A Note on Reconciling Gross Output TFP Growth with Value Added TFP Growth

Similar documents
On the Relationship between Gross Output-based TFP Growth and Value Added-based TFP Growth: An Illustration Using Data from Australian Industries

Reconciling Gross Output TFP Growth with Value Added TFP Growth

Export Import Price Index Manual 24. Measuring the Effects of Changes in the Terms of Trade

Answers to Questions Arising from the RPI Consultation. February 1, 2013

Retrospective Price Indices and Substitution Bias

Progress on Revising the Consumer Price Index Manual: Chapters 15-23

Weighted Country Product Dummy Variable Regressions and Index Number Formulae

1 This series was normalized to equal 1 in December 1997 so that it would be comparable to the other

The User Cost of Non-renewable Resources and Green Accounting. W. Erwin Diewert University of British Columbia and UNSW Australia

Measuring the Allocation of Australia Post s Reserved Service Productivity Dividend

Comparisons of Hospital Output in Canada: National and International Perspectives

The Digital Economy, New Products and Consumer Welfare

12TH OECD-NBS WORKSHOP ON NATIONAL ACCOUNTS MEASUREMENT OF HEALTH SERVICES. Comments by Luca Lorenzoni, Health Division, OECD

HEDONIC PRODUCER PRICE INDEXES AND QUALITY ADJUSTMENT

Comparing GDP in Constant and in Chained Prices: Some New Results

A CHARACTERIZATION OF THE TÖRNQVIST PRICE INDEX

DECOMPOSING A CPPI INTO LAND AND STRUCTURES COMPONENTS

Consistent Level Aggregation and Growth Decomposition of Real GDP

Price and Volume Measures

Centre for Efficiency and Productivity Analysis

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES AGGREGATION ISSUES IN INTEGRATING AND ACCELERATING BEA S ACCOUNTS: IMPROVED METHODS FOR CALCULATING GDP BY INDUSTRY

International Comparison Program

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

The Contributions of Productivity, Price Changes and Firm Size to Profitability

Canada-U.S. ICT Investment in 2009: The ICT Investment per Worker Gap Widens

INDEX NUMBER THEORY AND MEASUREMENT ECONOMICS

An Empirical Illustration of Index Construction using Israeli Data on Vegetables Revised version; April 28, 2013.

ECON 1102: MACROECONOMICS 1 Chapter 1: Measuring Macroeconomic Performance, Output and Prices

Does Capitalized Net Product Equal Discounted Optimal Consumption in Discrete Time? by W.E. Diewert and P. Schreyer. 1 February 27, 2006.

Intermediate Macroeconomics, Sciences Po, Answer Key to Problem Set 10 Dynamic Micro-founded Macro Model

Business Statstcs 1 MTU 07203

Effects of relative prices on contributions to the level and growth of real GDP Working Paper Series By Dr. Jesus C.

Deadweight Loss and the Cost of Public Funds in Australia

The Irrelevance of Detail in a Computable General Equilibrium Model

Measures of Productivity Change: Which Outcome Do You Want?

Econ 311 Intermediate Macroeconomics Professor Eschker. Fall 2014

Paper presented at the EMG (Economic Measurement Group) Workshop 2007 held at the Crowne Plaza Hotel, Coogee Australia, December 12-14, 2007.

New Estimates of Labour, Capital and Multifactor Productivity Growth and Levels for Canadian Provinces at the Three-digit NAICS Level,

Contribution of transport to economic growth and productivity in New Zealand

HIRSCHEL KASPER, Section Editor

Erwin Diewert 1 October 24, 2013 Discussion Paper 13-12, School of Economics, The University of British Columbia, Vancouver, Canada, V6T 1Z1.

Productivity and Misallocation in General Equilibrium by David Baqaee and Emmanuel Farhi

Alternative Measures of Change in Real Output and Prices

INDEX NUMBER THEORY AND MEASUREMENT ECONOMICS

Productivity: National vs. Domestic

By W.E. Diewert June 28, Chapter 8: The Measurement of Income and the Determinants of Income Growth

TEG-CPI Meeting on the CPI Manual

Money, Inflation, and Interest Rates

National Accounting. Introduction to Macroeconomics. October 7 th, 2011 WS 2011

A New Axiomatic Approach to Index Number Theory

INDEX NUMBER THEORY AND MEASUREMENT ECONOMICS

ECON 222, Spring 2009 Assignment #1, Answer Key

Lecture 9: Exchange rates

Hedonic Regressions: A Review of Some Unresolved Issues

EXAMINATIONS OF THE HONG KONG STATISTICAL SOCIETY

Price and Volume Measures Rebasing & Linking

THE PRODUCTIVITY PERFORMANCE OF THE CANADIAN AIRLINE INDUSTRY Alexander Gregory, Transport Canada

Gross Domestic Product. How Is The GDP Calculated? Net investment equals gross investment minus depreciation.

