Demographic Transition, Education, and Inequality in India

Similar documents
Economic Growth and Income Distribution: Linking Macroeconomic Models with Household Surveys at the Global Level

Assessing Development Strategies to Achieve the MDGs in the Arab Region

Main Features. Aid, Public Investment, and pro-poor Growth Policies. Session 4 An Operational Macroeconomic Framework for Ethiopia

General Equilibrium Analysis Part II A Basic CGE Model for Lao PDR

Economic Growth, Inequality and Poverty: Concepts and Measurement

MAKING THE MOST OF DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE IN SOUTHERN AFRICA

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Public Infrastructure and Economic Growth in Pakistan: A Dynamic CGEmicrosimulation. By Muhammad Zeshan SDPI. Sustainable Development Policy Institute

The Economic implication of retirement age extension in China. --A Dynamic general equilibrium analysis

Are we there yet? Adjustment paths in response to Tariff shocks: a CGE Analysis.

Energy, welfare and inequality: a micromacro reconciliation approach for Indonesia

Her Majesty the Queen in Right of Canada (2017) All rights reserved

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Inter temporal macroeconomic trade offs and payoffs of human development strategies: An economy wide modelling analysis

1 What does sustainability gap show?

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

IMPACTS OF AGING POPULATION ON REGIONAL ECONOMIES USING AN INTERREGIONAL CGE MODEL OF KOREA

Macroeconomic impacts of limiting the tax deductibility of interest expenses of inbound companies

Linking Microsimulation and CGE models

Challenges For the Future of Chinese Economic Growth. Jane Haltmaier* Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. August 2011.

Population Ageing, Retirement Age Extension and Economic Growth In China A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom

CHAPTER 4. EXPANDING EMPLOYMENT THE LABOR MARKET REFORM AGENDA

Analyzing Fiscal Space Using MAMS: An Application to Burkina Faso

Labor force participation of the elderly in Japan

Data requirements II: Building a country database for MAMS

To understand the drivers of poverty reduction,

Financing strategies to achieve the MDGs in Latin America and the Caribbean

A N ENERGY ECONOMY I NTERAC TION MODEL FOR EGYPT

Green tax reform in Belgium: Combining regional general equilibrium and microsimulation

On Linking Microsimulation and Computable General Equilibrium Models Using Exact Aggregation of Heterogeneous Discrete-choice choice Making Agents

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Issue Brief. Amer ican Academy of Actuar ies. An Actuarial Perspective on the 2006 Social Security Trustees Report

CHAPTER 03. A Modern and. Pensions System

Chapter 4: Micro Kuznets and Macro TFP Decompositions

Economic consequences of intifada

Long-Term Fiscal External Panel

Her Majesty the Queen in Right of Canada (2018) All rights reserved

What types of policy decisions is CGE model findings most useful for

Making the Most of Demographic Change in Southern Africa

Policy Options Beyond 2015 Achieving the MDGs in Bangladesh. Background Paper for European Development Report 2015

1 For the purposes of validation, all estimates in this preliminary note are based on spatial price index computed at PSU level guided

Halving Poverty in Russia by 2024: What will it take?

MDGs Example from Latin America

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

DSGD DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 11 PROSPECTS FOR GROWTH AND POVERTY REDUCTION IN ZAMBIA,

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

National Minimum Wage in South Africa: Quantification of Impact

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS OF FLORIDA AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS TO CUBA

PUBLIC SPENDING, GROWTH, AND POVERTY ALLEVIATION IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA: A DYNAMIC GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS

The Effect of Interventions to Reduce Fertility on Economic Growth. Quamrul Ashraf Ashley Lester David N. Weil. Brown University.

CRS Report for Congress

INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND INEQUALITY IN LUXEMBOURG AND THE NEIGHBOURING COUNTRIES,

Social Accounting Matrix and its Application. Kijong Kim Levy Economics Institute GEM-IWG summer workshop July

Simple Macroeconomic Model for MDGs based Planning and Policy Analysis. Thangavel Palanivel UNDP Regional Centre in Colombo

Testing the predictions of the Solow model:

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE CONFERENCE AGREEMENT FOR H.R. 1, THE TAX CUTS AND JOBS ACT

Appendix A Specification of the Global Recursive Dynamic Computable General Equilibrium Model

Brazil and Mexico Facing the Financial Crisis: Still Fragile or Becoming Stronger?

