Natural Resource Endowments, Governance, and the Domestic Revenue Effort: Evidence from a Panel of Countries

Similar documents
Demographic transition in resource rich countries: a bonus or a curse?

April 2015 Fiscal Monitor

Current Account Determinants for Oil- Exporting Countries

PRESS POINTS FOR CHAPTER 3: IS IT TIME FOR AN INFRASTRUCTURE PUSH? THE MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF PUBLIC INVESTMENT World Economic Outlook, October 2014

Managing Nonrenewable Natural Resources

Determinant of Tax Buoyancy: Empirical Evidence from Developing Countries

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND. October 2015 Fiscal Monitor. Background Notes. Prepared by the Fiscal Affairs Department

Resource Dependence and Budget Transparency By Antoine Heuty and Ruth Carlitz 1

The non-generalizability of The First Law of Petropolitics

Economic Growth and Convergence across the OIC Countries 1

ENVIRONMENTAL ISSUES and NATURAL RESOURCE EXTRACTION

A Crude Shock: Explaining the Impact of the Oil Price Decline Across Exporters

Natural Resource Taxation: Challenges in Africa

Natural resources impact on government revenues

Commodity Prices and Fiscal Policy in Latin America and the Caribbean EMILY SINNOTT

Determinants of Revenue Generation Capacity in the Economy of Pakistan

The Commodities Roller Coaster: A Fiscal Framework for Uncertain Times

Macroeconomic Stability in Resource-rich Countries: The Role of Fiscal Policy

Developing countries and the commodities trade: Why transparency matters

The Time Cost of Documents to Trade

Resource Windfalls and Emerging Market Sovereign Bond Spreads: The Role of Political Institutions

Commodity Prices and Sovereign Default: A New Perspective on the Harberger-Laursen-Metzler Effect

VERIFYING OF BETA CONVERGENCE FOR SOUTH EAST COUNTRIES OF ASIA

Another Technological Revolution in the O&G Industry: A new Future for Onshore E&P. Ivan Sandrea Advisor to Petra Energia

What Can Macroeconometric Models Say About Asia-Type Crises?

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

26 MAY Boustead Singapore Limited FY2010 Financial Results Presentation

FINANCIAL COOPERATION

Understanding Inflation Inertia in Angola

Dr. Raja M. Almarzoqi Albqami Institute of Diplomatic Studies

IMF/AMF High-Level Seminar on. Institutions and Economic Growth in the Arab Countries. Abu Dhabi, United Arab Emirates. December 19-20, 2006

Parallel Session 1: Empirical trade analysis (1)

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis

Effectiveness of macroprudential and capital flow measures in Asia and the Pacific 1

26 MAY Boustead Singapore Limited / Boustead Projects Limited Joint FY2015 Financial Results Presentation

Course Outline. Applied Upstream Petroleum Fiscal Modeling & Economics. Course Leader: Barry Rodgers

Government expenditure and Economic Growth in MENA Region

TIMID GLOBAL GROWTH: THE NEW NORMAL?

On Minimum Wage Determination

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility

GROWTH DETERMINANTS IN LOW-INCOME AND EMERGING ASIA: A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS

Online Appendices for

INVESTIGATION OF THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN CURRENT ACCOUNT DEFICIT AND SAVINGS IN MENA ECONOMIES: AN EMPIRICAL APPROACH

Oil Booms, Dutch Disease and Manufacturing Growth

Local Government Spending and Economic Growth in Guangdong: The Key Role of Financial Development. Chi-Chuan LEE

Topic 2. Productivity, technological change, and policy: macro-level analysis

Futures Markets, Oil Prices, and the Intertemporal Approach to the Current Account

Determinants of Inward Foreign Direct Investment: A Dynamic Panel Study

Do Domestic Chinese Firms Benefit from Foreign Direct Investment?

The Rise of the Middle Class and Economic Growth in ASEAN

Commodity Price Changes and Economic Growth in Developing Countries

The Impact of Fiscal Space on Economic Growth in Egypt

Impact of credit risk (NPLs) and capital on liquidity risk of Malaysian banks

Oil and Conflict: What Does the Cross-Country Evidence Really Show?

Economics Program Working Paper Series

IDBG OPERATIONS AT A GLANCE Q Update

The Linkage between the Oil and the Non-oil Sectors A Panel VAR Approach

DANIEL DUMAS ESCP Europe Business School London, 14 November 2013

Kazakhstan: Readying for a milder boom

On the Investment Sensitivity of Debt under Uncertainty

Foreign Direct Investment and Islamic Banking: A Granger Causality Test

ide: FRANCE Appendix A Countries with Double Taxation Agreement with France

The governance-natural resources nexus has been intensely debated in recent decades, and many economists have highlighted the intrinsic role played

What Firms Know. Mohammad Amin* World Bank. May 2008

Inflation persistence and exchange rate regimes: evidence from developing countries. Abstract

Does Public Employment Reduce Unemployment?

