LECTURE 11: INCOME INEQUALITY IN EUROPE AND THE USA

Similar documents
LECTURE 14: THE INEQUALITY OF CAPITAL OWNERSHIP IN EUROPE AND THE USA

LECTURE 12: THE 1 PERCENT IN EUROPE AND THE USA

LECTURE 3: MEASURING THE WEALTH OF NATIONS. Dr. Aidan Regan Website:

LECTURE 9: THE RETURN OF CAPITAL IN THE 21 ST CENTURY

Inequality and Social Mobility. Econ 101

Inequality and growth Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics

Capital in the 21 st century

Thomas Piketty s Capital in the 21 st Century

Capital in the 21 st century

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory. Costas Azariadis. Costas Azariadis. Lecture 3: Productivity and Labor

FIGURE I.1. Income inequality in the United States,

LECTURE 10: THE RETURN OF NEOLIBERAL CAPITALISM

Capital in the 21 st century. Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Visby, June

CAPITAL IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY

Economics 448: Lecture 14 Measures of Inequality

Income and Wealth Inequality in OECD Countries

Capital in the 21 st century. Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Cologne, December 5 th 2013

Income and Wealth Inequality A Lack of Equity

SKEMA BUSINESS SCHOOL Global risk and the mounting wealth gap Michel Henry Bouchet

INCOME INEQUALITY AND OTHER FORMS OF INEQUALITY. Sandip Sarkar & Balwant Singh Mehta. Institute for Human Development New Delhi

Maurizio Franzini and Mario Planta

Answer Key Midterm Exam Winter 2002

Redistribution from a lifetime perspective: historical and hypothetical reforms

Improving the Distribution of Wealth: Lecture in Memory of Anthony Atkinson. Joseph E. Stiglitz LSE February 16, 2018

Gabriel Zucman. Inequality: Are we really 'all in this together'? #ElectionEconomics PAPER EA030

Lecture 3: Income & Wage Taxation Over Time & Across Countries (check on line for updated versions)

CHAPTER 9 DISTRIBUTION: EXCHANGE AND TRANSFER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

THIRD EDITION. ECONOMICS and. MICROECONOMICS Paul Krugman Robin Wells. Chapter 18. The Economics of the Welfare State

INEQUALITY UNDER THE LABOUR GOVERNMENT

Inequality and the super-rich

long run inequality History and Inequality University of Oslo

CIE Economics A-level

CHAPTER What effect will each of the following proposed changes have on wage inequality?

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates)

the regional distribution of income

ECON 1100 Global Economics (Fall 2013) The Distribution Function of Government portions for Exam 3

Would the Senate Democrats proposed excise tax on highcost employer-paid health insurance benefits be progressive?

From Communism to Capitalism: Private Versus Public Property and Inequality in China and Russia

Wealth, Inequality & Taxation T. Piketty, IMF Supplementary slides

Inequality in the Western Balkans and former Yugoslavia. Will Bartlett Visiting Fellow, LSEE & International Inequalities Institute

A best seller on democracy and the inequality of wealth and income

Appendix A for. Cutthroat capitalism versus cuddly socialism: Are Americans more meritocratic and efficiency-seeking than Scandinavians?

Shifts in Non-Income Welfare in South Africa

Discussion: Accounting for Wealth Inequality Dynamics: Methods, Estimates and Simulations for France ( )

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Income Inequality Matters, but Mobility Is Just as Important. Daniel R. Carroll and Anne Chen

ECON 1000 (Summer 2018 Section 05) Exam #3AA

1 Income Inequality in the US

Poverty, Inequality and the Welfare State

Poverty, Inequity and Inequality in New Zealand

Rethinking Wealth Taxation

Wealth inequality and accumulation. John Hills, Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion, London School of Economics

Wealth and Welfare: Breaking the Generational Contract

Inequality in Oregon

Budget 2015/16: Is the new South Africa sustainable? By Professor Matthew Lester 25 February 2015

Trump s Tax Scam: What can we expect from the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act and how can we resist it? by Peter Bohmer February 23, 2018

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Longman

THREE WORLDS THEORY G L O B A L S T R A T I F I C A T I O N

Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Inequality: Why should we care?

POLICY INSIGHT. Inequality The hidden headwind for economic growth. How inequality slows growth

Development Economics Lecture Notes 4

WOMEN ENTREPRENEURSHIP IN UNORGANISED SECTOR

WHAT WOULD THE NEIGHBOURS SAY?