Horowhenua Socio-Economic projections. Summary and methods

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Simulation Model of the Irish Local Economy: Short and Medium Term Projections of Household Income

Chapter 6 Micro-determinants of Household Welfare, Social Welfare, and Inequality in Vietnam

Fiscal Sustainability Report 2017

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE TAX REFORM ACT OF 2014

Working Paper No China s Structural Adjustment from the Income Distribution Perspective

Global Aging and Financial Markets

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE TAX CUT AND JOBS ACT AS ORDERED REPORTED BY THE SENATE COMMITTEE ON FINANCE ON NOVEMBER 16, 2017

G.C.E. (A.L.) Support Seminar- 2016

Economic consequences of intifada

Automated labor market diagnostics for low and middle income countries

Chapter 8. Revenue recycling and environmental policy

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

The Aggregate Implications of Regional Business Cycles

YEREVAN 2014 MACROECONOMIC OVERVIEW OF ARMENIA

Structural Changes in the Maltese Economy

What Is Behind the Decline in Poverty Since 2000?

Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates)

Report ISBN: (PDF)

Research Report No. 69 UPDATING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY ESTIMATES: 2005 PANORA SOCIAL POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT CENTRE

Duty drawbacks, Competitiveness and Growth: The Case of China. Elena Ianchovichina Economic Policy Unit, PREM Network World Bank

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Labor s Declining Share of Income and Rising Inequality. Margaret Jacobson and Filippo Occhino

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy

Session 5 Evidence-based trade policy formulation: impact assessment of trade liberalization and FTA

Masaaki Shirakawa: The transition from high growth to stable growth Japan s experience and implications for emerging economies

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

UNCTAD S LDCs REPORT 2013 Growth with Employment for Inclusive & Sustainable Development

East Asian Trade Relations in the Wake of China s WTO Accession

Generational Accounting in Korea

Figure I Economy growth rate by income group. Real GDP growth rate (annual rate) Average from 2003 to 2013

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics

Fabrizio Perri Università Bocconi, Minneapolis Fed, IGIER, CEPR and NBER October 2012

Growth and Distributive Effects of Public Infrastructure Investments in China

STRUCTURAL REFORM REFORMING THE PENSION SYSTEM IN KOREA. Table 1: Speed of Aging in Selected OECD Countries. by Randall S. Jones

Transcription:

Demographic Transition, Education, and Inequality in India Maurizio Bussolo, Denis Medvedev, and Kathryn Vasilaky April 10, 2014 Abstract India is entering demographic transition much later than most developing countries, and will still be a relatively young nation twenty years from now. As the population ages and younger, better-educated cohorts enter the workforce. While the shift in labor supply composition towards skilled labor is likely to have positive effects on overall productivity, the evolution of returns to skills and, consequently, inequality will depend critically on changes in demand for these workers. To address these questions in a consistent framework, this paper links a computable general equilibrium (CGE) model of India with household survey data from India s National Sample Survey Organization (NSSO) in a simple micro-simulation framework. The CGE model results demonstrate that the demographic transition and the rising share of skilled workers could have substantial growth benefits for the Indian economy, raising the average per capita GDP growth over the 2011-2030 period by nearly 0.5 percentage points with most of the benefit coming from increasing skills rather than the rising worker/population ratio. Keywords: Demographic transition, inequality, India JEL classification: World Bank and Columbia University. The views expressed here are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the World Bank Group, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. Address for correspondence: 70L 1-019, The World Bank Group, 70 Lodi Estate, New Delhi, 110003, India; dmedvedev@worldbank.org.

