Health, Consumption and Inequality

Similar documents
Health, Consumption and Inequality

Social Security, Life Insurance and Annuities for Families

1 Dynamic programming

A Quantitative Theory of Unsecured Consumer Credit with Risk of Default

Balance Sheet Recessions

A Model with Costly Enforcement

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Retirement Financing: An Optimal Reform Approach. QSPS Summer Workshop 2016 May 19-21

Business Cycles and Household Formation: The Micro versus the Macro Labor Elasticity

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

1 The Solow Growth Model

Saving During Retirement

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

Movements on the Price of Houses

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

Directory. The Value of Life and the Rise in Health Spending p.1/34

Productivity and the Post-1990 U.S. Economy

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Consumption, Investment and the Fisher Separation Principle

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Nordic Journal of Political Economy

The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market

Unemployment, Consumption Smoothing and the Value of UI

A dynamic model with nominal rigidities.

Solutions to Problem Set 1

Assets with possibly negative dividends

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

004: Macroeconomic Theory

Household Finance in China

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System

Feb. 20th, Recursive, Stochastic Growth Model

Chapter 4 Topics. Behavior of the representative consumer Behavior of the representative firm Pearson Education, Inc.

Inflation, Demand for Liquidity, and Welfare

Development Microeconomics Tutorial SS 2006 Johannes Metzler Credit Ray Ch.14

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

14.05: SECTION HANDOUT #4 CONSUMPTION (AND SAVINGS) Fall 2005

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

Optimal portfolio choice with health-contingent income products: The value of life care annuities

Lecture 7: Optimal management of renewable resources

The Value of Unemployment Insurance

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Retirement in the Shadow (Banking)

Exchange Rate Policies at the Zero Lower Bound

Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

ON THE ASSET ALLOCATION OF A DEFAULT PENSION FUND

Endogenous employment and incomplete markets

Characterization of the Optimum

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO)

Road Map. Does consumption theory accurately match the data? What theories of consumption seem to match the data?

Public Pension Reform in Japan

Business Cycles II: Theories

2.6 Putting the Tools to Work the Effect of Temporary Assistance Programs on the Budget Constraint

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Topic 6. Introducing money

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

From Wages to Welfare: Decomposing Gains and Losses From Rising Inequality

Inflation. David Andolfatto

ECNS 303 Ch. 16: Consumption

1. Help you get started writing your second year paper and job market paper.

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

Business Cycles II: Theories

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography

1 No capital mobility

In understanding the behavior of aggregate demand we must take a close look at its individual components: Figure 1, Aggregate Demand

Saving for Retirement: Household Bargaining and Household Net Worth

A Model with Costly-State Verification

Slides III - Complete Markets

Inflation & Welfare 1

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Unemployment equilibria in a Monetary Economy

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Financial Economics: Risk Aversion and Investment Decisions

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Graduate Public Finance

Explaining Consumption Excess Sensitivity with Near-Rationality:

Incentives and economic growth

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory. Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130

A simple wealth model

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve

Optimal tax and transfer policy

Topic 4. Introducing investment (and saving) decisions

Choice Under Uncertainty (Chapter 12)

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007

A Theory of Credit Scoring and Competitive Pricing of Default Risk

ECON385: A note on the Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH). In this note, we will try to understand the permanent income hypothesis (PIH).

Wealth Accumulation in the US: Do Inheritances and Bequests Play a Significant Role

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

Transcription:

Health, Consumption and Inequality Josep Pijoan-Mas and José Víctor Ríos-Rull CEMFI and Penn February 2016 VERY PRELIMINARY Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 1/36

How to Assess Inequality We construct measures of Inequality between groups (today College Graduates vs those that have not finished High School) These measures use the notion of Compensated Variation (how much money does one group have to receive to be indifferent between remaining in his group instead of being in another group) These Measures take into account Differences in Mortality Differences in Health The actions that will be taken by the disadvantaged groups to improve mortality, health, and wellbeing when given more resources In doing so, we have developed, what we think are novel ways of measuring health-improving technology with medical expenditures Cole, Kim, Krueger (2015) have estimated the role of inconvenient activities Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 2/36