Export Market and Market Price Indices for ADAM

FISHER TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY INDEX FOR TIME SERIES DATA WITH UNKNOWN PRICES. Thanh Ngo ψ School of Aviation, Massey University, New Zealand

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

About Lowe Index and Mid-year Indices

Index Numbers. Chapter 15

CORRECTION OF CHAIN-LINKING METHOD BY MEANS OF LLOYD-MOULTON-FISHER-TÖRNQVIST INDEX ON CROATIAN GDP DATA

Three Suggestions to Improve Multi-Factor Productivity Measurement in Canadian Manufacturing

Money Supply, Inflation, and Interest Rates

One of the major recommended

April 2011 CENTRE FOR LIVING STANDARDS. CSLS Research Report i. Christopher Ross THE STUDY OF

WORKING PAPER. The Treatment of Owner Occupied Housing and Other Durables in a Consumer Price Index (2004/03) CENTRE FOR APPLIED ECONOMIC RESEARCH

Aggregate Indices and Their Corresponding Elementary Indices

BRITISH COLUMBIA FERRY COMMISSION ORDER NUMBER: 11-03

A Note on Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Externalities

Problems with the Measurement of Banking Services in a National Accounting Framework

INTRODUCING CAPITAL SERVICES INTO THE PRODUCTION ACCOUNT

The Demand and Supply of Safe Assets (Premilinary)

2 Some Essential Macroeconomic Aggregates

EXAMINATIONS OF THE ROYAL STATISTICAL SOCIETY

Appendix A: Supplementary Data and Analysis

HOW THE CHAIN-ADDITIVITY ISSUE IS TREATED IN THE U.S. ECONOMIC ACCOUNTS. Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Department of Commerce

Volume 36, Issue 4. Joint aggregation over money and credit card services under risk

The New Economy and an Old Problem: Net versus Gross Ouptut

Appendix E: Measuring the Quantity and Cost of Capital Inputs in Canada

CHAPTER 23 OUTPUT AND PRICES IN THE SHORT RUN

Answers to Problem Set #8

April An Analysis of Prince Edward Island s Productivity, : Falling Multifactor Productivity Dampens Labour Productivity Growth

AGGREGATE DEMAND, AGGREGATE SUPPLY, AND INFLATION. Chapter 25

CPI CHAPTER 22: The Treatment of Seasonal Products. April 29, A. The Problem of Seasonal Commodities

Learning Objectives. 1. Describe how the government budget surplus is related to national income.

The Multiplier Model

FUNCTIONS. Revenue functions and Demand functions

Answers to Problem Set #6 Chapter 14 problems

Chapter 6 Firms: Labor Demand, Investment Demand, and Aggregate Supply

Introduction to Macroeconomics

Chapter 2. The Measurement and Structure of the Canadian Economy. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

Money and the Measurement of Total Factor Productivity

Lecture notes 1 Macroeconomic data and history Facts to explain

1. Describe the term index. 3. Construct and interpret a Laspeyres price index. 4. Construct and interpret a Paasche price index.

Linking the Regions in the International Comparisons Program

Estimation of CPI-X in the WA Rail Industry. Draft Report

Transcription:

1 A Note on Reconciling Gross Output TFP Growth with Value Added TFP Growth Erwin Diewert 1 Discussion Paper 14-12, School of Economics, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, B.C., Canada, V6N 1Z1. Email: erwin.diewert@ubc.ca Abstract December 17, 2014 The paper obtains relatively simple exact expressions that relate value added Total Factor Productivity growth (TFP growth or Multifactor Productivity Growth) in a value added framework to the corresponding measures of TFP growth in a gross output framework when Laspeyres or Paasche indexes are used to aggregate outputs and inputs. Basically, as the input base becomes smaller, the corresponding estimates of TFP growth become larger. A fairly simple approximate relationship between Fisher indexes of gross output TFP growth and the corresponding Fisher index of value added TFP growth is also derived. The methodology developed in this note can be applied in other situations. Journal of Economic Literature Numbers C43, D24. Key Words Total Factor Productivity growth, TFP growth, Multifactor Productivity growth, MFP growth, Laspeyres, Paasche and Fisher index number formulae, magnification factors. 1 The author gratefully acknowledge the financial support of an Australian Research Council Linkage Grant (project number LP0884095) and a SSHRC grant. The author thanks Kevin Fox for helpful comments.