1. Introduction and motivation India is entering demographic transition much later than most developing countries, and will still be a relatively young nation twenty years from now. As the population ages and younger, better-educated cohorts enter the workforce, the average schooling of the working age population will increase by at least a full year even with no further improvements in the educational attainment of today s youth and could rise much faster if further progress is achieved on the education agenda. While the shift in labor supply composition towards skilled labor is likely to have positive effects on overall productivity, the evolution of returns to skills and, consequently, inequality will depend critically on changes in demand for these workers. A growing number of analysts have questioned whether the supply and quality of jobs will be sufficient for the new workforce entrants to take advantage of the demographic dividend (see, for example, Government of India Economic Survey, 2013 ). While the supply effect can be largely thought of as exogenous driven by expected demographic trends and the observed differences between the educational attainments of the young and the old the ability of the economy to absorb the rising share of skilled workers will depend on the speed as well as sectoral pattern of economic growth. Furthermore, the evolution of returns to skilled labor as an outcome of the supply and demand interactions will determine the evolution of inequality and the shape of India s income distribution. To address these questions in a consistent framework, this paper links a computable general equilibrium (CGE) model of India with household survey data from India s National Sample Survey Organization (NSSO) in a simple micro-simulation framework. The recursive-dynamic CGE model has a 2011 base year (corresponding to Indian FY2011/12), seven broad categories of economic activity with varying skill intensities, and three factors of production (unskilled labor, skilled labor, and capital). The sectoral distribution of employment and labor value added has been reconciled, to the extent possible, with the 2011/12 round of India s NSSO household survey. The CGE model is then solved recursively until 2030, using the World Bank s most recent medium-term macroeconomic forecast to calibrate labor productivity in the baseline. Changes in employment across the farm and non-farm sectors, labor earnings by skill and agriculture/non-agriculture, relative price changes across food and non-food commodities, and growth in consumption per capita are then mapped to the household survey to produce a counterfactual distribution. The paper analyzes the evolution of poverty and inequality between 2011 and 2030 under a baseline scenario which incorporates the expected aging dynamics and their impact on increased skill content of the labor force. The overall effects of on economic growth, allocation of resources across sectors, returns to labor, and inequality are then decomposed into contributions from aging and education with counterfactual scenarios. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: section 2 describes the past trends of inequality in India and links the widening inequality to, inter alia, rising returns to skilled labor, section presents the model and data used in this paper, section 4 develops the scenarios and discusses the impacts of a rising share of skilled workers on macroeconomic, sectoral, and distributional variables, while section 5 offers some concluding remarks and directions for future research. 1

2. Recent trends in inequality While over the past two decades India has enjoyed a period of high per capita GDP growth (average 5.3 percent per year) and major reductions in poverty (Table 1), inequality has also widened. The consumption Gini coefficient increased by nearly 5 points and the average consumption of the bottom 40 percent of the distribution has consistently lagged behind the rate of growth of the mean. Moreover, rates of per capita consumption growth have been consistently higher for richer percentiles of the population, resulting in widening inequality (Figure 1). Table 1: Characteristics of India s income distribution (1993-2011) 1993-94 2004-05 2009-10 2011-12 %Δ, 09-11 %Δ, 04-11 Household consumption per capita (2009 Rs.) 831.49 960.12 1,065.62 1,188.65 5.62 3.10 Household consumption per capita, bottom 40% 487.33 532.57 578.60 640.83 5.24 2.68 (2009 Rs) Poverty headcount, national poverty line 45.54 37.72 29.91 22.04-3.93-2.24 Poverty gap, national poverty line 11.19 8.37 6.20 4.03 Gini 27.79 30.92 31.96 32.26 Theil (GE[1]) 15.13 18.76 20.89 21.00 A large part of the increase in overall inequality can be attributed to the rising demand and returns for skilled labor. Defining skilled workers as those who have completed at least 12 years of education, returns to skills defined as either individual labor earnings or per capita consumption of households where the head is a skilled worker have risen more rapidly than remuneration of unskilled labor. Although Cain et. al. (2010) argue that whatever increases in education that have taken place up until 2004 have been more than enough to meet increased demand for education, technical and professional positions have seen an 18% increase in returns in urban areas. Some of this increased return to skilled labor may be due to skill biased technological change and foreign direct investment (Bang 2005), but also to increased inequality in educational opportunity (Asadullah 2012, Pal and Ghosh 2010). Overall, however, as inequality has widened between 1993/94 and 2011/12, dispersion between the two skilled groups has also increased. During the last decade (between 2004/05 and 2009/10), the growing gap between households headed by skilled and unskilled workers has accounted for the entire change in the Theil index. 2

