Predicting the Market

Similar documents
The Recovery Theorem* Steve Ross

Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) Option Pricing Model 40 th Anniversary Conference. The Recovery Theorem

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

The Recovery Theorem. Journal of Finance forthcoming. Steve Ross Franco Modigliani Professor of Financial Economics Sloan School, MIT.

The Recovery Theorem. Steve Ross Franco Modigliani Professor of Financial Economics MIT. Revised September 10, Abstract

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

The Black-Scholes Model

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Appendix A Financial Calculations

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

SOLUTION Fama Bliss and Risk Premiums in the Term Structure

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

The Black-Scholes Model

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 7 - part 2 Option Pricing Foundations

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

The Black-Scholes Model

Portfolio Management

Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005

Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs. Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Review for Quiz #2 Revised: October 31, 2015

Term Structure of Interest Rates. For 9.220, Term 1, 2002/03 02_Lecture7.ppt

The Forward-looking Equity Risk Premium of the Ross Recovery Theorem

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Generalized Recovery

OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL. Ilkka Rahikainen DIRECT METHODOLOGY FOR ESTIMATING THE RISK NEUTRAL PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTION

Lecture 5. Trading With Portfolios. 5.1 Portfolio. How Can I Sell Something I Don t Own?

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13

How Much Should You Pay For a Financial Derivative?

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Basics of Asset Pricing. Ali Nejadmalayeri

Z. Wahab ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 04/26/12. Volatility Smiles

B. Combinations. 1. Synthetic Call (Put-Call Parity). 2. Writing a Covered Call. 3. Straddle, Strangle. 4. Spreads (Bull, Bear, Butterfly).

Global Financial Management. Option Contracts

Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals

Problem Set 6. I did this with figure; bar3(reshape(mean(rx),5,5) );ylabel( size ); xlabel( value ); mean mo return %

Chapter 9 - Mechanics of Options Markets

Options Strategies. Liuren Wu. Options Pricing. Liuren Wu ( c ) Options Strategies Options Pricing 1 / 19

MATH 425 EXERCISES G. BERKOLAIKO

Volatility Surface. Course Name: Analytical Finance I. Report date: Oct.18,2012. Supervisor:Jan R.M Röman. Authors: Wenqing Huang.

Optimization Prof. A. Goswami Department of Mathematics Indian Institute of Technology, Kharagpur. Lecture - 18 PERT

How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile?

Slides III - Complete Markets

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

Estimating Forward Looking Distribution with the Ross Recovery Theorem

Finance: Lecture 4 - No Arbitrage Pricing Chapters of DD Chapter 1 of Ross (2005)

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

Math 5760/6890 Introduction to Mathematical Finance

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery

INTRODUCTION TO THE ECONOMICS AND MATHEMATICS OF FINANCIAL MARKETS. Jakša Cvitanić and Fernando Zapatero

Recovery Theorem with a Multivariate Markov Chain

University of Colorado at Boulder Leeds School of Business MBAX-6270 MBAX Introduction to Derivatives Part II Options Valuation

About Black-Sholes formula, volatility, implied volatility and math. statistics.

Web Extension: Continuous Distributions and Estimating Beta with a Calculator

( 0) ,...,S N ,S 2 ( 0)... S N S 2. N and a portfolio is created that way, the value of the portfolio at time 0 is: (0) N S N ( 1, ) +...

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

Ross Recovery theorem and its extension

A useful modeling tricks.

Fin 501: Asset Pricing Fin 501:

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher)

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

Smile in the low moments

Edgeworth Binomial Trees

Implied Volatility Surface

Mathematics in Finance

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Introduction: A Shortcut to "MM" (derivative) Asset Pricing**

The Recovery Theorem

Errata and updates for ASM Exam MFE (Tenth Edition) sorted by page.

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Financial Markets & Risk

Market Volatility and Risk Proxies

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

CONSTRUCTING NO-ARBITRAGE VOLATILITY CURVES IN LIQUID AND ILLIQUID COMMODITY MARKETS

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

A note on sufficient conditions for no arbitrage

Put-Call Parity. Put-Call Parity. P = S + V p V c. P = S + max{e S, 0} max{s E, 0} P = S + E S = E P = S S + E = E P = E. S + V p V c = (1/(1+r) t )E

Implied Volatility Surface

Any asset that derives its value from another underlying asset is called a derivative asset. The underlying asset could be any asset - for example, a

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Calibration of the Ross Recovery Theorem to Real-world Data, and Tests of its Practical Value