2 1. Introduction Schreyer (2001; 26) developed an approximate formula to relate Total Factor Productivity Growth (or Multifactor Productivity Growth) in a gross output model of production to TFP (or MFP) growth in a value added setting. In this note, we take another look at this problem 2 and develop an exact relationship between the two measures if Laspeyres (or Paasche) output and input indexes are used to compute aggregate growth rates of inputs and outputs. We develop rules relating the two productivity concepts that are simpler than the existing rules that have been developed in the literature. Sections 2 and 3 assume that aggregate outputs and inputs are constructed using the Laspeyres and Paasche formulae respectively while section 4 uses the Fisher (1922) ideal index number formula to aggregate inputs and outputs. Section 5 concludes. 2. The Laspeyres Case We first consider the situation where Laspeyres indexes are used to aggregate outputs and inputs. For simplicity, consider a situation where we want to compute gross output and t value added productivity growth rates for a production unit that produces gross output q Y t t t > 0 at prices p Y > 0, uses intermediate input q M > 0 at the prices p M > 0 and uses primary input q t X > 0 at the prices p t X > 0 for t = 0,1. 3 Define the period t value of gross output, intermediate input and primary input as v t Y p t Y q t Y, v t M p t M q t M and v t X p t t X q X respectively for t = 0,1. Define (one plus) the growth rates of output, intermediate input and primary inputs as Γ Y, Γ M and Γ X as follows: (1) Γ Y q Y 1 /q Y 0 ; Γ M q M 1 /q M 0 and Γ X q X 1 /q X 0. We assume that the value of inputs equals the value of outputs in period 0: (2) v Y 0 = v M 0 + v X 0. (One plus) gross output TFP growth using Laspeyres quantity indexes, Π G, is defined as follows: 4 (3) Π G Γ Y /[s M 0 Γ M + s X 0 Γ X ] where the period 0 input expenditure shares s M 0 and s X 0 are defined as follows: (4) s M 0 v M 0 /[v M 0 + v X 0 ] = v M 0 /v Y 0 using (2); 2 Balk (2009) has a more recent rather comprehensive paper on this topic. We obtain approximately the same result as he obtains but our method of derivation is much simpler. 3 In the case where there are many inputs and outputs, the output and input quantity ratio aggregates, q Y 1 /q Y 0, q M 1 /q M 0 and q X 1 /q X 0 can be interpreted as Laspeyres indexes of the micro quantities. The corresponding aggregate price ratios are of course Paasche price indexes. 4 Note that s M 0 Γ M + s X 0 Γ X is the Laspeyres quantity index of all inputs.

3 (5) s X 0 v X 0 /[v M 0 + v X 0 ] = 1 s M 0 using (4). We now need to define value added TFP growth. We use the Laspeyres index number formula to form an aggregate of gross output less intermediate input. We assume that the quantities of gross output and intermediate input are positive but we change the sign of the price of intermediate inputs from a positive sign to a negative sign in order to form a Laspeyres index of real value added. Thus (one plus) real value added TFP growth using a Laspeyres quantity index to construct real value added growth, Π VA, is defined as follows: (6) Π VA [S Y 0 Γ Y + S M 0 Γ M ]/Γ X where the period 0 value added output expenditure shares 5 S Y 0 and S M 0 are defined as follows: 6 (7) S Y 0 v Y 0 /[v Y 0 v M 0 ] = 1/[1 (v M 0 /v Y 0 )] = 1/[1 s M 0 ] using (4); (8) S 0 M v 0 M /[v 0 Y v 0 M ] 0 = 1 S Y using (7) = s 0 M /[1 s 0 M ] using the last equation in (7). Now substitute (7) and (8) into (6) and we obtain the following expression for (one plus) value added TFP growth: (9) Π VA = [Γ Y s M 0 Γ M ]/(1 s M 0 )Γ X. We can also substitute (5) into (3) and obtain the following expression for (one plus) gross output TFP growth: (10) Π G Γ Y /[s M 0 Γ M + (1 s M 0 )Γ X ]. Comparing (9) and (10), it can be seen that both value added and gross output TFP (one plus) growth rates can be expressed in terms of (one plus) the growth rates of output, intermediate input and primary input (Γ Y, Γ M and Γ X ) and the share of intermediate input in total input, s M 0. 5 These shares sum to one but of course S 0 M is negative and so the shares will not be bounded from below by 0 and above by 1. 6 Note that we did not change the sign of v 0 M > 0 and s 0 M > 0. Thus using (7), S 0 M < 0. We assume that period 0 nominal value added, v Y 0 v M 0, is greater than 0.