Consumption Based Measures of Inequality Education and Wealth So how unequal are College Grads from those that did not graduate from High School (Dropouts for short)? College Grads from 50 on consume over their remaining lifetime 81% more than Dropouts, so in principle it would take 81 additional cents per year for each dollar that the Dropouts consume to be as well off as College graduates. [We made some adjustments: family size, but not others (leisure)]. What about wealth? Top vs bottom quintiles (also at 50)? They can still move up and down. Households in the top quintile at age 50 seem to consume 51% more over their remaining lifetime which seems too little but It is wealth not income Our data set (PSID, HRS) surely misses the top 10% in wealth so this is not such a huge jump. Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 3/36

Not so Fast, Dropouts and the wealthy live longer At 50 the Expected Longevity l 50 of white males Differences between socioeconomic types l 50 difference Education Dropouts 75.6 0.0 High School 78.6 3.0 College Grads 81.9 6.3 Wealth q5 76.4 0.0 q4 78.4 2.0 q3 79.4 3.0 q2 80.0 3.6 q1 80.6 4.2 Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 4/36

How much more is worth to be in another group? Need to compare value of consumption with value of being alive. Can a life have a price? According to many, yes. Big literature on this that values a life according to modern standards at about $100,000-$150,000 per year. This is what is called the Value of Statistical Life. It is based on people s choices. (like the premium for dangerous wages) We set it at $100,000 (2005) per year. Yields conservative estimates. It also requires an assessment of the decreasing value of consumption, that following standard practice in Economics is valued with logs. As people get richer, they value more to be alive: they will allocate an increasing share of their resources to live one more year. Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 5/36

The Trade-Off Between Consumption and Being Alive Consider a person that lives potentially forever, but Each period can die with probability 1 γ. So her life expectancy is She discounts the future at rate β per period. We write the total value of consuming c while alive and having survival probability of γ as 1 1 γ Ω(c, γ) = β t γ t t=0 [log c + α] = log c + α 1 βγ We need to find the α that is consistent with the $100,000 per year value of life. We can do so by solving Ω c dc + Ω γ dγ = 0, making dγ large enough to add one more year of life. Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 6/36

Details to derive α Value of Statistical Life measures the willingness to pay for an extra year of life. Proceed by Ω c dc+ω γ dγ = 0 dc dγ = β u (c) 1 βγ u c (c) = β (α + log c) c 1 βγ To map the Value of Statistical Life (VSL) into dc dγ note that: W/ annuities, a payment da translates into a constant consumption flow: dc = (1 γ + r) da A change de in life expectancy requires a change in the survival prob of Hence VSL = da de (Using β (1 + r) = 1) dγ = (1 γ) 2 de ( ) 2 (1 γ)2 dc 1 γ = 1 γ + r dγ = (α + log c) c 1 γ + r Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 7/36

Details to derive α We use VSL = $100, 000 c = $33, 657 (Total household expenditure per adult minus health expenditure, NIPA 2005) γ = 0.965 (e 50 = 28.8 years for white males) r = 3.5% We obtain α = 1.55 u (c) = 11.98 Ω (c) = 1+r u (c) = 177.84 1 γ+r We are now in business to calculate welfare differences when longevities differ. Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 8/36

So how much is the extra life of different groups worth? How much extra consumption has to be given to the low type to be as happy as (indifferent) the high type? We ask how much do people in group i need to get be indifferent between remaining in group i and switching to group 1 but keeping their own survival probabilities. Currently they consume {c 1, c i } and have survival probabilities {γ 1, γ i }. We need to solve for x in log c 1 + α 1 βγ 1 = log (1 + x) ci + α 1 βγ i Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 9/36