Percent change in consumption per capita Percent change in consumption per capita Preliminary & incomplete draft, please do not distribute or quote without authors permission Figure 1: Growth incidence (1993-2011) 2.5 Growth incidence, 2004-1993 2.5 Growth incidence, 2009-2004 2 1.5 2 1.5 1.5 0 20 40 60 80 100 Share of population ranked by consumption per capita, percent 0 20 40 60 80 100 Share of population ranked by consumption per capita, percent 6.5 Growth incidence, 2011-2009 3.6 Growth incidence, 2011-2004 3.4 6 3.2 5.5 3 2.8 5 2.6 0 20 40 60 80 100 Share of population ranked by consumption per capita, percent 0 20 40 60 80 100 Share of population ranked by consumption per capita, percent 3. Model and data The CGE model used in this paper is the World Bank's prototype single-country model. 1 Production takes place under perfect competition and constant returns to scale, and is modeled in a nested constant elasticity of substitution (CES) fashion to reflect various substitution possibilities across inputs (see Figure 2). All labor and capital income accrues to the households. Household demand is allocated across commodities according to the linear expenditure system (LES), in which consumers maximize a Stone- Geary utility function subject to the disposable income constraint. 2 Other final demand agents government and investment use the CES expenditure system. International trade is modeled using the nested Armington specification, in which consumer products are differentiated by region of origin and combined using CES functions. 3 World import prices are fixed, which means that any increase in import demand can be satisfied without affecting global prices. On the supply side, producers allocate output to domestic and export markets the model according to a constant elasticity of transformation (CET) specification while the export price elasticity of demand is infinite. 1 Detailed model documentation and the user s guide are available in van der Mensbrugghe (2005b) and van der Mensbrugghe (2005a), respectively. 2 See Deaton and Muellbauer (1980, Chapter 3) for a detailed discussion of the LES demand system, and Stone (1954) for the Stone-Geary utility function. 3 See Armington (1969). 3

Figure 2 Nested structure of production Output (XP) p Aggregate intermediate demand (ND) Value added (VA) v Intermediate demand (XAp) m, w Capital-labor (KL) kl Aggregate land (TT) t Intermediate demand by region of origin (XD & XM) Unskilled labor (UL) u Capital-skilled labor (KSK) ks Land demand by type (T d ) Unskilled labor demand by type (L d ) Skilled labor (SKL) s Aggregate capital (KT) k Skilled labor demand by type (L d ) Capital demand by type (K d ) The aggregate stock of capital is allocated across various sectors with a finite elasticity of transformation, resulting in imperfect mobility of capital. Skilled workers are freely mobile throughout the economy, while the market for unskilled labor is segmented into farm- and non-farm categories. Within each segment, labor is perfectly mobile across activities, but mobility across segments is limited by a migration function which responds to changes in the farm/non-farm wage premiums. The volumes of government current and investment spending are fixed as shares of real GDP, while the deficit (in real terms) is also fixed. Public revenues adjust to clear the government balance by means of a flexible household direct tax rate. 4 The investment-to-gdp ratio is fixed at the base year value and a flexible marginal propensity to save out of household disposable income ensures that total saving equals total investment. The current account balance is fixed by the available quantity of foreign saving and the 4 Although other assumptions about closing the government balance, such as adjustments in indirect taxes, increased borrowing, or reduced spending, are also plausible, choosing the direct tax rate as an instrument is a fairly neutral way (in an allocative sense) of restoring fiscal balance in case of a shock. It also simplifies welfare measurements since the incidence of making up the budgetary shortfall falls squarely on consumers (in contrast to indirect taxes, which, for example, may motivate producers to allocate a larger share of production toward exports which may be taxed at a lower rate). 4