The Impact of Social Security Reform on Low-Income Workers

The impact of tax and benefit reforms by sex: some simple analysis

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

Source: Oxfam Issue Briefing, Having It All and Wanting More, January 2015

CHAPTER \11 SUMMARY OF FINDINGS, CONCLUSION AND SUGGESTION. decades. Income distribution, as reflected in the distribution of household

A Transition to Sustainable and Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz Tokyo March 14, 2017

The Canada We Want in 2020 Reducing Income Disparities and Polarization

Who is getting richer, who is getting poorer

PRODUCTIVE AGEING ROBERT BUTLER MEMORIAL LECTURE ILC GLOBAL ALLIANCE

THE SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT GOALS AND SOCIAL PROTECTION

Global economic inequality: New evidence from the World Inequality Report

Inside the black box of the family

Geneva Locke MBA World Summit 2018 Cape Town, South Africa. How Our Generation Can Solve Inequality

Poverty and income inequality

Downloads from this web forum are for private, non commercial use only. Consult the copyright and media usage guidelines on

Capitalism, Inequality & Globalization. J. E. Stiglitz Davidson College March 2018

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.ec] 1 Sep 2014

Poverty and Inequality in the Countries of the Commonwealth of Independent States

Table 4.1 Income Distribution in a Three-Person Society with A Constant Marginal Utility of Income

Where Does the Money Go?

Analysis of the Distribution of Incomes and Taxes for Tax Cases and Earners

INSTABILITY IMPLICATIONS OF INCREASING INEQUALITY : EVIDENCE FROM NORTH AMERICA

Lecture 4: Income Taxes Over Time & Across Countries

Public economics: inequality and poverty

ECON 1100 Global Economics (Section 05) Exam #3 Fall 2010 (Version A) Multiple Choice Questions ( 2. points each):

A Just Social Wage and a Job Guarantee

Cambridge University Press Getting Rich: America s New Rich and how they Got that Way Lisa A. Keister Excerpt More information

Two Cheers for Piketty

ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality

Briefing Paper BP1/2015. New survey research on public attitudes to wealth taxes. Karen Rowlingson, Andy Lymer and Rajiv Prabhakar.

How EUROMOD works and what it can achieve:

Global Inequality. Joseph E. Stiglitz Ancona, Italy November 2, 2017

Updated Facts on the U.S. Distributions of Earnings, Income, and Wealth

Taxation of High Net Worth Individuals (HNWIs)

Section A: Multiple Choice Indicate the option that correctly completes the statement. (1 mark each = 6 marks)

Consumption Inequality in Canada, Sam Norris and Krishna Pendakur

Public Sector Economics Test Questions Randall Holcombe Fall 2017

Transcription:

LECTURE 11: INCOME INEQUALITY IN EUROPE AND THE USA Dr. Aidan Regan Email: aidan.regan@ucd.ie Website: www.aidanregan.com Teaching blog: www.capitalistdemocracy.wordpress.com Twitter: @aidan_regan #CapitalUCD

Introduction In all societies income can be decomposed into three terms: Inequality in income from labour Inequality in income arising from the ownership of capital And the interaction between these two terms The causal mechanisms and normative justification underpinning each of these is different.

Vautrin s Lesson Vautrin explains to Rastignac that it is illusory to think that social success can be achieved through study, talent and effort. Vautrin claims that even if Rastingnac is talented and learns brilliant medical skills, he will never become wealthy. By contrast, the best strategy for social success is inheritance. On this basis he encourages Rastignac to marry Mademoiselle Victorine. But to do this he must first murder her brother, to ensure that she gets the inheritance. Rastingnac is prepared to marry without love or affection but is not quite prepared to commit murder. The key question being proposed by this moral dilemma is whether it pays to work if inheritance matters more Under such conditions why not be immoral and appropriate capital by whatever means?

The key question: work or inheritance? In 19 th century Europe the question of work did not arise. All that mattered was the size of one's wealth and the size of one's fortune, whether acquired through inheritance or marriage. The shock of WW1 brought these patrimonial societies to an end. Our capitalist democracies are founded on the normative belief that inequalities based on merit are more justified than other inequalities The core question to ask yourself over the coming weeks is whether we live in a society where inheritance and the social class into which you are born matters more than hard work and merit? Do we live in a meritocracy?

Inequalities with respect to labor & capital In the case of labour what matters is; the supply and demand for different skills; the state of the educational system; the rules and institutions of the labour market; the strength of trade unions; and the structure of collective bargaining. Note: in the study of economics these political institutions are generally considered a rigidity that block the presence of competitive labor market forces. What policy implications emerge from this? In the case of unequal income from capital what matters is; cross-national differences in capital markets; savings and investment behavior; laws on inheritance; and the operation of housing-rental and finance markets.

Inequality of labour income Table 7.1. Inequality of labor income across time and space Share of different groups in total labor income Low ( Scandinavia, 1970s- 80s) Medium ( Europe 2010) High ( U.S. 2010) Very high ( U.S. 2030?) The top 10% "Upper class" 20% 45% including: the top 1% ("dominant class") 5% 7% 12% 17% ("well- including: the next 9% to-do class") 15% 18% 23% 28% The middle 40% "Middle class" 45% 45% 40% The bottom 50% "Lower class" 30% 20% Corresponding Gini coefficient (synthetic index) 0.19 0.26 0.36 0.46 In societies where labor income is relatively low (such as in Scandinavian countries in the 1970s-1980s), the top 10% most well paid receive about 20% of total labor income, the bottom 50% least well paid about, the middle 40% about 45%. The corresponding Gini index (a synthetic index going from 0 to 1) is equal to 0.19. See technical appendix.