How much extra consumption has to be given to the low type to be as happy as (indifferent) Welfare difference between types Due only to Consumption Due to Consumption and Life Expectancy Education 0.81 6.45 Bw Dr. & Coll Wealth 0.51 2.91 Between 1 & 5 Quint But Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 10/36

Endogeneity of Life Duration: Could it be that the low groups could have used the extra resources to increase their life duration? This would have 1 Reduced differences in life durations. 2 Reduced the size of inequality because of a much more efficient use of the resources. The assessment requires an adjustment based on how much more longevity money can buy: Need to measure health technology. We need to separate how much of the life expectancy is intrinsic to the type (either it was settled before or because of selection) and how much can be bought. We use theory (a revealed preference argument) to back out this technology using data on consumption c i, health expenditures x i, and expected longevities l 50,i across types. Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 11/36

Backing out the life extending technology Take two types, say college and dropout. Assume survival probability takes the following functional form: γ i ( x i) = λ i (x i ) 1 ν 0 + λ 1 1 ν This form is flexible: it can impute all the advantage as being intrinsic to the type (λ 1 = 0) (It could also be the result of different preferences on non-monetary investments that we will ignore.) or as being the result of having more resources (λ i 0 = 0) or somenthing in between. We have to specify 4 parameters (ν, λ 1, and the two λ i 0 ) in addition to the preference parameters that we have used (β, α). We do need a model of health investment to do this. Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 12/36

A model of health investment Perpetual Youth model with choice of consumption c t and medical expenditure x t Types i differ in resources and survival probability technology γ i (x). Actual survival is a combination of both. Health investment at t increases survival probability only at t. External (Internal) Life annuities: extra return on savings of 1/γ i All individuals of type i are identical, so they make the same choices. Terms in red exist under the interpretation (that today we will ignore) of having annuities depend on own rather than aggregate behavior. Preferences t=0 β t [Π t 1 s=1 γi (x s )] [log c t + α] Budget constraint: c t + x + γ i (x t ) a t+1 = a t (1 + r) Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 13/36

Solving this model (what will the person do?) { V i (a) = max u ( a (1 + r) x γ i (x) a ) } + βγ i (x) V i (a ) c,x,a The solution satisfies ( u c c i ) = β ( γi x i) (1 + r) [ γ i (x i u c (c i ) ] [ = β (1 + r) u c (c i ) ] ) ( u c c i ) [ ( 1 + dγi x i) ] ( a = β dγi x i) V i (a ) dx dx Assume β(1 + r) = 1. Then the solution is stationary (a = a) c i = (c i ) ] (c i ) 1 = [β V i (a ) a λ i (x i ) ν = (c i ) 1 = c i [ ] β (log c i + α) 1 β (λ i 0 + λ 1 (x i ) 1 ν 1 ν ) a c i λ i (x i ) ν Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 14/36

Taking Stock: We have the following 4 equations Optimal Choices for both types (c i ) 1 β (log c i + α) = ( ) λ i (x i ) ν 1 β λ i 0 + λ 1 (x i ) 1 ν 1 ν The values of life expectancy for both types γ i = λ i 0 + λ 1 (x i ) 1 ν 1 ν We can solve for the four unknowns in red using those equations. This tells us how easy is to transform money into health and how much of the differences in life expectancy are intrinsic to those groups. Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 15/36

An insight: ν can be identified independently If we rewrite the optimal choice condition and take the ratio between types, we obtain c 1 c i = (log ci + α) (1 β γ 1 ) ( x1 ) ν (log c 1 + α) (1 β γ i ) x i The ratio x c for a given type gives us λ 1. The observed life expectancies of each types give us λ i 0 of each type We are now ready to see what the data tells us Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 16/36

What we have in the data: PSID 2005-2013, white males aged 50-88 Out of Pocket Medical Expenditures hospital / nursing home doctors prescriptions / in-home medical care / other services health insurance premia Non-medical expenditure Non-durable goods and services in PSID 2005-2013 (excluding education and medical) Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 17/36