exchange rate is the numeraire, which means that domestic prices are determined relative to a fixed-cost basket of foreign goods. 5 The model is solved in a recursive dynamic mode, in which subsequent end-of-period equilibria are linked with a set of equations that update the main macro variables. There are three determinants of real GDP growth in the model: labor supply growth, capital accumulation, and increases in productivity. Labor volume growth is determined outside of the CGE model through the pipeline aging effect, under the assumption of constant labor force participation rates. The capital stock in each period is the sum of depreciated capital from the period before and new investment. For all sectors, capital productivity remains fixed throughout the model horizon, while growth in labor productivity in the business-as-usual (BaU) scenario is calibrated to real GDP growth in the World Bank s medium- and long-term forecast. In all other scenarios, labor productivity is fixed in each period at the BaU level, and GDP growth becomes endogenous. 6 Thus, real GDP growth may differ from BaU due to faster/slower accumulation of capital or shocks to the productivity shift parameters, allowing the variations in GDP growth across scenarios to be directly attributed to the shocks. Distributional analysis is carried out with the World Bank s GIDD model, which generalizes the existing CGE-microsimulation methodologies and is described in detail in Bussolo, De Hoyos, and Medvedev (2010). Starting from the observed global distribution, the CGE model provides a set of link variables for the micro-simulation: (a) change in the allocation of workers across sectors in the economy, (b) change in returns to labor by skill and occupation, (c) change in the relative price of food and non-food consumption baskets, and (d) overall growth in real consumption per capita. The final distribution is obtained by applying the changes in these link variables to the household survey. 4. Potential future trends in inequality 4.1 Demographic projections: how much will the age and education structure change? Expected demographic changes in particular, forthcoming changes in age structure combined with increased levels of education of the younger cohorts imply that, for India, a large wave of educated individuals will enter the labor market over the next two decades. Since these young cohorts replace older less educated (and also smaller) cohorts, the average education in India is likely rise by at least one year without any further effort to increase educational attainment among the current student-age population. Consider first the current structure of India s population. As fertility rates came down while health outcomes and life expectancy improved since the middle of the last century, the ratio of young workers (aged 25-29) to older workers (aged 60-64) has come down (red line in the top right panel of Figure 3). Nonetheless, India remains a very young country today, with half of its population below the age of 24 (bottom right panel of Figure 3). Perhaps even more importantly, young cohorts continue to be much more educated than the older cohorts they gradually replace in the labor force. The ratio of the average years of education of young workers to that of older workers has risen dramatically over time (blue line in the top right panel of Figure 3) and today, the young workers have on average nearly three more years of education than older workers (bottom left panel of Figure 3). 5 We use the deflator of GDP at factor cost as a measure of movements in the real exchange rate. 6 Thus, in the absence of any shocks, the BaU GDP growth rate is reproduced exactly. 5

Figure 3: Demographics and education 6 India, births per woman.12 5.1 4.08 3.06.04 2 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Year Total fertility rate Source: World Development Indicators Adolescent fertility rate Average years of education by age cohort 15 to 19 20 to 24 25 to 29 30 to 34 35 to 39 40 to 44 45 to 49 50 to 54 90 and above 85 to 90 80 to 84 75 to 79 70 to 74 65 to 69 60 to 64 55 to 59 50 to 54 45 to 49 40 to 44 35 to 39 30 to 34 25 to 29 20 to 24 15 to 19 10 to 14 5 to 9 Under 5 60 50 40 30 20 Millions 20 30 40 50 60 Source: NSS 66th Round. Male and Female Population by Age, 2009-10 Males Females 8 6 4 2 55 to 59 60 to 64 65 to 69 70 to 74 75 to 79 80 to 84 85 to 90 90 and above Male and Female Projected Population by Age, 2030 90 and above 85 to 90 80 to 84 75 to 79 70 to 74 65 to 69 60 to 64 55 to 59 50 to 54 45 to 49 40 to 44 35 to 39 30 to 34 25 to 29 20 to 24 15 to 19 10 to 14 5 to 9 Under 5 60 50 40 30 20 Millions 20 30 40 50 60 Source: NSS 66th Round & UN Population division. Males Females 6