Request to accept inclusive insurance P6L or EASY Pauschal

Argentina Bahamas Barbados Bermuda Bolivia Brazil British Virgin Islands Canada Cayman Islands Chile

Presented at the Conference on China's Exchange Rate Policy, October 19, 2007, at the Peterson Institute, Washington, DC.

The relationship amongst public debt and economic growth in developing country case of Tunisia

The Politics of Energy Policy in the Gulf Arab States: Shortage and Reform in the World s Storehouse of Energy

ISLAMIC DEVELOPMENT BANK PROGRESS REPORT ON THE ACTIVITIES OF THE ISLAMIC SOLIDARITY FUND FOR DEVELOPMENT (ISFD)

FINANCIAL INTEGRATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: A CASE OF PORTFOLIO EQUITY FLOWS TO SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Volatility and Growth: Credit Constraints and the Composition of Investment

SUSTAINING NATURAL RESOURCE BOOMS: ARE FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS A SOLUTION?

Informality and Regulations: What Drives Firm Growth?

Sovereign Wealth Funds

HEALTH WEALTH CAREER 2017 WORLDWIDE BENEFIT & EMPLOYMENT GUIDELINES

Delivering mobile connectivity in MENA: A review of mobile sector taxation and licence extension. May 2017

Effectiveness of Stabilization Funds in Managing Volatility in Oil-Rich Countries

VAT in GCC countries. Tax in zero tax environment? 21 April, 2015

Comperative DTTs of Pakistan

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

Working Paper. An Analysis of Emerging Market Spreads NO.3. Shin Oya. November 2001 JBIC INSTITUTE JAPAN BANK FOR INTERNATIONAL COOPERATION

Cross-Border Tax Regimes. Steven Sieker Partner, Baker McKenzie 28 June 2018

Deregulation and Firm Investment

Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality. June 19, 2017

DETERMINANTS OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN BRICS COUNTRIES

Volume 29, Issue 2. A note on finance, inflation, and economic growth

Debt and Economic Growth in South Asia

Does health capital have differential effects on economic growth?

Exchange Rate Assessments: Methodologies for Oil Exporting Countries

New Generalized Systems of Preferences: What does it mean for you? Countries excluded from new scheme

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

Cross Sectional Analysis of Financial Development on Economic Growth. Jeremy Carmack Hari Krishnam Haidan Zhou

Country Fixed Effects and Unit Roots: A Comment on Poverty and Civil War: Revisiting the Evidence

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011

Generating Government Revenue from the Sale of Oil and Gas: New Data and the Case for Improved Commodity Trading Transparency

Do Debt-Service Savings and Grants Boost Social Expenditures?

Transcription:

WP/08/170 Natural Resource Endowments, Governance, and the Domestic Revenue Effort: Evidence from a Panel of Countries Fabian Bornhorst, Sanjeev Gupta, and John Thornton

2008 International Monetary Fund WP/08/170 IMF Working Paper Fiscal Affairs Department Natural Resource Endowments, Governance, and the Domestic Revenue Effort: Evidence from a Panel of Countries Prepared by Fabian Bornhorst, Sanjeev Gupta, and John Thornton 1 July 2008 Abstract This Working Paper should not be reported as representing the views of the IMF. The views expressed in this Working Paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent those of the IMF or IMF policy. Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published to elicit comments and to further debate. The recent development literature stresses that countries that receive large revenues from natural resource endowments typically raise less revenue from domestic taxation, and that this creates governance problems because the lower domestic tax effort reduces the incentive for the public scrutiny of government. Our results from a panel of 30 hydrocarbon producing countries indicate that the offset between hydrocarbon revenues and revenues from other domestic sources is about 20 percent but that it is invariant to governance indicators. 6BJEL Classification Numbers: H20; O13 Keywords: hydrocarbon revenues; domestic revenue effort; governance Author s E-Mail Address: fbornhorst@imf.org, sgupta@imf.org, jthornton@imf.org 1 Fabian Bornhorst and Sanjeev Gupta are, respectively, Economist and Senior Advisor in the IMF s Fiscal Affairs Department; John Thornton is an Assistant Director in the IMF s Middle East and Central Asia Department. The authors thank Paolo Mauro; Stephanie Eble, and Rabah Arezki for helpful comments on an earlier version of the paper. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the IMF, its Executive Board, or its management.