Let s look at the Data hundreds of dollars 22 18 14 10 6 CG HSD (a) Medical expenditure (per capita) thousands of dollars 22 18 14 10 6 (b) Non-medical expenditure (equivalized) CG HSD 2 2 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 0.5 0.4 CG HSD (c) Ratio medical to non-medical 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 18/36

Summarizing the Data Inputs Coll Grad Dropout CG-Dr Longevity at 50 (HRS) 81.9 75.6 6.3 Health Expenditures (PSID) 1,660 986 68.4% Relative to Cons 0.1647 0.1526 7.9% The higher medical expenditures to consumption ratio for the college graduates confirms that indeed life duration is more important the richer people are. But not by a lot. So maybe money does not buy so much life expectancy. Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 19/36

Estimates College Grads Dropouts ν 1.13 λ 1 0.027 λ i 0 0.976 0.969 γ 0.969 0.961 The interpretation is that λ i 0 are the maximum life expectancy after 50 if all the money in the world was spent in trying to make it as big as possible. College grads can make it to 91.4 on average under the best health care. Dropouts can make it to 82.0 on average under the best healh care. Most of longevity differentials cannot be fixed after 50 with money. Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 20/36

A picture of the health technology 0.20 0.17 CG HSD (a) x/c ratio 35 30 CG HSD (b) Life expectancy ratio 0.15 0.12 years 25 0.10 0 25 50 75 100 consumption (thousands) 20 0 25 50 75 100 consumption (thousands) The ratio x/c declines (very mildly) with c: medical spending more a necessity than a luxury But higher types spend more because they have higher λ 0, which makes health investments more profitable Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 21/36

Some Counterfactuals Outputs Coll Grad Dropout Diff w Coll G Data 31.90 25.60 6.30 Dropouts x as Coll Gr 26.02 5.88 College G x as Dropouts 31.27 0.63 Dropouts spending in health care as college graduates close 6.7% of gap. College graduates spending in health care as dropouts still have 90% of the actual gap. Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 22/36

The adjusted size of inequality Welfare difference between types Due only to Due to Cons. With Choice of Cons. and Exogenous Health Investment Education 0.81 6.45 4.75 Bw Dr. & Coll Wealth 0.51 2.91 Between 1 & 5 Quint Sizable but not enormous difference. The extra resources are spent so that consumption per year is 4.7 times larger and health investment expenditures per year are 4.4 times larger instead of all in consumption. Life expectancy of Dropouts goes up by 1 year closing about one sixth of the gap. Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 23/36

What about Health? Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 24/36

Taking Health into Account We have abstracted from differences in health across people, but We want to reasses our findings by looking at the role of investments that extend life via maintaining health. A natural way to proceed is to postulate that Survival conditional on health h, depends on type (education) i, and health investments (x) to get γ i (x, h). Health transitions also depend on health h, type (education) i, and health investments (x) to get Γ i h,h (x). Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 25/36

Some prior information restricts options Our earlier research showed that short term (two years ahead) survival only depends on self assessed health status and not on education type. (Pijoan-Mas and Rios-Rull (2014)) We take this to mean that 1 Survival conditional on health is sufficient and no type specific advantage exists. 2 Investments in health care only affect the evolution of health and not survival. If it did, educated people with more resources would have invested more and got better outcomes, which they did not. Therefore we are left with an exogenous γ h and a function Γ i h,h (x) where we observe the optimal choice. Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 26/36

A model with investments in health: Other Issues to Deal with 1 Complete markets: Annuities 2 Complete markets: State Contingent Markets Guarantees stationarity. Allows us to ignore issues of financial risks associated to health that are (likely) second order. 3 Again, market prices depend on aggregate, not individual behavior. 4 The budget constraint becomes c + x + γ h h q i h,h a h = a(1 + r) 5 Equilibrium (zero profit) requires q i h,h = Γi h,h (x ) Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 27/36

