Investment and Taxation in Germany - Evidence from Firm-Level Panel Data Discussion

Similar documents
Review of Recent Evaluations of R&D Tax Credits in the UK. Mike King (Seconded from NPL to BEIS)

Returns to R&D and the depreciation problem. Bronwyn H. Hall UC Berkeley and NBER

FINANCIAL FACTORS AND INVESTMENT IN BELGIUM, FRANCE, GERMANY, AND THE UNITED KINGDOM: A COMPARISON USING COMPANY PANEL DATA

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV

Does the Equity Market affect Economic Growth?

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

* + p t. i t. = r t. + a(p t

Adaptation, Anticipation and Social Interactions in Happiness: An Integrated Error-Correction Approach. Maarten Vendrik Maastricht University IZA

Internal and External Effects of R&D Subsidies and Fiscal Incentives Empirical Evidence Using Spatial Dynamic Panel Models

Do Domestic Chinese Firms Benefit from Foreign Direct Investment?

Swedish Lessons: How Important are ICT and R&D to Economic Growth? Paper prepared for the 34 th IARIW General Conference, Dresden, Aug 21-27, 2016

The Impact of Tax Policies on Economic Growth: Evidence from Asian Economies

Optimal fiscal policy

Demand and Supply for Residential Housing in Urban China. Gregory C Chow Princeton University. Linlin Niu WISE, Xiamen University.

Are we there yet? Adjustment paths in response to Tariff shocks: a CGE Analysis.

Impact of Devaluation on Trade Balance in Pakistan

Determination of manufacturing exports in the euro area countries using a supply-demand model

MEASURING THE OPTIMAL MACROECONOMIC UNCERTAINTY INDEX FOR TURKEY

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013

Simulations of the macroeconomic effects of various

Demographics and Secular Stagnation Hypothesis in Europe

Tax Incentives, International Tax and FDI: Evidence from South-East Asia

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Internal Finance and Growth: Comparison Between Firms in Indonesia and Bangladesh

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

Tax Evasion, Tax Monitoring Expenses and Economic Growth: An Empirical Analysis in OECD Countries

Acemoglu, et al (2008) cast doubt on the robustness of the cross-country empirical relationship between income and democracy. They demonstrate that

EFFECTIVENESS OF RESEARCH AND EXPERIMENTATION TAX CREDITS: CRITICAL LITERATURE REVIEW AND RESEARCH DESIGN

Conditional Convergence Revisited: Taking Solow Very Seriously

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

Has the Inflation Process Changed?

Volume Author/Editor: Mervyn A. King and Don Fullerton, eds. Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press

The test has 13 questions. Answer any four. All questions carry equal (25) marks.

The Impact of Foreign Direct Investment on the Export Performance: Empirical Evidence for Western Balkan Countries

The Effects of EU Formula Apportionment on Corporate Tax Revenues

The roles of expected profitability, Tobin s Q and cash flow in econometric models of company investment

The Time Cost of Documents to Trade

On the Returns to Invention Within Firms: Evidence from Finland. Prepared for the AER P&P 2018 Submission

ANALYSES OF MODEL DERIVED IS LM,

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

Investment 3.1 INTRODUCTION. Fixed investment

Abstract. Crop insurance premium subsidies affect patterns of crop acreage for two

Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions

SHORT-RUN EQUILIBRIUM GDP AS THE SUM OF THE ECONOMY S MULTIPLIER EFFECTS

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

Using Land Values to Predict Future Farm Income

Ruhm, C. (1991). Are Workers Permanently Scarred by Job Displacements? The American Economic Review, Vol. 81(1):

Greenfield Investments, Cross-border M&As, and Economic Growth in Emerging Countries

WORKING PAPERS INFORUM WORKING PAPER Investment and Exports: A Trade Share Perspective. Douglas Nyhus Qing Wang.

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender *

The Stock Market Crash Really Did Cause the Great Recession

Explaining the Last Consumption Boom-Bust Cycle in Ireland

INFLATION TARGETING AND INDIA

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot

Do labor market programs affect labor force participation?

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

Input Tariffs, Speed of Contract Enforcement, and the Productivity of Firms in India

User cost elasticity of capital revisited

Base erosion and profit shifting in multinational corporations

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011

The Role of APIs in the Economy

Do Financing Constraints Matter for R&D?

Empirical Analysis of the US Swap Curve Gough, O., Juneja, J.A., Nowman, K.B. and Van Dellen, S.

