the Federal Reserve to carry out exceptional policies for over seven year in order to alleviate its effects.

Similar documents
Balance Sheet Recessions

Discussion of. Balance Sheet Recessions. by Zhen Huo and Jose-Victor Rios-Rull. Dirk Krueger. University of Pennsylvania, CEPR, and NBER

Models of Government Expenditure Multipliers 1

Models of Government Expenditure Multipliers

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Expansions (periods of. positive economic growth)

SIEPR policy brief. Fiscal Stimulus in the Form of Lower Payroll Taxes. By Mark Bils and Pete Klenow. About The Author

Lecture 7. Unemployment and Fiscal Policy

Channels of Monetary Policy Transmission. Konstantinos Drakos, MacroFinance, Monetary Policy Transmission 1

The Science of Macroeconomics

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description

Business Cycles II: Theories

Chapter 2. Literature Review

Joseph S Tracy: A strategy for the 2011 economic recovery

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

Notes VI - Models of Economic Fluctuations

Zhen Huo and José-Víctor Ríos-Rull. University of Minnesota, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, CAERP, CEPR, NBER

On Abenomics and the Japanese Economy. Motoshige Itoh Member, Council on Economic and Fiscal Policy and Professor, University of Tokyo

A Review on the Effectiveness of Fiscal Policy

Real Business Cycle Model

Comment. John Kennan, University of Wisconsin and NBER

THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND THE GREAT RECESSION

State-dependent effects of monetary policy: The refinancing channel

The Liquidity-Augmented Model of Macroeconomic Aggregates FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS

Discussion of Capital Injection to Banks versus Debt Relief to Households

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Economics 134 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Spring 2018 Professor David Romer NOTES ON THE MIDTERM

The Anatomy of the Transmission of Macroprudential Policies

Global Financial Crisis and China s Countermeasures

19.2 Exchange Rates in the Long Run Introduction 1/24/2013. Exchange Rates and International Finance. The Nominal Exchange Rate

Box 1.3. How Does Uncertainty Affect Economic Performance?

Fabrizio Perri Università Bocconi, Minneapolis Fed, IGIER, CEPR and NBER October 2012

China Update Conference Papers 1998

Discussion of Unemployment Crisis

International Monetary and Financial Committee

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

New Ideas about the Long-Lasting Collapse of Employment after the Financial Crisis

STRUCTURAL TRANSFORMATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT EQUILIBRIUM. Joseph E. Stiglitz Trento Summer School July 2016

PERSPECTIVES ON LABOR MARKETS AND MONETARY POLICY

Indonesia: Changing patterns of financial intermediation and their implications for central bank policy

Session 9. The Interactions Between Cyclical and Long-term Dynamics: The Role of Inflation

Speaking Points for the Gaidar Forum Economic Perspective for Europe and Russia

Financial Risk and Unemployment

The Lack of an Empirical Rationale for a Revival of Discretionary Fiscal Policy. John B. Taylor Stanford University

Discussion of Do taxes explain European employment? Indivisible labor, human capital, lotteries and savings, by Lars Ljungqvist and Thomas Sargent

Discussion of paper: Quantifying the Lasting Harm to the U.S. Economy from the Financial Crisis. By Robert E. Hall

Market Reforms in a Monetary Union: Macroeconomic and Policy Implications

Haruhiko Kuroda: How to overcome deflation

Special Report. May 28, the United States and. represent over 50% of total employment in 60. the country. In addition to their majority

Obama s Tax Hikes on High-Income Earners Will Hurt the Poor and Everyone Else

Yes, We Can Reduce the Unemployment Rate

Discussion of Heaton and Lucas Can heterogeneity, undiversified risk, and trading frictions solve the equity premium puzzle?

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

Movements on the Price of Houses

Bubbles, Liquidity and the Macroeconomy

Introduction Background of country

Macroeconomics Robert J. Gordon Twelfth Edition

Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno

Aggregate and Distributional Dynamics of Consumer Credit in the U.S.