A model with investments in health Today we abstract from health affecting utility We write it already in recursive form V i (a, h) = max c,x,a u(c) + β γ h h Γ i h,h (x) V i (a, h ) With optimizing conditions (again assuming β = 1 + r) and noting that there are finitely many h u c (c h ) = u c (c h ), h c h = c h h u c (c h ) = β γ h h Γi h,h (x) x V i (a, h ). With strict concavity in Γ i h,h, we also get constant a and x h. Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 28/36

Characterizing Let s use again the utility function log c + α Let s pose for simplicity two health levels h = {g, b}, and Γ i gg (x) = λ i x 1 νg 0,g + λ 1,g 1 ν g Γ i bg (x) = λ i x 1 ν b 0,b + λ 1,b 1 ν b This technology requires estimating 8 parameters { λ i 0,g, λ i 0,b, λ 1,g, λ 1,b, ν g, ν b } Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 29/36

Data that we use Preference Parameters: {β, α} Expenditures in Health by Type and Health: Consumption data by type {x i h} for h g, b, i {C, D}. c i for i {C, D}. Survival Probabilities by health: γ h for h g, b. Actual Health Transitions by health today, health tomorrow and type: Γ i h,h for h, h g, b, i {C, D}. Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 30/36

We have 8 equations to solve for the 8 parameters The 4 observed health transitions for i and h. The 4 first order conditions for i and h 1 c i = β γ h λ 1,h (x i h) ν h ( V i g V i b) The only problem here are the 4 values for i and h, which are given by ] Vh i = u(c i ) + β γ h [Γ i h,h g (xh)v i g i + (1 Γ i h,h g (xh))v i b i But they are easily solved given the observed survival and transitions and consumptions ( ) [ ( ) ( V i g γg 0 Γ i = I β gg 1 Γ i )] 1 ( ( ) ) gg u c i 0 γ b Γ i bg 1 Γ i bg u ( c i) V i b Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 31/36

Using Algebra to Make things very simple Define b i h = c i (V i g V i b) Then ( ) x i νh h = bi x 1 h b 1 Which permits us to identify independently v h Use optimization conditions to identify λ 1,h, for h {g, b}. Expressions for health transitions yield the λ i 0,h for i and h {g, b}. Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 32/36

Analysis How to compare welfare? At fifty the fractions of type i with health h is µ i h. Then the Average value of type i is V i = h µi h V i h We can compare without letting them choose how much extra consumption we have to give to the average people in type i (Dropouts) to be indifferent with type 1. Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 33/36

Findings Health matters a lot: Conditional on always having the same health E g = 83.1 Life duration if always in good health E b = 69.3 Life duration if always in bad health Initial differences in health are large between college and dropouts. µ c g =.94 Coll Grads are in great health µ d g =.59 Dropouts are not College health transitions are better Γ c gg Γ d gg = 0.055 College are better at remaining in good health Γ c bg Γ d bg = 0.257 and even better at recuperating good health Hence, if cg i = cb i, the difference in value between good and bad health is larger for HSD Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 34/36

Findings Summary of health technology Γ hg λ i 0h λ 1h ν h Good health College 0.955 0.925 Dropouts 0.900 0.882 Bad health College 0.375 0.338 Dropouts 0.118 0.099 5.0 10 5 0.32 3.2 10 5 0.25 LE decomposition Data Model µ CG x CG λ CG 0h College 81.9 80.8 Dropouts 75.6 75.2 76.0 76.0 79.8 difference 6.3 5.6 0.8 0.8 4.6 Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 35/36

Conclusions We have discussed how to incorporate life expectancy jointly with consumption to construct a measure of inequality. We have found vastly larger numbers than those associated to consumption alone. Even when taking into account the adapting behavior of people. In doing so, we have produced new estimates of a health production function. These numbers are preliminary so they will likely change somewhat. We need to have a tighter link between Demographics and Economics. Pijoan-Mas & Ríos-Rull Health, Consumption and Inequality 36/36