Extending these trends into the future by following the movements of age cohorts through time to match the UN population projections, we develop a new age-education structure of India s population in 2030 (Table 2). This new structure is generated via a pipeline effect where today s younger cohorts replace older cohorts of tomorrow, such that the 20-24-year-olds of 2010 become the 40-44-year-olds of 2030, carrying with them all of their characteristics (education, sector of employment, etc.). Younger cohorts, such as those currently in school or not yet born, take on the educational and other characteristics of today s young workers. In this sense, the increase in average educational attainment of the population is passive since we make no assumptions about further investments in the education of today s students which would otherwise result in even faster accumulation of skilled workers in the population. Table 2: Education shock Percent of group with tertiary education 2010 2030 Change Young 0.2 0.7 0.5 Middle 0.9 1.1 0.3 Old 0.1 0.3 0.2 Percentage of population by education levels 2010 2030 Change Prim 64.0 55.8-8.3 Sec 34.5 41.7 7.1 Ter 1.4 2.5 1.1 AveEdu 1 1.37 1.47 Notes: 1. Average education is the weighted education level (primary=1, sec=2, tertiary=3) where the weights are equal to the population shares. In modeling terms, the new 2030 population structure is arrived at by applying a re-weighting procedure to the 2011/12 India household survey: household sampling weights are adjusted such that greater weight is given to households with older and more educated members until the new age-education for the population are reached (see Bussolo, De Hoyos, and Medvedev, 2010, for details). Since the re-weighting procedure replicates all of the characteristics of today s older and more skilled households, it also changes the structure of the 2011/12 distribution in a number of other important ways. For example, households with a larger number of older and more skilled members are more likely to be found in urban areas, with their members more likely to be earning most of their income from non-agricultural activities. Because of this, these households also tend to have higher per capita consumption than households which are assigned lower weights as a result of the re-weighting procedure with the end result being that the new 2030 age-education population is also characterized by a more urban, more non-farm, and more unequal distribution. The simulation steps described in section 4.3 below take into account most of these byproducts of population aging when passing the economic shocks from the macro model to the initial distribution to generate a proper counterfactual. 4.2 Demand pressures (CGE model results) As described in the previous section, the contribution of more skilled cohorts to India s labor force is likely to increase substantially over the next two decades. The impact of the increased supply of skilled labor on the returns to education, or the skill premium, will in turn depend on demand for skills, i.e. the 7

ability of the economy to generate jobs which require higher skilled workers. 7 Modeling the labor demand side presents a series of challenges, as it depends (mainly) on technological changes and on patterns of growth. For example, export led growth may have quite different labor market consequences if exports are concentrated in a few commodities or are supplied by broader manufacturing and service sectors. Changes in the premium may also be affected by shifts in the institutional setting and policies of the labor market, although these are outside the scope of the current paper. In the CGE model of this paper, demand for skilled workers is generated solely through the process of economic growth. Faster rates of growth generate demand for higher-income-elasticity goods and services, which tend to require a more skill-intensive mix to produce. At the top level of the capital-labor nest, skilled labor and capital are also treated as complements, so that a faster-growing economy which accumulates savings and capital more rapidly will also demand larger quantities of skilled labor. The strength of these effects in generating a sufficient demand for skills depends on the rate of per capita GDP growth (which for India averages 5.3 percent per year through 2030 in the baseline scenario) and the share of high-income-elasticity goods and services in the households consumption basket (which for India is just over 50 percent). In order to evaluate the potential impacts of supply and demand-side factors on returns to skills, this section contrasts the baseline (BaU) scenario with two alternatives which decompose the effects of aging and education. The business-as-usual (BAU) scenario models the impacts of the demographic trends described earlier, i.e., a substantial aging of the population (the share of young people declines from 42 to 35 percent of the population) and a significant increase in skill intensity (the share of individuals with at least a secondary degree rises from 37 to 46 percent of the population, while the share of those with a tertiary degree increases from 1.6 to 2.8 percent). In the first alternative scenario (NoSkill), we isolate the impact of population aging from rising educational attainments by having the supply of both skilled and unskilled workers grow at the same rate, equal to the growth rate of the labor force. Effectively, this scenario illustrates the impact of the pure demographic dividend, as if the new larger labor force in 2030 retained the skill composition of today. A second alternative scenario (Demogr) develops a case where the economy benefits neither from rising skill attainments nor from the demographic dividend (i.e., the rising ratio of the labor force to population). In this scenario, the supply of skilled and unskilled workers grows at the same rate as total population (vs. growing at the rate of the 15-64 age group in the previous scenario). Table 3 shows the path of the main macroeconomic variables in the three scenarios. Since the growth of total factor productivity is the same in all three scenarios, the differences across them can be attributed directly to differences in labor force growth (across skill categories) and the dynamic effects of faster employment growth and higher skill content on income levels, savings, capital accumulation, and subsequent growth. As mentioned earlier, real GDP per capita grows at an average annual rate of 5.3 percent in the BaU scenario, where the supply of skilled workers grows at more than four times the rate of unskilled workers (an average of 2.4 percent per year vs. 0.6 percent per year). Real GDP per capita growth drops to 4.9 percent per year when the supply of skilled and unskilled workers grows instead at the same rate as the labor force (1.5 percent per year in the NoSkill scenario), and to 4.8 percent per year 7 For example, in an overlapping generations general equilibrium model, Fehr et. al. predict a 22% increase in high skilled wages vs. a 16% decline in low skilled wages between 2005 and 2050 ( pg. 15) due to the increased supply of low skilled labor, which some view as a demographic disaster (Majumder 2013). 8