Modeling of Price. Ximing Wu Texas A&M University

Options Trading Strategies

ActuarialBrew.com. Exam MFE / 3F. Actuarial Models Financial Economics Segment. Solutions 2014, 1 st edition

MBF2263 Portfolio Management. Lecture 8: Risk and Return in Capital Markets

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I)

SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES EXAM IFM INVESTMENT AND FINANCIAL MARKETS EXAM IFM SAMPLE QUESTIONS AND SOLUTIONS DERIVATIVES

Option Pricing. Simple Arbitrage Relations. Payoffs to Call and Put Options. Black-Scholes Model. Put-Call Parity. Implied Volatility

Transcription:

Predicting the Market April 28, 2012 Annual Conference on General Equilibrium and its Applications Steve Ross Franco Modigliani Professor of Financial Economics MIT

The Importance of Forecasting Equity Returns Estimating the equity risk premium to use for asset allocation, risk management, pension planning, actuarial analyses, and accounting to mention just a few Forecasting market volatility, the probability of a crash or a boom, and, more generally, we want to estimate the whole probability distribution of future returns We need the probability distribution of returns for risk control, e.g., VAR type computations and scenario analysis We could use the distribution to test if a strategy that generates an alpha in backtesting is likely it is to do so out of sample Because financial markets price securities with payoffs extending out in time, the hope that they can be used to forecast the future has long been a source of fascination This talk outlines a new technique for using the prices of equity derivatives to determine the market s subjective forecast of the probability distribution of future returns as well as the market s risk premium the Recovery Theorem Page 2

Predicting Interest Rates In bond markets, we already use prices to tell us about the future Forward rates are rates we can lock in today for lending or borrowing in the future At best, forward rates only tell us what the market thinks will happen and certainly not what will actually happen, but even that is of great use We form our own models and forecasts and we ask experienced market participants what they think But whatever their opinions or our views, we compare these forecasts with forward rates Page 3

Forward Rates Spot Yield Curve 1.40% 1.20% 1.00% The one year rate two years forward 0.80% 0.60% 0.40% 0.20% 0.00% 1 2 3 4 5 Maturity (Years) Lend for 3 years Borrow for 2 years Result = Lend In 2 for 1 E.g., the one year rate in two years is implied by the current spot two and three year rates An investor could lock in lending at this rate (the in two for one) with spot rates by lending for three years at the three year rate and borrowing for two years at the two year rate (and the reverse is true for borrowing in two for one) Page 4

Predicting the Probability of Different Interest Rate Paths Forward rates are just one prediction out of the universe of possible future interest rates What we don t do with bond prices alone is answer a richer set of questions For example, what is the probability that the long rate will rise to 7% or higher in the next year, what is the chance that today s low rates will persist? To answer these questions, we need more than just forward rates derived from bond prices; we need contingent forward prices A contingent forward rate would be a rate for lending in the future that could be locked in today and that depends on what interest rates had done in the intervening period Example: A rate we could lock in today for a one year investment to be made two years from now if the 10 year rate then is, say, 6% Page 5

The State of the Art in Forecasting Equity Markets For equities we don t even ask the market for a single forecast like we do with forward interest rates Here is what we do now in the equity markets: We use historical market returns and the historical premium over risk-free returns to predict future returns We build a model, e.g., a dividend/yield model to predict stock returns We survey market participants and institutional peers We use the martingale measure or some ad hoc adjustment to it as though it was the same as the natural probability distribution What we want to do in the equity markets and the fixed income markets is find the market s subjective distribution of future returns We could then compare our forecasts and models of equity returns with the market s forecasts Page 6

The Options Market A put option on the market the S&P 500 - is a security with a specified strike price and maturity, say one year, that pays the difference between the strike and the market iff the market is below the strike in one year A put option is like insurance against a market decline with a deductible; if the market drops by more than the strike, then the put option will pay the excess of the decline over the strike, i.e., the strike acts like a deductible A call option on the market is a security with a specified strike price and maturity, say one year, that pays the difference between the market and the strike iff the market is above the strike in one year We will use the rich (complete) market in equity derivatives, to derive contingent equity forward prices and then use them to unlock the market s forecast Page 7

Volatility and Implied Volatility The markets use the Black-Merton-Scholes formula to quote option prices, and volatility is an input into that formula The implied volatility is the volatility that the stock must have to reconcile the Black-Scholes formula price with the market price The higher the implied vol, the more expensive are puts and calls Options with different times to maturity (tenors) and different strikes generally have different implied volatilities and the next slide displays this volatility surface Notice, though, that the market isn t necessarily using the BMS formula to price options, only to quote their prices Page 8