4 Now define the rate of gross output TFP growth as π G equal to Π G less 1 and the rate of real value added TFP growth as π VA equal to Π VA less 1. We can obtain the following alternative expressions for π G and π VA : (11) π G Π G 1 = (Γ Y /[s M 0 Γ M + (1 s M 0 )Γ X ]) 1 using (10) = [Γ Y s M 0 Γ M (1 s M 0 )Γ X ]/[s M 0 Γ M + (1 s M 0 )Γ X ]; (12) π VA Π VA 1 = ([Γ Y s M 0 Γ M ]/(1 s M 0 )Γ X ) 1 using (9) = [Γ Y s M 0 Γ M (1 s M 0 )Γ X ]/(1 s M 0 )Γ X. Form the ratio of value added TFP growth to gross output TFP growth and we obtain the following exact formula relating these two productivity concepts: 7 (13) π VA /π G = (1 s 0 M ) 1 [s 0 M Γ M + (1 s 0 M )Γ X ]/Γ X = (s 0 X ) 1 [s 0 M Γ M + (1 s 0 M )Γ X ]/Γ X using (5) = [v 0 Y /v 0 X ][s 0 M Γ M + (1 s 0 M )Γ X ]/Γ X using (2) and (5). Thus the bigger is the share of intermediate inputs in total period 0 input, s M 0, the bigger will be (1 s M 0 ) 1 and hence the bigger will be value added TFP growth relative to gross output TFP growth. 8 Similarly, the bigger is (one plus) aggregate input growth s M 0 Γ M + (1 s M 0 )Γ X over the two periods being compared relative to (one plus) primary input growth Γ X, the bigger will be value added TFP growth relative to gross output TFP growth. Typically, (one plus) aggregate input growth will not be all that different from (one plus) primary input growth (both terms will be close to unity) so the term (1 s M 0 ) 1 = 1/s X 0 = v Y 0 /v X 0 will explain almost all of the difference in the two TFP growth rates. 9 Note that the last equation in (13) shows that π VA /π G is approximately equal to v Y 0 /v X 0, the value of output revenues v Y 0 divided by the value of primary input v X 0, which in turn is equal to value added v Y 0 v M 0 using our assumption (2). The ratio of revenues to value added is frequently called the Domar Factor; see Balk (2009; 249). The above results can readily be generalized to many outputs and inputs due to the consistency in aggregation properties of the Laspeyres formula. 7 We need to assume that π G 0. 8 Note that 1 s M 0 is equal to s X 0, the share of primary inputs in total inputs used in period 0. The first equation in (12) is roughly equivalent to Domar s (1961; 725) equation (4.6) while the third equation in (12) is roughly equivalent to Balk s (2009; 248) equation (20). 9 Thus if (Laspeyres) gross output TFP growth π G is 0.5 % and the period 0 primary input share of total input s X 0 is ½, then (Laspeyres) value added TFP growth π VA will be approximately (s X 0 ) 1 (0.5%) = 1.0%; if s X 0 = 1/3, then π VA (1/3) 1 (0.5%) = 1.5%.