when skilled and unskilled labor grow at the rate of total population growth (1.1 percent per year in the Demogr scenario). Since the largest differential is observed between the BaU and NoSkill scenarios, this means that a larger quantity of skills rather than total workers makes a bigger difference to the growth rate of per capita GDP in India. National accounts (percent change y-oy) Table 3: Macroeconomic variables in the three scenarios BaU NoSkill Demogr 2011 2015 2020 2025 2030 2015 2020 2025 2030 2015 2020 2025 2030 GDP at constant prices 6.6 6.9 6.8 6.7 6.3 6.5 6.5 6.4 6.1 6.4 6.4 6.3 Private consumption 6.8 7.1 7.1 7.0 6.4 6.7 6.7 6.7 6.2 6.6 6.5 6.5 Public consumption 6.6 6.9 6.8 6.7 6.3 6.5 6.5 6.4 6.1 6.4 6.4 6.3 Investment 6.2 6.4 6.4 6.3 6.0 6.2 6.3 6.3 5.8 6.1 6.2 6.2 Exports 6.2 6.5 6.4 6.3 5.8 6.0 5.9 5.8 5.6 5.8 5.7 5.6 Imports 6.2 6.5 6.6 6.6 5.9 6.2 6.2 6.2 5.7 6.1 6.1 6.1 Balance of payments (US$ million) Current account balance -73-75 -97-127 -167-75 -97-127 -167-75 -97-127 -167 (as percent of GDP) -3.9-3.3-3.1-2.9-2.8-3.3-3.1-3.0-2.9-3.3-3.1-3.0-2.9 Balance on goods and services -121-137 -189-266 -382-138 -191-270 -389-138 -191-271 -390 (as percent of GDP) -6.4-5.9-5.9-6.1-6.3-6.0-6.1-6.3-6.7-6.1-6.2-6.5-6.9 Exchange rate 47.9 47.6 47.9 47.9 47.7 47.4 47.6 47.5 47.3 47.4 47.5 47.4 47.1 Public finance (percent of GDP) Overall balance -11.0-12.8-13.7-14.7-15.8-13.1-14.3-15.6-17.1-13.2-14.5-16.0-17.5 Government revenue 13.2 13.3 13.5 13.8 14.0 13.2 13.4 13.6 13.8 13.2 13.4 13.6 13.7 Total expenditure 24.3 26.1 27.3 28.5 29.8 26.3 27.8 29.3 30.9 26.4 27.9 29.6 31.3 Recurrent expenditure 20.3 22.1 23.3 24.4 25.7 22.3 23.8 25.3 26.9 22.4 24.0 25.6 27.3 Capital expenditure 4.0 4.0 4.0 4.1 4.1 4.0 4.0 4.0 4.0 4.0 4.0 4.0 4.0 Memo (percent change y-o-y) Employment 1.8 1.6 1.4 1.2 1.7 1.4 1.2 1.0 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.9 Population 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.9 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.9 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.9 The evolution of returns to labor and capital under the three scenarios is shown in Table 4. In the base year, skilled workers earn on average 2.4 times the wages of unskilled labor. Under the BaU scenario, this premium declines to 1.7 times by 2030 as the rapid growth in the supply of skilled labor more than offsets the rising demand due to higher incomes. 8 Under the other two scenarios, however, the skill premium instead rises further to about 2.8 times the unskilled wage. This suggests that India s current skill mix (in terms of the share of skilled workers in the overall labor force) is unlikely to be sufficient to meet the needs of a rapidly growing economy, but also that skill premiums could decline somewhat over the next two decades unless growth accelerates beyond BaU assumptions or demand shifts more strongly into goods which require higher skill content to produce. The non-farm premium widens in all three scenarios as demand shifts further away from agricultural goods and into manufacturing and services. This is true despite acceleration in the migration of unskilled labor from farm to non-farm activities in response to the rising wage differentials, and this shift is particularly pronounced in the BaU scenario due to more rapid overall income growth. Returns to capital increase somewhat in the BaU scenario and decline in the two alternative simulations, as initial period capital stock is consistent with a higher growth path than what is realized under the two latter scenarios. 8 Real wages still more than double for all skill and sector categories. 9