2 Contents Page I. Introduction...3 II. Data and Methodology...3 III. Empirical Results...7 IV. Conclusions...9 Figure 1. Government Revenue from Hydrocarbons and Domestic Taxes...5 Tables 1. Government Revenue from Hydrocarbons, 1992 2005...4 2. Summary Statistics for Selected Variables...7 3. Panel OLS Results with Fixed Effects...8 References...10

3 I. INTRODUCTION The recent development literature stresses that countries receiving large revenues from natural resource endowments typically raise less revenue from domestic taxation, and that this creates governance problems because the lower domestic tax effort reduces the incentive for the public scrutiny of government (e.g., Moore, 1998, 2007; Collier and Hoeffler, 2005; and Collier, 2006). 2 A similar and older argument has been made with respect to the impact of foreign aid on the domestic revenue effort (Bauer, 1976). In both cases, relying on revenues from sources other than domestic taxation is seen as reducing incentives to strengthen domestic revenue mobilization. However, while there has been some empirical work on the impact of foreign aid on the domestic revenue effort, the impact of natural resources on the non-resource-related tax base has received scant attention. 3 In this paper, we focus on the relation between natural resource endowments and the domestic (non-resource-related) revenue effort in natural resource-rich countries. Specifically, we examine whether there is evidence of an offset between government revenues from hydrocarbon (oil and gas) related activities and revenues from other domestic sources in a panel of 30 hydrocarbon producing countries. Our results indicate that there is an offset of about 20 percent, which is robust to the inclusion of control variables and alternate estimation methodologies. II. DATA AND METHODOLOGY Governments of countries with hydrocarbon endowments typically receive revenues from taxing the extraction companies, from the royalties these companies pay, and from production sharing arrangements. Table 1 provides summary data for these revenue streams in 30 countries for the period 1992-2005. It shows hydrocarbon revenue in relation to total government revenue (net of foreign grants) and to GDP. On both measures, revenue has increased substantially over the period (from 48.8 percent to 60.1 percent of total government revenue, and from 14.7 percent to 24.0 percent of GDP), reflecting increases in hydrocarbon production and world prices, and in the tax and royalty rates applied to the hydrocarbon sector. Figure 1 plots for the same countries hydrocarbon revenues against non-hydrocarbon domestic revenues (both in percent of GDP). 4 We model non-hydrocarbon domestic revenue, R NH, as a function of revenue from hydrocarbon products, R H, normalized by GDP, Y, and a series of control variables. The basic equation that we estimate is: 2 This contrasts sharply with the early development literature which viewed a sizeable endowment of natural resources as helping countries to grow (e.g., Lewis 1955; Viner, 1952). 3 See Gupta et al (2004) for a survey of the debate on the relation between foreign aid and the domestic revenue effort and a contribution to the empirical evidence. 4 The total government revenues (i.e., hydrocarbon plus other domestic tax and non-tax revenues) of hydrocarbon and non-hydrocarbon producing countries are broadly similar. For example, the average total government revenueto-gdp ratio in our sample of hydrocarbon producers is 29.6 percent, which compares to an average ratio of about 28 percent in a sample of 60 non-hydrocarbon producing countries.

4 Table 1. Government Revenue from Hydrocarbons, 1992 2005 In percent of: GDP Total Revenue Africa 16.0 52.4 Angola 32.9 83.6 Cameroon 3.9 25.2 Chad 0.5 4.0 Congo 18.3 64.7 Equatorial Guinea 16.0 59.0 Gabon 16.6 56.3 Nigeria 24.0 73.8 Asia-Pacific 14.3 45.8 Brunei 32.0 81.2 Indonesia 4.3 27.9 Vietnam 6.5 28.3 Europe 7.9 17.1 Russia 6.6 17.0 Norway 9.2 17.2 Middle East 20.0 57.2 Algeria 21.6 64.8 Azerbaijan 7.2 29.2 Bahrain 18.7 63.0 Iran 15.7 58.8 Kazakhstan 5.6 22.2 Kuwait 39.3 68.3 Libya 29.7 65.3 Oman 32.8 77.1 Qatar 26.0 65.7 Saudi Arabia 25.3 77.0 Sudan 7.2 43.8 Syria 11.7 44.3 UAE 20.9 62.6 Yemen 18.1 58.2 Western Hemisphere 8.9 33.7 Ecuador 6.1 24.5 Mexico 7.2 31.8 Trinidad and Tobago 7.0 26.1 Venezuela 15.3 52.5 Average 16.2 49.1 Source: International Monetary Fund.