5 3. The Paasche Case We now consider the situation where Paasche indexes are used to aggregate outputs and inputs. Again, define (one plus) the growth rates of output, intermediate input and primary inputs as Γ Y, Γ M and Γ X by equations (1) but if we are in the case of multiple outputs and inputs, these ratios are to be interpreted as being equal to Paasche indexes of gross output, intermediate input and primary input in this section. We assume that the value of inputs equals the value of outputs in period 1: (14) v Y 1 = v M 1 + v X 1. (One plus) gross output TFP growth using Paasche quantity indexes, Π G *, is defined as follows: 10 (15) Π G * Γ Y /[s M 1 Γ M 1 + s X 1 Γ X 1 ] 1 where the period 0 input expenditure shares s M 1 and s X 1 are defined as follows: (16) s M 1 v M 1 /[v M 1 + v X 1 ] = v M 1 /v Y 1 (17) s X 1 v X 1 /[v M 1 + v X 1 ] = 1 s M 1 using (14); using (16). We now need to define Paasche value added TFP growth. We use the Paasche index number formula to form an aggregate of gross output less intermediate input. We assume that the quantities of gross output and intermediate input are positive but we change the sign of the price of intermediate inputs from a positive sign to a negative sign in order to form a Paasche index of real value added. Thus (one plus) real value added TFP growth using a Paasche quantity index to construct real value added growth, Π VA *, is defined as follows: 11 (18) Π VA * [S Y 1 Γ Y 1 ] 1 /Γ X where the period 1 value added output expenditure shares 12 S Y 1 and S M 1 are defined as follows: 13 (19) S Y 1 v Y 1 /[v Y 1 v M 1 ] = 1/[1 (v M 1 /v Y 1 )] = 1/[1 s M 1 ] using (16); 10 Note that [s 0 M Γ 1 M + s 0 X Γ 1 X ] 1 is the Paasche quantity index of all inputs. 11 Note that [S 1 Y Γ 1 Y + S 1 M Γ 1 M ] 1 is the Paasche real value added index. 12 These shares sum to one but of course S 1 M is negative and so the shares will not be bounded from below by 0 and above by 1. We assume that v 1 Y v 1 M > 0. 13 Note that we did not change the sign of v 1 M > 0 and s 1 M > 0. Thus using (20), S 1 M < 0.

6 (20) S 1 M v 1 M /[v 1 Y v 1 M ] 1 = 1 S Y using (19) = s 1 M /[1 s 1 M ] using the last equation in (19). Now substitute (19) and (20) into (18) and we obtain the following expression for (one plus) value added Paasche TFP growth: (21) Π VA * = [S Y 1 Γ Y 1 ] 1 /Γ X = Γ X 1 /[S Y 1 Γ Y 1 ] = (1 s M 1 ) 1 Γ X 1 /[Γ Y 1 s M 1 Γ M 1 ]. We can also substitute (17) into (15) and obtain the following expression for (one plus) gross output Paasche TFP growth: (22) Π G * Γ Y /[s M 1 Γ M 1 ] 1 = [s M 1 Γ M 1 ]/Γ Y 1. Comparing (21) and (22), it can be seen that both value added and gross output Paasche TFP (one plus) growth rates can be expressed in terms of (one plus) the growth rates of (Paasche) output, intermediate input and primary input (Γ Y, Γ M and Γ X ) and the period 1 share of intermediate input in total input, s M 1. Now compute (Π VA * ) 1 1 and (Π G * ) 1 1 using (21) and (22): (23) (Π VA * ) 1 1 = {[Γ Y 1 s M 1 Γ M 1 ]/(1 s M 1 ) 1 Γ X 1 } 1 = [Γ Y 1 s M 1 Γ M 1 (1 s M 1 )Γ X 1 ]/[(1 s M 1 )Γ X 1 ]; (24) (Π G * ) 1 1 = {Γ Y 1 /[s M 1 Γ M 1 ]} 1 = [Γ Y 1 s M 1 Γ M 1 (1 s M 1 )Γ X 1 ]/[s M 1 Γ M 1 ]. Now take the ratio of (23) to (24) and we obtain the following identity: 14 (25) [(Π VA * ) 1 1]/[(Π G * ) 1 1] = [s M 1 Γ M 1 ]/[(1 s M 1 )Γ X 1 ]. Define the Paasche rate of gross output TFP growth as π G * equal to Π G * less 1 and the Paasche rate of real value added TFP growth as π VA * equal to Π VA * less 1: (26) π G * Π G * 1; (27) π VA * Π VA * 1. Now multiply both sides of (25) by Π VA * /Π G * and we obtain the following equation: (28) π VA * /π G * = [Π VA * /Π G * ]{[s M 1 Γ M 1 ]/[(1 s M 1 )Γ X 1 ]} using (25) 14 We need to assume that (Π G * ) 1 1 0 which will imply π G * Π G * 1 is also not equal to 0 since Π G * > 0.