The Volatility Surface 50% 45% 40% 35% 30% Volatility (% p.a.) 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90% 100% 110% 120% Moneyness (% of spot) 130% 140% 4.5 3.5 2.5 1.5 0.5 150% Maturity (years) Surface date: January 6, 2012 0%-5% 5%-10% 10%-15% 15%-20% 20%-25% 25%-30% 30%-35% 35%-40% 40%-45% 45%-50% Page 9

Implied Vols, Risk Aversion, and Probabilities Implied vols for options on the S&P 500 are relatively high today (?) by historical standards, i.e., the level of the surface is high, particularly at the short end The vol surface is also highly skewed, i.e., prices for out-of-the-money puts are expensive because The market thinks that the probability of a crash is historically high And/or because the market is very risk averse Like any insurance, put prices are a product of these two effects: Put price = Risk Aversion x Probability of a Crash But which is it how much of the high price comes from high risk aversion and how much from a higher chance of a crash? The following slides develop a model that lets us separate these two effects and isolate the probability of a crash from the market s risk aversion Page 10

The Model A state is a description of what we use to forecast the equity market,, e.g., the current market level, last month s returns, current implied volatility The probability that the system moves from state i to state j in the next quarter is π ij П = [π ij ] the natural probabilities embedded in market prices P = [p ij ] is the matrix of contingent prices, i.e.,, the prices of a security that pays $1 if the system is currently in state i and transits to state j in the coming month The contingent prices are the Arrow-Debreu prices conditional on the current state of nature and they are proportional to the risk neutral or martingale probabilities We can find P from market prices and what we want is to use P to find П The next slide describes the relation between the contingent prices (or the martingale probabilities), p ij, and the natural probabilities, π ij The subsequent slides demonstrate how we can use this relation to find the natural probabilities, π ij, from the contingent prices, p ij Page 11

Risk Aversion and Contingent Prices The contingent price, p ij, depends on both the probability that a transition from state i to state j will occur and on market risk aversion Since purchasing a contingent security protects against the consequences of state j it is a form of insurance and, like any insurance, contingent prices are a product of these two effects: Contingent price = δ x Kernel x Probability of a transition P ij = δ x Kernel x π ij where δ is the market s average discount rate From arbitrage alone we know that a positive kernel exists (and is unique in complete markets) The traditional approach to estimating this relationship is to either determine the kernel from other data or use historical data to estimate the transition probabilities Page 12

Estimating the Pricing Kernel I It is often said that we observe the natural distribution but not the martingale probabilities let s see The graph on the next page shows the distribution of the martingale probabilities inferred from the vol surface, q(s) The following graph displays a lognormal estimated distribution of actual stock returns, f(s) The third graph displays the pricing kernel, i.e., q(s)/f(s) Clearly a ridiculously high E[ϕ 2 ] not pretty Maybe its telling us that there are fat tails with high probabilities of catastrophes Page 13

The Martingale Measure 2.5 The Martingale Probability Density (e rt q(s)) 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 0.10 0.35 0.60 0.85 1.10 1.35 1.60 1.85 Stock Price Page 14

The Natural Measure A Lognormal Fitted Density Function 0.12 0.10 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00 0.10 0.35 0.60 0.85 1.10 1.35 1.60 1.85 Stock Price Page 15

The Implied Pricing Kernel Density 8000000000000000000000 ϕ - state price/probability 7000000000000000000000 6000000000000000000000 5000000000000000000000 4000000000000000000000 3000000000000000000000 2000000000000000000000 1000000000000000000000 0 0.10 0.35 0.60 0.85 1.10 1.35 1.60 1.85 Stock Price Page 16

Estimating the Pricing Kernel II To get the natural density, suppose, instead, we use the histogram from bootstrapping stock return data (1960 to 2010) The graph on the next page shows the distribution of the resulting historical probabilities The next graph displays the pricing kernel, i.e., q(s)/f(s) Clearly we ve learned our lesson and only plotted it where the probability is positive This may be appropriate because the state price density must be absolutely continuous with respect to the natural measure But it isn t really because there are positive prices where the natural measure is zero Again, its telling us that there are fat tails with high probabilities of catastrophes Interestingly, the resulting volatility estimate for E[ϕ 2 ] = 0.0058 very tight Page 17