Yves Mersch: Monetary policy and economic inequality

Week 1. H1 Notes ECON10003

Macroeconomic Effects from Government Purchases and Taxes. Robert J. Barro and Charles J. Redlick Harvard University

Labor Market Tightness across the United States since the Great Recession

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for?

Microeconomic Heterogeneity and Macroeconomic Shocks

MACROECONOMICS. The Science of Macroeconomics. N. Gregory Mankiw. PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich. Modified for EC 204 by Bob Murphy

Macro Economic questions Part I

Economics 1012 A : Introduction to Macroeconomics FALL 2007 Dr. R. E. Mueller Second Midterm Examination October 19, 2007

Part VIII: Short-Run Fluctuations and. 26. Short-Run Fluctuations 27. Countercyclical Macroeconomic Policy

Haruhiko Kuroda: Moving forward Japan s economy under Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing

Financial Markets and Real Economic Activity

Working Paper No China s Structural Adjustment from the Income Distribution Perspective

The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters

Battle Over Japan's Mortgage Market Raises Default Risks

Inequality, Recessions and Recoveries. Fabrizio Perri. February 2014

The sharp accumulation in government debt can t go on forever

Macroeconomic Policy during a Credit Crunch

Chapter 13 The Open Economy Revisited: the Mundell-Fleming Model and the Exchange-Rate Regime

Okun s law revisited. Is there structural unemployment in developed countries?

Discussion of Fiscal Policy and the Inflation Target

Econ 223 Lecture notes 2: Determination of output and income Classical closed economy equilibrium

The U.S. Housing Market

The Conduct of Monetary Policy

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation

The Federal Reserve System and Open Market Operations

Discussion of Why Has Consumption Remained Moderate after the Great Recession?

Discussion of. \Aggregate Shocks and the Volatility of House Prices" by Rios-Rull and Sanchez-Marcos. Dirk Krueger

Chapter 16. MODERN PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS Third Edition

The Outlook for Consumer Spending and the Broader Economic Recovery

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates)

Economics of Money, Banking, and Fin. Markets, 10e (Mishkin) Chapter 25 Transmission Mechanisms of Monetary Policy

Jean-Pierre Roth: Recent economic and financial developments in Switzerland

Discussion of Arias Garrido Parra Rincon Do different types of capital flows respond

MONETARY POLICY EXPECTATIONS AND BOOM-BUST CYCLES IN THE HOUSING MARKET*

Monetary Policy and Resource Mobility

III. 9. IS LM: the basic framework to understand macro policy continued Text, ch 11

Perspectives on the U.S. Economy

Labor Markets in Turbulent Times: Some Evidence from Mexico

Transcription:

The Great Recession and Financial Shocks 1 Zhen Huo New York University José-Víctor Ríos-Rull University of Pennsylvania University College London Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis CAERP, CEPR, NBER October 2015 Abstract A case can be made for the Great Recession being the result of a large financial shock that makes household borrowing difficult. The channel involves large reductions in house prices, which trigger sharp reductions in consumption. We discuss the ingredients that a quantitative model of the economy requires to be successful in implementing such a theory. They include: wealth heterogeneity where the majority of the population needs to acquire financing to purchase houses despite the large amount of wealth in the economy; sizeable real frictions that hinder the transformation of consumption into exports and investment and that constraint the increase of the working hours of households; and, a role for expenditures in contributing to productivity. The aftershocks of the Great Recession are only just now receding, an episode that has prompted the Federal Reserve to carry out exceptional policies for over seven year in order to alleviate its effects. The Great Recession was the most severe since the Great Depression, with GDP and consumption falling about 10% below trend and not yet fully recovering. What was its cause? For many economists and for the popular press, it is the end product of a financial shock that made access to credit more difficult, resulted in major losses in financial wealth and made it necessary for economic agents to retrench in order to repair their balance sheets. While the notion of a large financial disruption being the trigger of the crisis is very intuitive, financial shocks cannot generate such costly outcomes in standard economic models built from first principles. Macroeconomic models make simplifying assumptions so that they are tractable with modern computational techniques, but still can be and mapped to the national accounts of an actual economy and retain the elements that are essential to answering the questions at hand. In this note, we describe the main ingredients of an economic model that are required to demonstrate formally 1Thanks to the National Science Foundation for Grant SES-1156228, to the comments of Kei-Mu Yi, and to the detailed input of Carolyn Wilkins. The views expressed herein are those of the author and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis or the Federal Reserve System.