7 = (1 s 1 M ) 1 [S 1 Y Γ 1 Y + S 1 M Γ 1 M ] 1 /Γ Y using (21) and (22) = (s 1 X ) 1 [S 1 Y Γ 1 Y + S 1 M Γ 1 M ] 1 /Γ Y using (17) = (v Y 1 /v X 1 )[S Y 1 Γ Y 1 ] 1 /Γ Y using (17) and (14). Thus the bigger is the share of intermediate inputs in total period 1 input, s M 1, the bigger will be (1 s M 1 ) 1 and hence the bigger will be value added Paasche TFP growth relative to Paasche gross output TFP growth. Of course, (1 s M 1 ) 1 is equal to 1/s X 1 which in turn is equal to the period 1 Domar Augmentation Factor, v Y 1 /v X 1, which in turn is equal to the period 1 value of gross output divided by the period 1 value of primary input. 15 Similarly, the bigger is (one plus) real value added growth [S Y 1 Γ Y 1 ] 1 over the two periods being compared relative to (one plus) gross output growth Γ Y, 16 the bigger will be Paasche value added TFP growth relative to Paasche gross output TFP growth. Note the similarity of the Paasche formula (28) to our earlier Laspeyres formula (13). Typically, (one plus) real value added growth will not be all that different from (one plus) gross output growth (both terms will be close to unity) so the Paasche Augmentation Factor (1 s M 1 ) 1 = 1/s X 1 = v Y 1 /v X 1 will explain almost all of the difference in the two Paasche TFP growth rates. The above results can readily be generalized to many outputs and inputs due to the consistency in aggregation properties of the Paasche formula. 4. The Fisher Case One plus the Fisher (1922) index of value added productivity growth, Π VA F, is defined as the geometric mean of the corresponding Laspeyres and Paasche measures of (one plus) value added TFP growth, Π VA and Π VA * : (29) Π VA F [Π VA Π VA * ] 1/2. Similarly, (one plus) the Fisher (1922) index of gross output productivity growth, Π G F, is defined as the geometric mean of the corresponding Laspeyres and Paasche measures of (one plus) gross output TFP growth, Π G and Π G * : (30) Π G F [Π G Π G * ] 1/2. Finally, define the Fisher (1922) indexes of value added and gross output productivity growth, π VA F and π G F, as follows: (31) π VA F Π VA F 1; 15 Assumption (14) ensures that v Y 1 /v X 1 > 1. 16 Note that [S Y 1 Γ Y 1 ] 1 is the Paasche index of real value added growth and Γ Y is to be interpreted as the Paasche index of gross output growth if there are many outputs and we are aggregating outputs in two stages using the Paasche formula.

8 (32) π G F Π G F 1. Equations (9) and (10) give exact expressions for the Laspeyres indexes Π VA and Π G while equations (21) and (22) give exact expressions for the Paasche indexes Π VA * and Π G *. Hence we could use these expressions to calculate the Fisher variables (29)-(32) and we would end up with an exact expression for the ratio of Fisher index value added TFP growth to Fisher gross output growth, π VA F /π G F. However, the resulting expression is difficult to interpret and so we will resort to a different strategy that makes use of equations (13) and (28) but also involves approximating the geometric means that define Π VA F and Π G F by corresponding arithmetic means. 17 The first step in our strategy is to define the right hand sides of equations (13) and (28) as the constants γ and γ * : 18 (33) π VA /π G = (s X 0 ) 1 [s M 0 Γ M + (1 s M 0 )Γ X ]/Γ X γ; (34) π VA * /π G * = (s X 1 ) 1 [S Y 1 Γ Y 1 ] 1 /Γ Y γ *. Using definitions (11) and (12) and (26) and (27), equations (33) and (34) imply the following relations: (35) (Π VA 1) = γ(π G 1); (36) (Π VA * 1) = γ * (Π G * 1). Using definitions (29) and (31), we have the following equations: (37) π VA F = [Π VA Π VA * ] 1/2 1 ½ Π VA + ½ Π VA * 1 where we have approximated the geometric mean by an arithmetic mean = ½ [Π VA 1] + ½ [ Π VA * 1] = ½ γ[π G 1] + ½ γ * [ Π G * 1] where the last equation follows using (35) and (36). Using definitions (30) and (32), we have the following equations: (38) π G F = [Π G Π G * ] 1/2 1 ½ Π G + ½ Π G * 1 where we have approximated the geometric mean by an arithmetic mean = ½ [Π G 1] + ½ γ[ Π G * 1]. If ½ [Π G 1] + ½ γ[ Π G * 1] is not equal to zero, we can take the ratio of π VA F to π G F and using (37) and (38), we obtain the following approximate relationship of Fisher value added TFP growth to Fisher gross output TFP growth: 17 These approximations will typically be very close. 18 These constants can be regarded as magnification factors; they magnify the gross output TFP growth rates into the corresponding real value added TFP growth rates.