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

effective interest rate is constant and the price fall is large, too, the movement opposite to that shown in the figure

Chapter 2 Fiscal Policies in Germany and France

Productivity Trends of New Zealand Electricity Distributors

Capital Gains Realizations of the Rich and Sophisticated

The Impact of Trade and Factor Flows on Domestic Taxation

The Labor Market Consequences of Adverse Financial Shocks

Dynamic Demographics and Economic Growth in Vietnam. Minh Thi Nguyen *

Deregulation and Firm Investment

Uncertainty and Investment Dynamics

WHAT DOES THE HOUSE PRICE-TO-

Life Insurance and Euro Zone s Economic Growth

Endogenous Growth with Public Capital and Progressive Taxation

Unemployment, Income Growth and Social Security

An Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between Macroeconomic Variables and Stock Prices in Bangladesh

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland

Volume 29, Issue 2. A note on finance, inflation, and economic growth

/JordanStrategyForumJSF Jordan Strategy Forum. Amman, Jordan T: F:

Online Appendix Only Funding forms, market conditions and dynamic effects of government R&D subsidies: evidence from China

Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note*

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND UNEMPLOYMENT RATE OF THE TRANSITION COUNTRY THE CASE OF THE CZECH REPUBLIC

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility

Ten Years after the Financial Crisis: What Have We Learned from. the Renaissance in Fiscal Research?

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Topic 2. Productivity, technological change, and policy: macro-level analysis

Glossary. Average household savings ratio Proportion of disposable household income devoted to savings.

Topic 3: Endogenous Technology & Cross-Country Evidence

The Simple Regression Model

Long-run Stability of Demand for Money in China with Consideration of Bilateral Currency Substitution

A Test of Two Open-Economy Theories: The Case of Oil Price Rise and Italy

Spillovers from public intangibles

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks

Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality. June 19, 2017

Employment Effects of Reducing Capital Gains Tax Rates in Ohio. William Melick Kenyon College. Eric Andersen American Action Forum

Transcription:

Investment and Taxation in Germany - Evidence from Firm-Level Panel Data Discussion Bronwyn H. Hall Nuffield College, Oxford University; University of California at Berkeley; and the National Bureau of Economic Research 1 Introduction Several different factors have come together to make the topic of this conference, Investing Today for the World of Tomorrow, a timely one for any developed economy, and particularly for Germany. Among them are increased global competition, a seemingly rapid pace of technological change, especially in information-based and network industries, and, in Germany, the need to absorb and restructure industrial firms in the former DDR. All of these factors imply an accelerated need for investments both to replace aging plant and equipment and in order to redirect activities from those subject to competition from regions with lower labor costs to those that are highly knowledge-intensive and more likely to support the relatively high wages that are the norm in developed countries. Fear that industry will not undertake the investment necessary to provide adequate job growth has frequently led governments to subsidize investment spending via the tax code. In this paper, Harhoff and Ramb make an important contribution to our understanding of the magnitude and the extent of firm responses to the investment incentives put in place by the German government over the past ten years or so. In addition, they use their estimated investment equation to forecast the effects of some recent changes to the German tax law, in particular those introduced in the 2001 tax reform law. Although the questions of interest here are aggregate or macro-economic in nature, being concerned with increasing investment across the economy, it is essential to base an analysis of the incentive effects of tax changes on data obtained at the level of the decision-maker and tax-paying unit, which in this case is the firm. At this level it is possible to use a behavioral economic model to describe the investment decision, and it is also possible to take account of the fact that firms are very heterogeneous both in their tax positions and in their investment needs and goals, rather than relying on representative firm behavior.

The authors are to be complemented on their efforts to obtain a dataset with very wide coverage, both with respect to sectors and to firm size, and for using estimation strategies that control both for permanent unobserved differences across firms, and for simultaneity in the choice of investment level, output level, and tax rate (which affects the cost of capital). The paper also provides a very useful discussion of the features of the German tax law as it affects business investment and incorporates these features in a tax-adjusted cost of capital based on the King-Fullerton methodology. Because the authors have a much larger range of sizes and types of firms than previous studies using data from Germany and other European countries and because they are able to construct and use a firm-specific cost of capital, their results differ somewhat from those earlier results. 1 Sorting out which of these is the main cause of differences remains a topic for future research. In this comment I first make some remarks about the econometric difficulties and results, and then discuss the tax policy experiment. 2 Econometrics The authors present results for a distributed lag model of investment (ADL) using two panel data fixed effect estimators (Ordinary Least Squares with firm effects, either differenced or within, and Generalized Method of Moments on differenced data). Both of these estimators allow for permanent unobserved differences across firms, but only the second allows for endogeneity or simultaneity of the right hand side variables with the error term (unexpected or unexplained investment). This simultaneity can arise because output, cash flow, and some determinants of the cost of capital (in particular, the firm s tax position or depreciation rates) are chosen simultaneously with the investment level. Given this discussion of the difference between OLS and GMM, it is instructive to compare the results in Tables 5 and 6 of the paper. First, there is relatively little difference between the Within and First Differences OLS estimates, which suggests that the bias arising from transitory measurement error in the right hand side variables is rather small. Second, the main difference between the OLS and GMM estimates is in the coefficient of the cost of capital, which is about 33 percent lower in the GMM results. The implication is that the simultaneity between investment and the cost of capital is fairly substantial, but that it probably 1 For studies using large firms from Germany, France, Belgium, the United Kingdom, and the United States, and without a cost of capital, besides Bond, Harhoff, and van Reenen (1999), cited in this paper, see Bond et al (1997), Mairesse, Hall, and Mulkay (1999), and Mulkay, Hall, and Mairesse (this volume).