Analysis In societies where wage is low (Scandinavia in the 1970's), the top 10% received 20% of labour income, the middle 40% took 45% and the bottom 50% took. In real terms: if average pay is 2,000 per month, the top 10% would take 4,000 (the top 1% would take 6,000) the bottom 50% would take 1,400 and the middle 40% would take 2,250. The one country that stands out from table 7.1 is the USA where the of labour income has broken historical records. In real terms: in the USA where average pay is $2,000 per month, the top 10% take $7,000 ($24,000 for the top 1 percent), the middle 40% take $2,000 and the bottom 50% take $1,000.

Analysis Think about these magnitudes. In Sweden the bottom half of the population earn $1,400 whereas in the USA it is $1,000. This 40 percent difference is a significant amount. Women are significantly over-represented in the bottom 50 percent, which suggests that class-based inequalities are also gender-based income inequalities. Looking at table 7.1 we can probably conclude that it is better to be a low to middle-income wage earner in western Europe than to be a low wage earner in the the USA. Why do different countries have different attitudes toward social inequalities?

Inequality of capital ownership Table 7.2. Inequality of capital ownership across time and space Share of different groups in total capital Low (never observed; ideal society?) Medium ( Scandinavia, 1970s-1980s) Mediumhigh ( Europe 2010) High ( U.S. 2010) Very high ( Europe 1910) The top 10% "Upper class" 30% 50% 60% 70% 90% including: the top 1% ("dominant class") 10% 20% 50% ("well- including: the next 9% to-do class") 20% 30% 40% The middle 40% "Middle class" 45% 40% 5% The bottom 50% "Lower class" 10% 5% 5% 5% Corresponding Gini coefficient (synthetic index) 0.33 0.58 0.67 0.73 0.85 In societies with "medium" of capital ownership (such as Scandinavian countries in the 1970s-1980s), the top 10% richest in wealth own about 50% of aggregate wealth, the bottom 50% poorest about 10%, and the middle 40% about 40%. The corresponding Gini coefficient is equal to 0.58. See technical appendix.

Analysis Table 7.2 shows that inequalities with respect to wealth and capital ownership are even more extreme. In Europe the top decile typical own 60% of wealth, the middle class own, whereas the bottom 50 percent own little more than 5% of wealth. In the US, the top decile typically owns 70% of wealth, the middle class own, whereas the bottom 50 percent also own little more than 5% of wealth. In real terms, if average net wealth is $200k (divided into real estate and financial assets) this would imply that in the US: The top decile own capital worth $1.2 million the top centile own capital worth $5 million. The poorest 50 percent would have net wealth of less than $20,000.

Analysis The importance of housing as a form of wealth decreases the further one goes up the income distribution. Housing is the asset investment of the middle class, whereas true wealth almost always consist of financial and business assets. The growth of middle class was the principle structural transformation of the distribution of wealth (and politics) in the 20th century. In the 19th century, and right up to WW1, there was no middle class. Almost 90% of national wealth was owned by the top 10 percent. The vast majority of a society's assets were owned by an elite minority. Nevertheless, table 7.2 shows that in the ownership of capital remains extreme (the top decile own 60 percent of national wealth in Europe and 70 percent in the USA).

Inequality of total income Table 7.3. Inequality of total income (labor and capital) across time and space Share of different groups in total income (labor + capital) Low ( Scandinavia, 1970s- 80s) Medium ( Europe 2010) High ( U.S. 2010, Europe 1910) Very high ( U.S. 2030?) The top 10% "Upper class" 50% 60% including: the top 1% ("dominant class") 7% 10% 20% including: the next 9% ("well-to-do class") 18% 30% The middle 40% "Middle class" 45% 40% 30% The bottom 50% "Lower class" 30% 20% 15% Corresponding Gini coefficient (synthetic index) 0.26 0.36 0.49 0.58 In societies where the of total income is relatively low (such as Scandinavian countries during the 1970s-1980s), the 10% highest incomes receive

Analysis Democratic societies are clearly capable of accepting extreme concentrations of capital ownership because capital-income only constitutes one quarter to one third of national income. But if the same level of (top decile owning 90 percent of all output) applied to total income then surely a democratic revolution would occur? Or would it? Table 7.3 shows that the USA may set a new record on income by 2030. The top decile may take 60 percent of income whereas the bottom half of the population would barely get 15 percent.

Inequality of total income: two worlds There are two ways for a society to achieve a very unequal distribution of total income: 19th century Europe was a hyper-patrimonial society where high incomes from capital (and inherited wealth) dominated. The new high levels of in the USA emerge from high incomes from labour income (super-managers). Some call this a hyper-meritocratic society. But is it based on merit, effort and work?

Conclusion Lets return to our opening question on the role of merit versus inheritance. How are each of these income inequalities justified? It is the justification of that matters most in a democratic society. This is what s called the problem of distributive justice. See John Rawls and other normative political theorists.