The Bootstrapped Natural Measure The Natural Histogram Density Function 0.14 0.12 0.10 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00 0.60 0.85 1.10 1.35 1.60 1.85 Stock Price Page 18

The Implied Pricing Kernel Density The Natural ϕ Density 12.00 10.00 8.00 6.00 4.00 2.00 0.00 0.60 0.85 1.10 1.35 1.60 1.85 Stock Price Page 19

Estimating the Pricing Kernel III Let s try a different tack and use a stock distribution implied by a particular utility function Let the representative agent in this complete market have a constant coefficient of relative risk aversion, R, and set the kernel equal to the marginal utility, ϕ(s) = S -R This implies that the natural density, f(s) = q(s)s R The next graphs display the kernels for three choices of R, R = 0, R =.5, and R = 5 The last graph displays the resulting inferred natural density Not surprisingly, the lower risk aversion coefficients provide tight bounds on the volatility of the pricing kernel, E[ϕ 2 ] = 1 and 1.03 for R = 0 and R = 1 respectively For R = 5,, E[ϕ 2 ] = 56 There is no obvious way to choose among these (insensible) estimates of the kernel Page 20

The Utility Natural Probability Density 3.50 The Kernel as the Marginal Utility 120000 The Kernel as the Marginal Utility 3.00 100000 2.50 2.00 80000 1.50 60000 1.00 40000 0.50 20000 0.00 0.10 0.35 0.60 0.85 1.10 1.35 1.60 1.85 Stock Price R = 0 R =.5 0 0.10 0.35 0.60 0.85 1.10 1.35 1.60 1.85 Stock Price R = 5 Page 21

The Pricing Martingale Measure Utility Implied Probabilities 0.16 0.14 0.12 0.10 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00 0.10 0.35 0.60 0.85 1.10 1.35 1.60 1.85 Stock Price R = 0 R =.5 R = 5 Page 22

The Recovery Theorem Contrary to our initial intuition, both the kernel and the probabilities can be recovered from the price equation alone The pricing equation has the form: p ij = δ x RA x π ij = δ[u (C(j))/U (C(i))] π ij A sufficient condition for this to hold is that the representative agent have an intertemporally additive separable utility function (or Epstein-Zinn recursive utility) What is critical is that the kernel is the ratio of the value of a function at the ending state, j, to the value at the initial state i, i.e., it doesn t depend on the transition from i to j If D is the diagonal matrix with the m risk aversion coefficients, RA(j), on the diagonal then the equilibrium equation has the form: P = δd -1 D Page 23

The Recovery Theorem Keep in mind that we observe P and we are trying to solve for Rearranging the basic pricing equation we have: = (1/δ) DPD -1 and since the probabilities in the row sum add to one e = e = <1,,1>, or DPD -1 e = δe, Px = δx where x = D -1 e is a vector whose elements are the inverses of the Risk Aversions This is a familiar eigenvector equation in mathematics and, assuming that P is irreducible (equivalently that is irreducible), from the Perron-Frobenius Theorem we know there is a unique positive eigenvector, x and eigenvalue δ From x we have D -1 and given δ we can now solve for the natural probabilities, Page 24

An Intuitive Argument for Recovery We have 11 possible price ranges ( -35%, -29%,, 54%) in our sample At each step the price transits from the current range one of the 11 possibilities to a new choice from the 11 possible price ranges This gives us a total of 11 x 11 possible price paths, and a total of 11 x 11 = 121 distinct equations, one for each possible path These equations have 121 unknown probabilities and 11 unknown Risk Aversions But since starting from any price, the 11 probabilities must add to one, we only need to find 10 probabilities for each starting price (as the 11 th will be implied); that is, 11 x 10 = 110 distinct probabilities Thus, we have a total of 110 + 11 = 121 unknowns to find Since the number of equations equals the number of unknowns, we can solve for the unknown probabilities and for the market Risk Aversions Page 25

Applying the Recovery Theorem A Three Step Procedure I picked an arbitrary but interesting date, April 27, 2011 Step 1: use option prices to get pure securities prices Step 2: use the pure prices to find the contingent prices Step 3: apply the Recovery Theorem to determine the risk aversion the pricing kernel and the market s natural probabilities for equity returns as of that date Page 26