how a financial disruption can cause economic losses of the magnitude of the Great Recession. We also discuss how such a model could be used to answer important policy questions. Most of the work in exploring the implications of financial disruptions has been concentrated on its effects on the production side of the economy. The argument for this approach is that firms have projects that they need to finance. In the context of the financial crisis, this work finds that financing became more difficult, preventing the implementation of many good projects. In fact, younger firms performed much worse in the Great Recession than in other recessions relative to larger and older firms that had easier access to credit. Some of the slack was taken up by low quality projects (those in the hands of firms with access to credit or to their own funds), resulting in lower new investment with worse performance than normally. There have been various excellent attempts to pursue this line of reasoning, but we do not think that it is powerful enough to generate a recession as big as the one we had for a number of reasons. First, investment is a small part of GDP. Second, many firms had large reserves of cash, so the firms that were subject to tighter lending conditions were few or relatively unimportant to overall GDP. Third, there is not a lot of evidence that cash rich firms expanded at the expense of cash stripped firms, which is an unavoidable implication of the theory. Finally, consumption contracted a lot in the Great Recession, and increased financial frictions on firms are not a big enough trigger to reduce consumption in these models. The bottom line is that the effects of financial shocks on the production side of the economy are only a minor contributor to the Great Recession. Whatever caused the crisis, it triggered a large reduction in consumption. According to standard theory, households reduce consumption because either a change in prices induces them to do so (for instance, an increase in interest rates would induce households to postpone consumption) or because they experience a reduction in wealth that induces them to save more to rebuild their wealth. Regarding the first explanation, interest rates fell considerably during this period; hence, they cannot explain the drop in consumption. Rather, the latter explanation is a prime candidate; wealth disappeared from households pockets, because prices of assets, mostly houses, fell dramatically during the crisis.

The question is whether a financial shock, and the ensuing difficulties to borrow, can trigger the kind of drop in house prices (and household wealth) we saw during the crisis. While household wealth in the United States immediately prior to the crisis (and currently) is close to 500 per cent of GDP, it is very concentrated. For most homeowners, the home is their primary or only source of wealth. This means that the sharp fall in this wealth, and their related capacity to borrow, hit this large segment of the U.S. population particularly hard.. Moreover, pension wealth cannot really be used as a buffer in terms of liquidity for consumption or collateral for borrowing. What we saw was consistent with these facts. The financial shock resulted in increased and widespread difficulties to get mortgages which, in turn, drastically reduced the demand for houses and ultimately resulted in plummeting housing prices (more than offsetting the effects of the credit expansion of earlier years). For a model to successfully deliver this type of explanation for the Great Depression, it has to include several ingredients. First, it must incorporate substantial wealth inequality and place many households in a position where a loss of housing wealth directly reduces their desired consumption. The model has to have many households buying houses on credit and the price of houses has to be dependent on credit availability. Recent work by Huo and Ríos-Rull (2014a) and Kaplan, Mitman, and Violante (2015) have large drops in housing prices as a result of financial shocks. Second, when households suffer a drastic reduction of wealth, they typically have incentives to save more and work harder to re-build their lost wealth. In the standard model, a reduction of wealth happens because of capital destruction, which increases the rate of return, and the response is to work harder and to save and invest more. The economy shifts quickly from production for consumption (e.g., espresso bars, hair salons) to production for saving into the future (e.g., net exports) To explain the facts, the model needs to incorporate frictions such that households cannot get all the work they desire. Turning the economy on a dime from being a consumption-oriented economy to a savings-oriented economy has to be difficult due to high costs of reallocation of resources. This dynamic is reinforced in a model that incorporates a global recession, as countries find it more difficult to increase exports.

