital bases are in nitely elastic. Keywords: Tax competition; Nash Equilibrium; Non-preferential regime. JEL classi cation: C72; F20; H26 Introduction Haupt and peters (2005) nd that "home bias" can explain the gain from having a non-preferential agreements between two countries over two capital bases of equal size which are elastic with respect to the di erence in tax rates of competing countries. A capital base is considered to have home bias in favor of a particular country if for an equal tax rate, a larger fraction of the capital base locates in the country in favor of which it has home bias. It has been shown in the literature that asymmetry in the size of capital bases between countries enhance competition, since a small country (a country with a smaller share in a capital base) is more aggressive. In Haupt and Peters (2005) under a non-preferential agreement, a smaller share in one of the two capital bases is o set by the larger share in the other capital base. Hence, a Department of Economics. University of Pretoria. Hat eld. 0083. SA. Email: kaushal.kishore@up.ac.za. Ph: +27(72)032029. For instance, see Janeba and Peters (999).

non-preferential regime induce symmetry and reduce competition. On the other hand, under a preferential regime, competing countries set tax rates on two capital bases independent of each other; hence, a country obtaining a smaller share of capital base is more aggressive, which reduces tax revenues of competing countries from both capital bases. In this paper, we identify the gains from a non-preferential regime due to home bias in separation from heterogeneity in the size of capital bases. For doing so we adopt a model which captures the main idea of Haupt and Peters (2005). Further, we do not impose restrictions to insure a pure strategy Nash equilibrium. Thus our model also extends Janeba and Peters (2005) for the case when two capital bases are perfectly mobile 2. Another realistic feature of our model is that in equilibrium both competing countries can obtain mobile capital with a positive probability even if they set di erent tax rates. 2 Model There are two identical countries/governments labeled as A and B. Each country consists of homogeneous agents of unit mass who are imperfectly mobile between two countries and each agent is endowed with one unit of capital. Governments maximize tax revenues and agents maximize net after tax returns on capital. We assume that the net return on capital is identical in two countries which is equal to. We assume that the maximum tax rate a country can impose is equal to as well. The capital base owned by agents who are residents of country i is denoted as i c, where i = A; B. A fraction of the capital base i c is located in country i, while is located in country j (j = A; B; i 6= i). Owners of capital base i c have home bias in favor of country i which is captured by the term f 2 (0; ). To explain the role of home bias, let t i and t j be the tax rates on capital base i c by country i and j, respectively. If t j > t i f, then the capital base i c locates completely in country i. On the other hand if t j t i f, then the capital base i c locates completely in country j. Below, we describe the nature of the game under a non-preferential and a preferential regime. Under a preferential regime, in stage one, competing countries simultaneously announce di erent tax rates applicable to capital bases A c and A c. In stage two, agents decide whether to relocate after observing the tax rates set by two countries. After investments decision are made, investors pay the tax in the country where their capital is invested. The game under a non-preferential regime is similar to a preferential regime except that, in stage, countries announce an equal tax rate applicable for both capital bases. 2 We observe that most of FDI (Foreign Direct Investments) is carried out by big multinationals. Jenses, Bernard and Schott (2008) nd that importing and exporting are closely related, more than 50 percent of the rms in the United States that import also export and these rms account for close to 90 percent of US trade. Their investment decision based on di erences in tax rates are likely to be highly correlated which in reality may lead to violation of conditions insuring pure strategy Nash equilibirum. Article 24 of OECD (997) Model of Tax Competition prevents di erences in tax treatments which are solely based on certain spe c grounds. 2