Step 1: Estimating the Pure Prices Options complete the market, i.e., from options, we can create a pure Arrow- Debreu security, a digital option that only pays off iff the market is between, say, 1350 and 1352, one year from now (see Ross and Breeden and Litzenberger) We can do this with bull butterfly spreads, made up of holding one call with a strike of 1350, one with a strike of 1352, and selling two calls with strikes of 1351 The prices of these pure securities are P(c,j,t) where t is the maturity of the security and c denotes the current state these are the prices for a $1 payoff in state j in t periods The following two slides illustrate these pure prices for maturities up to 3 years and for returns from 35% down to 54% up - this range corresponds to proportional movements of one standard deviation = 30% annually Notice that the prices are lowest for large moves, higher for big down moves than for big up moves, and that after an initial fall prices tend to rise with tenor Page 27

Pure Security Prices for $1 Contingent Payoffs Pure Security Prices Tenor 0.25 0.50 0.75 1.00 1.25 1.50 1.75 2.00 2.25 2.50 2.75 3.00-35% $0.005 $0.023 $0.038 $0.050 $0.058 $0.064 $0.068 $0.071 $0.073 $0.075 $0.076 $0.076-29% $0.007 $0.019 $0.026 $0.030 $0.032 $0.034 $0.034 $0.035 $0.035 $0.035 $0.034 $0.034-23% $0.018 $0.041 $0.046 $0.050 $0.051 $0.052 $0.051 $0.050 $0.050 $0.049 $0.048 $0.046 Market -16% $0.045 $0.064 $0.073 $0.073 $0.072 $0.070 $0.068 $0.066 $0.064 $0.061 $0.058 $0.056 Scenario -8% $0.164 $0.156 $0.142 $0.128 $0.118 $0.109 $0.102 $0.096 $0.091 $0.085 $0.081 $0.076 0% $0.478 $0.302 $0.234 $0.198 $0.173 $0.155 $0.141 $0.129 $0.120 $0.111 $0.103 $0.096 9% $0.276 $0.316 $0.278 $0.245 $0.219 $0.198 $0.180 $0.164 $0.151 $0.140 $0.130 $0.120 19% $0.007 $0.070 $0.129 $0.155 $0.166 $0.167 $0.164 $0.158 $0.152 $0.145 $0.137 $0.130 30% $0.000 $0.002 $0.016 $0.036 $0.055 $0.072 $0.085 $0.094 $0.100 $0.103 $0.105 $0.105 41% $0.000 $0.000 $0.001 $0.004 $0.009 $0.017 $0.026 $0.036 $0.045 $0.053 $0.061 $0.067 54% $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 $0.001 $0.001 $0.002 $0.002 $0.003 $0.003 Priced using the SPX volatility surface from April 27, 2011 A pure security price is the price of a security that pays one dollar in a given market scenario for a given tenor - for example, a security that pays $1 if the market is unchanged (0% scenario) in 6 months costs $0.302 Page 28

Security Prices The Pure Security Price Surface $0.50 $0.45 $0.40 $0.35 $0.30 $0.25 $0.20 $0.15 $0.10 $0.05 $0.00 Tenor (years) -35% -29% -23% 0% -8% -16% Market Scenario 9% 19% 30% 41% 54% Priced using the SPX volatility surface from April 27, 2011 Page 29

Step 2: Estimating the Contingent Prices For example, from the table p(c,+19%, 3) = $0.129 Given the pure prices the next job is to get the contingent prices, p ij The prices we need are the contingent prices, p ij for, say, quarterly transitions As an example, the price of getting to up 19% by year end given that the market is down 8% by the end of the third quarter, is the contingent price of rising by three price range increments (9% each) in the last quarter We can find all these contingent forward prices by moving through the table of pure security prices along possible market paths and different tenors and strikes Page 30

Contingent Prices and Market Paths Today End of 3 rd Quarter End of Year P(1300,1600,3) 1600 P(1600,1450) 1500 1400 1450 P(1300,1450,4) current state, S&P = 1300 1300 1200 1100 P(1000,1450) P(1300,1000,3) 1000 Page 31