9 (39) π VA F /π G F {γ[π G 1] + γ * [ Π G * 1]}/{[Π G 1] + γ[ Π G * 1]} = wγ + (1 w)γ * where the weight w [Π G 1]/{[Π G 1] + [ Π G * 1]}. Thus π VA F /π G F is approximately equal to a weighted average of the Laspeyres and Paasche magnification factors, γ and γ *. 19 If we are willing to make a further approximation that the Laspeyres and Paasche indexes of gross output growth are approximately equal so that Π G Π G *, then we obtain the following very simple approximate relationship between Fisher value added TFP growth and Fisher gross output TFP growth: (40) π VA F /π G F ½ γ + ½ γ *. 5. Conclusion We have obtained relatively simple exact expressions for the relationship between the rate of gross output Multifactor Productivity Growth and the corresponding rate of real value added MFP growth if the Laspeyres or Paasche index number formulae are used to aggregate inputs and outputs. We also obtained a simple approximate expression relating value added TFP growth to gross output TFP growth if the Fisher formula is used to aggregate inputs and outputs. Generally speaking, gross output TFP growth is magnified when we move to value added TFP growth and the magnification factor is approximately equal to the reciprocal of the share of primary inputs in total input use. The same methodology can be used in other situations. For example, we may want to compare value added productivity growth to net value added productivity growth where the latter concept takes depreciation out of capital services and treats it as an intermediate input expense. The resulting net value added TFP growth will be equal to a magnification factor times the corresponding traditional value added TFP growth and the magnification factor will be approximately equal to the reciprocal of the share of labour and waiting services in traditional labour and capital services (which include depreciation in the user costs of capital). 20 In some regulatory contexts, we may want to compute TFP growth with labour added regarded as an intermediate input and only capital services in the primary input base and compare this TFP growth with more traditional measures. Again a magnification factor will emerge. 21 Generally speaking, the smaller we make the input base in the productivity measure, the bigger will be the rate of TFP growth. Other examples of this magnification effect can be found in Schreyer (2001) and in Balk (2009). References 19 The weights for γ and γ * will sum to unity but they need not be nonnegative unless Π G 1 and Π * G 1 have the same sign. This will almost always be the case empirically. 20 For applications of this net value added approach and estimates of the resulting magnification factors, see Diewert (2014) and Diewert and Yu (2012). 21 For an application of this approach, see Lawrence, Diewert and Fox (2006).

10 Balk, B.M. (2009), On the Relation between Gross Output and Value Added Based Productivity Measures: The Importance of the Domar Factor, Macroeconomic Dynamics, 13 (Supplement 2), 241 267. Diewert, W.E. (2014), US TFP Growth and the Contribution of Changes in Export and Import Prices to Real Income Growth, Journal of Productivity Analysis 41, 19-39. Diewert, W.E. and E. Yu (2012), New Estimates of Real Income and Multifactor Productivity Growth for the Canadian Business Sector, 1961-2011, International Productivity Monitor, Number 24:Fall, 27-48. Domar, E.D. (1961), On the Measurement of Technological Change, Economic Journal 71, 709 729. Fisher, I. (1922), The Making of Index Numbers, Boston: Houghton-Mifflin. Lawrence, D.A., W.E. Diewert and K.J. Fox (2006), Who Benefits from Economic Reform: The Contribution of Productivity, Price Changes and Firm Size to Profitability, Journal of Productivity Analysis 26, 1-13. Schreyer, P. (2001), OECD Productivity Manual: A Guide to the Measurement of Industry-Level and Aggregate Productivity Growth, Paris: OECD.