Third, the model needs to use a production technology where lower demand translates into lower productivity, because of idle capacity, and profits. Service industries with fewer customers will look like they have lower productivity, and unsold consumer goods will show up as low-value inventory goods and perhaps be sold only at low prices. This is in contrast to the standard macroeconomic model in which lower demand and the accompanying reduction in employment results in an increase in productivity. Recent developments that use search theory in goods markets (Bai, Ríos-Rull, and Storesletten (2011), Dyrda and Rios-Rull (2012), Huo and Ríos-Rull (2014b), Huo and Ríos-Rull (2014a) and Petrosky- Nadeau and Wasmer (2015) allow for a different outcome whereby decreases in spending result in lower productivity. Fourth, a successful model must incorporate market imperfections. In standard macroeconomic models, when households do the best they can, how much they work and how much they consume is governed by a simple equation linking their real wages to their desire to substitute consumption and leisure. However, this relation has been shown empirically to not work very well. Fortunately, in the last few years the standard framework has been supplanted by the approach of Nobel laureates Dale Mortensen and Christopher Pissarides. According to the Mortensen and Pissarides approach, unemployed workers are not always able to find jobs even though they are looking. With the aid of search theory, there is discipline in how this is done and high unemployment can exist when firms post few vacancies. 2 Finally, the model should also incorporate a degree of unresponsiveness of interest rates to movements in consumption. When all is said and done, in standard models, much of the macroeconomic adjustment investment and consumption, in particular - occurs via interest rate movements. Reductions in consumption coming from a negative wealth effect push down interest rates, thus reducing the strength of the fall in consumption. However, interest rates all over the world have come down for reasons that are 2A trickier issue is the behavior of wages. Most traditional models imply large wage reductions as the economy s response to unemployment, again a feature that is not present in the data. While many models pose arbitrary rigidities in the wage adjustment process, recent work by Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Trabandt (2013) shows how wage inertia can arise endogenously.

not internal to the U.S. Moreover, the expansionary monetary policy has nominal interest rates close to the zero bound, leaving limited room for further interest rate reductions. To summarize, the most important implication of these ingredients for explaining the Great Recession is that assets prices adjust in response to financial frictions, which requires that large numbers of agents trade the assets (mostly houses) actively and are vulnerable to abrupt changes in financing terms. Because modern economies have a lot of wealth, a delicate balance must be achieved between the total amount of wealth and the existence of vulnerable people in the fringes. Also required is the existence of real rigidities that hinder the transformation of an economy mostly engaged in producing to consume into one capable of producing for the future, as well as frictions in goods and in labor markets that reduce labor productivity during the recession and slow down the adjustment of wages and of workers so unemployment can linger for a long time. While there is still much room for improvement, economic models that have these ingredients are a step up from standard models for answering important policy questions. This is because they feature the main channels of transmission of financial shocks, which we have learned only recently are so important. We look forward to seeing reliable answers to questions related to the effectiveness of anti-crisis fiscal and monetary policies and what types of households are more likely to increase consumption in response to income stimulus, among others.

References Bai, Y., J.-V. Ríos-Rull, and K. Storesletten (2011): Demand Shocks as Productivity Shocks, manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Christiano, L. J., M. S. Eichenbaum, and M. Trabandt (2013): Unemployment and Business Cycles, Mimeo, Northwestern University. Dyrda, S., and J.-V. Ríos-Rull Models of Government Expenditure Multipliers. Economic Policy Papers, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, March 2012. Huo, Z., and J.-V. Ríos-Rull (2014a): Financial Frictions, Asset Prices, and the Great Recession, manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. (2014b): Tightening Financial Frictions on Households, Recessions, and Price Reallocations, Forthcoming Review of Economic Dynamics. Kaplan, G., K. Mitman, and G. Violante (2015): Consumption and House Prices in the Great Recession: Model meets Evidence, Unpublished Manuscript, NYU. Petrosky-Nadeau, N., and E. Wasmer (2015): Macroeconomic Dynamics in a Model of Goods, Labor and Credit Market Frictions, Journal of Monetary Economics, 72, 97 113.