Contingent Forward Prices Quarterly Contingent Forward Prices Market Scenario Final Period -35% -29% -23% -16% -8% 0% 9% 19% 30% 41% 54% -35% $0.671 $0.241 $0.053 $0.005 $0.001 $0.001 $0.001 $0.001 $0.001 $0.000 $0.000-29% $0.280 $0.396 $0.245 $0.054 $0.004 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000-23% $0.049 $0.224 $0.394 $0.248 $0.056 $0.004 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 Market -16% $0.006 $0.044 $0.218 $0.390 $0.250 $0.057 $0.003 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 Scenario -8% $0.006 $0.007 $0.041 $0.211 $0.385 $0.249 $0.054 $0.002 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 Initial 0% $0.005 $0.007 $0.018 $0.045 $0.164 $0.478 $0.276 $0.007 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 Period 9% $0.001 $0.001 $0.001 $0.004 $0.040 $0.204 $0.382 $0.251 $0.058 $0.005 $0.000 19% $0.001 $0.001 $0.001 $0.002 $0.006 $0.042 $0.204 $0.373 $0.243 $0.055 $0.004 30% $0.002 $0.001 $0.001 $0.002 $0.003 $0.006 $0.041 $0.195 $0.361 $0.232 $0.057 41% $0.001 $0.000 $0.000 $0.001 $0.001 $0.001 $0.003 $0.035 $0.187 $0.347 $0.313 54% $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 $0.000 $0.032 $0.181 $0.875 Priced using the SPX volatility surface from April 27, 2011 Contingent forward prices are the prices of securities that pay one dollar in a given future market scenario, given the current market range - for example, a security that pays $1 if the market is down 16% next quarter given that the market is currently down 8% costs $0.211 Page 32

Step 3: Applying the Recovery Theorem to P We have 11 possible price ranges ( -35%, -29%,, 54%) in our sample At each step the price transits from the current range one of the 11 possibilities to a new choice from the 11 possible price ranges and we have found the (11x11) matrix of contingent forward prices, P We now apply the Recovery Theorem and solve for the eigenvalue, δ, and the eigenvector of P Dividing each price, p ij by δ [U (C(j))/U (C(i))] = π ij, the natural transition probability The next slides compare these predictions with the historical numbers using the 60 years of stock market history from 1960 through 2010 Page 33

The Bootstrapped (Historical) and Recovered Probabilities Six Months Out Probabilities: Cumulative Probabilities: Market Scenario Bootstrapped Recovered Bootstrapped Recovered -32% 0.0008 0.0120 0.0008 0.0120-26% 0.0012 0.0103 0.0020 0.0223-19% 0.0102 0.0250 0.0122 0.0473-12% 0.0448 0.0438 0.0570 0.0912-4% 0.1294 0.1242 0.1864 0.2153 0% 0.2834 0.2986 0.4698 0.5139 4% 0.3264 0.3765 0.7962 0.8904 14% 0.1616 0.1047 0.9578 0.9951 24% 0.0384 0.0047 0.9962 0.9998 35% 0.0036 0.0002 0.9998 1.0000 48% 0.0002 0.0000 1.0000 1.0000 Calculated from the SPX volatility surface from April 27, 2011 The historical probability of a drop of 32% or more was.08% and the probability of a decline in excess of 26% was.20% (using 5000 bootstrapped six month return periods) By contrast, the recovered probabilities of a catastrophic drop in excess of 32% is 1.2% and the probability of a decline in excess of 26% is 2.23%, over ten times higher Page 34

Recovered Natural Probabilities vs. Historical Probabilities 0.400 Probability Distributions 0.350 0.300 0.250 0.200 0.150 0.100 0.050 0.000-32% -26% -19% -12% -4% 0% 4% 14% 24% 35% 48% Historical Probabilities (1960-2010) Recovered Probabilities - April 27, 2011 Page 35

Annualized Recovered and Historical Statistics Statistics Recovered Historical Tenor 0.25 0.50 0.75 1.00 1.00 Mean 5.13% 5.52% 5.96% 6.16% 10.34% Sigma 11.66% 14.04% 14.69% 15.00% 15.47% Risk Premium 4.65% 5.28% 5.00% 4.31% 4.89% Sharpe Ratio 0.399 0.376 0.34 0.287 0.316 ATM vol 14.53% 16.69% 17.71% 18.20% Calculated from the SPX volatility surface from April 27, 2011 Page 36

Some Applications and a To Do List We have to test the recovery method by estimating the future market return probabilities in the past, e.g., daily or monthly, and then comparing those estimates with the actual future outcomes and with predictions using history up to that day We can also compare the recovered predictions with other economic and capital market factors to find potential hedge and/or leading/lagging indicator relationships This will point us to new standards and metrics for managing both equity and equity derivative portfolios based on our more complete understanding of the implications of current prices Extending the analysis to the fixed income markets is already underway in joint research with Ian Martin of Stanford Publish a monthly report on the current recovered characteristics of the stock return distribution: The forecast equity risk premium The chance of a catastrophe or a boom Page 37