Table 4: Factor returns in the three scenarios BaU NoSkill Demogr 2011 2030 % Δ per year 2030 % Δ per year 2030 % Δ per year Labor Supply (mln) Total 385.6 509.8 1.48 495.1 1.32 475.9 1.11 Skilled 178.5 279.2 2.38 229.2 1.32 220.3 1.11 Unskilled 207.1 230.6 0.57 265.9 1.32 255.6 1.11 Farm 122.4 128.7 0.27 149.0 1.04 143.1 0.83 Non-farm 84.7 101.9 0.98 116.9 1.71 112.4 1.50 Wages (2011 000 Rs) Total 106.0 246.7 4.55 266.1 4.97 274.4 5.14 Skilled 153.8 300.8 3.59 405.0 5.23 419.8 5.43 Unskilled 64.7 181.1 5.57 146.3 4.39 149.0 4.49 Farm 43.6 115.4 5.26 93.9 4.12 96.9 4.29 Non-farm 95.2 264.2 5.52 213.1 4.33 215.3 4.39 Capital Stock (% of GDP) 230.6 218.7-0.28 225.6-0.12 229.1-0.03 Rental rate 1.00 1.10 0.49 0.97-0.16 0.94-0.34 4.3 Inequality outcomes (micro-simulation results) Under all three scenarios, economic growth is sufficiently rapid to more than halve poverty headcounts at the $2/day (PPP) poverty line, reducing poverty from 69 percent of the population in 2011 to 12-16 percent in 2030 while extreme poverty ($1.25/day poverty line) could fall to single digits. Poverty reduction is most rapid under the BaU conditions, as per capita expenditure growth is fastest in this scenario. To be completed Table 5: Micro-simulation link variables BaU NoSkill Demogr Employment, % Δ Unskilled non-farm 20.3 38.0 32.8 Unskilled farm 5.2 21.7 16.9 Wages, % Δ in the Unskilled non-farm 9.0 7.3 3.4 premium over unskilled Skilled farm -36.4 31.1 31.9 farm workers Skilled non-farm -36.4 31.1 31.9 Consumption p.c., % Δ 175.6 159.0 151.7 Prices, % Δ over total CPI Food 14.5 10.8 11.8 Non-food -3.1-2.3-2.5 5. Conclusions This paper s results demonstrate that the demographic transition and the rising share of skilled workers could have substantial growth benefits for the Indian economy, raising the average per capita GDP growth over the 2011-2030 period by nearly 0.5 percentage points with most of the benefit coming from increasing skills rather than the rising worker/population ratio. Under the BaU scenario, the rising supply of skilled workers somewhat exceeds the demand for skills (despite the fact that growth is driven to a 10

large extent by skill-intensive service sectors) and the skilled/unskilled wage gap reduces by approximately one-third. In the alternative scenarios, which equalize the rates of growth of skilled and unskilled workers, the supply of skilled labor is insufficient to meet the demands of a rapidly growing economy and skill premiums instead rise by about one-third. In all scenarios, growth is driven increasingly by economic activity in the non-farm sector and, despite rising rural-urban migration, labor demand in the non-farm sector is sufficiently high to result in a small widening of the farm/non-farm wage gap. To be completed 11

6. References To be completed 12