The payo s of competing countries and investors are fully determined by the tax rates set by countries in stage one. Hence, we model the tax competition as a symmetric one shot simultaneous move game. 3 Non-preferential regime Let t A and t B be tax rates set by country A and B, respectively. The revenue function of country i can be written as 8 Rnp i t i ; t j < 2t i if t i t j f = t i if t i t j < f () : 0 if t i t j + f where i; j = A; B and i 6= j. When t i t j < f, the capital base i c locates completely in country i, therefore country i obtains the tax revenue equal to t i. When t i t j f, both capital bases locate in country i, in that case country i earns tax revenue equal to 2t i. If t i t j + f then both capital bases locate in country j and country i receives zero tax revenue. If home bias is not too large (f < =2), a pure strategy Nash equilibrium does not exist. A government desire a low tax rate when the competitor s tax rate is high and also desire a high tax rate when the competitor s tax rate is low. We follow the method in Kishore (205) to nd the mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. In the mixed strategy Nash equilibrium, a country sets a high tax rate when competitor s tax rate is low and set a low tax rate when competitor s tax rate high. As the cost of mobility (f) decreases, competition for mobile capital increases and tax revenues of competing countries decreases. Proposition Under a non-preferential regime if f =2, a pure strategy Nash equilibrium exists. Both countries set the tax rate equal to and receive tax revenues equal to. When f < =2, a pure strategy Nash equilibrium does not exist, however, a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium exist. When = + p 2 < f < =2, in a symmetric mixed strategy Nash equilibrium countries earn tax revenue equal to. In the mixed strategy Nash equilibrium both countries randomize over the interval f( f; f) ; ( ; )g. There is a probability mass of m at, where = f=2 (=2) p f 2 + 4f ( f) m = > 0 f Equilibrium strategy of countries, i.e., the distribution of tax rate over the support is ( (t+f) t+f for t 2 ( f; f) G (t) = (t f) t f for t 2 ( ; ) When f = + p 2, countries earn tax revenues equal to f + p 2. Countries randomize over the interval (; + 2f) and there is no probability 3

mass anywhere on the support. The distribution of tax rates over the support in the equilibrium is ( t+f for t 2 (; + f) G (t) = (t f) t+f for t 2 ( + f; + 2f) where = f + p 2 f: Proof. The proof is similar to proposition (3) in kishore (205). The mixed strategy Nash equilibrium described in the proposition () has many desirable properties which relate to observed facts. When the cost of capital relocation is high, i.e., f > = + p 2, both countries set very high tax rate with strictly positive probability, explaining high tax rates on mobile capital in many countries. Also, both countries obtain mobile capital even if their tax rate di er as long as the di erence is not too large. 4 Preferential regime Under a preferential regime maximization of tax revenues requires a country setting a lower tax rate on the capital base which has bias in favor of the competing countries. This reciprocal discounts by competing countries results in low tax rates on both capital bases, thereby reducing tax revenues. Proposition 2 Under a preferential regime, in a symmetric pure strategy Nash equilibrium country i sets tax rates f and 0 on capital bases i c and j c ; where i; j = A; B. In the equilibrium competing countries earn tax revenue equal to f. Proof. Proof is simple. It is trivial to argue that no country can get better by a unilateral deviation from the proposed strategy in proposition (2). The zero tax rate on the capital with positive bias in favor of competing country is instructive. One of the "key factors" proposed by OECD (997) to identify "harmful preferential regimes" is "a low or zero e ective tax rates on speci c kinds of income". 5 Comparison Table () below list tax revenues under a preferential regime (R p ) and a nonpreferential regime (R np ). The result further strengthen the claim in Haupt and Peters (2005), that, home bias itself can explain the gain from having a non-preferential regime when capital bases are highly elastic. Further, while Haupt and Peters (2005) show that only a partial ban on a preferential regime is desirable, our result shows that a complete ban on a preferential regime increases tax revenues of competing countries. 4

R np R p R np R p f =2 f f 0 = + p 2 < f < =2 f=2+ (=2) p p f 2 + 4f f (=2) f 2 + 4f f > 0 f = + p 2 f + p 2 f f p 2 > 0 Table 6 Conclusion This paper strengthen the claim in Haupt and Peters (2005) that the result of Keen (200) may reverse if capital owners have home bias. Further, we also show that a complete ban on a preferential regime is desirable even when the capital bases are in nitely elastic. References [] Andrew B. Bernard, J. Bradford Jensen, Peter K. Schott. 2008. Importers, Exporters, and Multinationals: A Portrait of Firms in the U.S. that Trade Goods. Yale School of Management Working Paper Series, No. 39. [2] Alexander Haupt, Wolfgang Peters. 2005. Restricting preferential tax regimes to avoid harmful tax competition. Regional Science and Urban Economics 35, 493 507. [3] Eckhard Janeba, Wolfgang Peters. 999. Tax evasion, tax competition and the gains from nondiscrimination: the case of interest taxation in Europe. The Economic Journal 09, 93 0. [4] Michael Keen. 200. Preferential Regimes Can Make Tax Competition Less Harmful. National Tax Journal 54, 757-62. [5] Kaushal Kishore. 205. Tax Competition, Imperfect Capital Mobility and the gain from non-preferential agreements. Working Paper. [6] OECD. 997. Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital (Paris: OECD Committee on Fiscal A airs). 5