arises from the fact that firms respond fairly quickly to falls in the cost of capital (because unforecastable changes in the cost of capital are associated with investment in the same way as forecastable changes). Simultaneity due to the choice of tax parameters is less likely to be a transitory phenomenon that can be addressed by this type of instrumental variable estimation, except for that which arises through the choice of new equity financing for the investment, and this feedback effect has the opposite sign from that which was found. The authors also present results for an error-correcting version of their distributed lag model (ECM). As Mairesse, Hall, and Mulkay (1999) discuss, the ADL and the ECM versions of the investment equation, although superficially alike, have very different dynamic properties. The differenced ADL removes all information about levels of investment, output, and prices from consideration, and treats the firm effect as representing differences in the growth rates of capital and output. The ECM retains information about the levels of capital and output and the firm effects correspond to different capital-output ratios for different firms. Thus the ECM is able to describe the long run equilibrium from shocks to output or the cost of capital, while the ADL is primarily suitable for measuring a quasi-short run elasticity of investment with respect to the cost of capital. Although possibly less informative, it is also less restrictive (since in effect, it has been differenced one additional time). Because the ECM is conceptually a somewhat better model that is able to deliver long run as well as short run behavior, it is useful to compare its results to those from the ADL. Table 7 shows that these results differ somewhat from those obtained for large firms in Germany and OECD economies by previous authors (including one of the present authors). The most important differences are that the lagged dependent variable has a positive coefficient (which is theoretically unattractive), that output growth enters negatively rather than positively, and that the error-correcting term has a very small estimated coefficient. For example, Bond, Harhoff, and van Reenen (1999) obtain 0.085 (0.055) for this coefficient using data on approximately 200 large German firms, whereas the coefficient estimate here is 0.028 (0.013). 2 Because of these somewhat unsatisfactory results, the authors focus on the ADL estimates in performing their tax reform scenario computations. As mentioned earlier, it is unclear whether these differences arise because the cost of capital is included in the equation or because the sample is much larger and includes many smaller firms. Based on the estimates, I hypothesize that most of the explanation is the latter. The positive coefficient on lagged investment, the negative coefficient on output (unlike estimates using larger firms, which usually 2 Other estimates in the literature are 0.141 (0.052) for the UK (Bond, Harhoff, and van Reenen 1999), -0.091 (0.061) for the United States, and 0.109 (0.034) for France (Mulkay, Hall, and Mairesse, this volume).

are nearly constant returns), and the limited error-correction behavior all suggest that these firms have a variety of growth paths and are not yet in a stable equilibrium. This would explain why the ADL specification, which allows for firm-specific growth rates, is somewhat more satisfactory than the ECM, which does not. It also suggests that a richer model of investment that incorporates differences across sectors or firms sizes might be appropriate and informative. I hope that in future work, the authors will be able to undertake this. 3 Cost of Capital and Tax Reform To understand how changes in the tax system impact the cost of capital in the Harhoff-Ramb framework, it is useful to look more closely at equations (2.1) and (2.6), taking into account the features of the tax system that they use. Taking the logarithm of the user cost variable, we obtain the following expression: log J it = log p jt + log (1-A it ) + log (ρ t +δ e jt ) log (1-τ re t ) where j denotes sector specific variables, i denotes firm specific variables, and I have suppressed to source of finance subscript f. From Table 2, we can see that, except for the cost to institutional investors of issuing new equity, the required rate of return for internal finance is simply r, and for external finance, r times (1-τ cr ). The main impacts of the tax system in this equation are therefore threefold: 1) A it re (the depreciation allowances available), τ t (the tax rate on retained profits including business tax), and τ cr t (the tax rate on retained profits). Reductions in the latter two rates have offsetting effects: the required rate of return for new debt and/or equity increases, but the pre-tax cost required to get a given post-tax return decreases (the last term in J). The latter effect will dominate in the cost of capital formula because the first is mediated by the interest rate (which is small). However, the effect of reducing depreciation allowances is direct and increases the cost of capital. Harhoff and Ramb find that the proposed changes in the 2001 Act are dominated by this term and that the overall cost of capital may therefore increase. To this one might add that it is possible that economic depreciation (δ e ) may be increasing over time, at least for equipment investment, because of rapid technological change in the equipment sector, which implies that the cost of capital may also be increasing for this reason. A second look at the design of depreciation allowances may be desirable for both these reasons.

References Bond, S. R., J. A. Elston, J. Mairesse, and B. Mulkay. 1997. Financial Factors and Investment in Belgium, France, Germany, and the UK: A Comparison Using Company Panel Data. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 5900. Mairesse, J., B. H. Hall and B. Mulkay. 1999. Firm-Level Investment in France and the United States: An Exploration of What We Have Learned in Twenty Years. Annales d'economie et de Statistiques 55-56, pp. 27-67. Mulkay, B., B. H. Hall and J. Mairesse. 2000. Investment and R&D in France and the United States. This volume.