5 R Y NH it H R = α i + β 1 + controls + uit Y (1) it for i = 1,, 30 and t = 1992, 2005. We allow for a country specific fixed effect α i and include the error term u it, the assumptions on which are relaxed according to the estimation technique. The coefficient on β 1 indicates the marginal effect of an additional percentage point of government revenue from hydrocarbons on the non-hydrocarbon domestic revenue effort. For any estimate of β 1 less than zero, an increase in hydrocarbon revenue is associated with lower non-hydrocarbon revenue. 50 Figure 1. Government Revenue from Hydrocarbon and Domestic Taxes (In percent of GDP) 45 Norway 40 Non-hydrocarbon domestic revenue 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 Russia Kazakhstan Timor Ecuador Venezuela Azerbaijan Chad Cameroon Indonesia Mexico Sudan Syria UAE Gabon Trinidad and Tobago Qatar Iran Vietnam Bahrain Algeria Nigeria Congo Equatorial Guinea Saudi Arabia Libya Brunei Oman Angola Kuwait 0 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 Hydrocarbon revenues For the control variables, we draw on the empirical literature on the basic determinants of crosscountry variations in tax revenue-to-gdp ratios (e.g., Tanzi, 1992; Gupta 2007). Thus, our variables are: income, measured as the log of per capita GDP; openness to international trade, measured as the sum of non-hydrocarbon exports plus imports in relation to GDP; the composition of output between agriculture and non-agricultural activities; and perceptions of levels of corruption. In addition, we include dummy variables to control for common time effects that may have an impact on hydrocarbon revenues, such as the effect of the oil price. We test three particular variations of the basic equation. First, we differentiate countries according to the relative importance of hydrocarbon revenue to GDP, where our expectation is

6 that a larger share of revenues from hydrocarbons would have a correspondingly greater adverse impact on other domestic revenues. To this end, we interact R H /Y with three 0,1 dummy variables that enter as 1 for countries where the share of hydrocarbon revenues in total revenue is between zero and 15 percent, greater than 15 percent but less than 25 percent, and greater than 25 percent, respectively. Second, we take explicit account of the interaction between hydrocarbon revenues and corruption by interacting R H /Y with two corruption indices, one indicating perceptions of low corruption and the other indicating perceptions of high corruption. Finally, we interact R H /Y with an indicator variable for periods of rising and of falling hydrocarbon revenue to determine whether any offset is symmetrical. 5 A potential difficulty with equation (1) is that since the hydrocarbon sector often represents a significant and volatile part of GDP, the normalization of revenues by total GDP could affect the size and significance of the estimated coefficients for β 1. Specifically, if hydrocarbon production increases sharply, and hydrocarbon revenues grow relative to GDP, the nonhydrocarbon revenues may appear depressed as a fraction of GDP simply because of the increased income and the estimates for β 1 may be biased downwards. Accordingly, we H NH decompose GDP into it hydrocarbon and non-hydrocarbon components (i.e., Y = Y + Y ) and reformulate equation (1) to estimate: R Y NH NH it H R = α i + β 1 + controls + u H it Y (2) it NH H where Y and Y represent the non-hydrocarbon and hydrocarbon components of GDP respectively, and the other variables are as defined previously. 6 The data for hydrocarbon and non-hydrocarbon fiscal revenues, and for hydrocarbon and nonhydrocarbon GDP are from the International Monetary Fund; 7 and data on the control variables is taken from the World Bank s World Development Indicators database, and the data for foreign grants (to compute the domestic non-hydrocarbon revenue) is from the OECD s database on official development assistance. The corruption series is the perception-based index from the International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) dataset, which assigns risks points on a scale of 1 to 6 and is described by Keefer and Knack (1997). For the interaction with R H /Y, high corruption countries are those with risk points from 1 to 3 and low corruption those with risk points from 4 to 6. Summary statistics for the key variables are reported in Table 2. The estimation method is panel OLS with fixed effects to account for time invariant, country specific effects. 5 A period of rising (falling) hydrocarbon revenue is defined as a period in which R H /Y is higher (lower) than in the preceding period. 6 Non-hydrocarbon GDP excludes value added from the hydrocarbon sectors. 7 The data are unpublished but are available from the authors on request.

7 Table 2. Summary Statistics for Selected Variables Variable Mean Standard Deviation R H /Y 16.0 11.1 R NH /Y 13.5 8.6 R H /Y H 67.0 40.7 R NH /Y NH 18.4 11.0 Y H /Y 71.7 19.0 Log(GDP per capita) 7.8 1.3 Log (GDP) 3.2 1.5 Openness 81.0 32.9 Agriculture 11.3 9.7 Sample for specification (3) in Table 3. R H and R NH refer to government revenues from hydrocarbon and non-hydrocarbon domestic sources, respectively; Y, YH and YNH are nominal GDP, and its hydrocarbon and non-hydrocarbon components, respectively; openness is non-hydrocarbon exports plus imports in relation to GDP; and agriculture referes to its share in GDP. III. EMPIRICAL RESULTS The empirical results are reported in Table 3. The effect of hydrocarbon revenue on the domestic revenue effort is statistically significant and negative in all specifications. The first column of the table reports results excluding the control variables. The coefficient on R H /Y indicates that an additional percentage point of revenue from hydrocarbons reduces revenues from other domestic sources by 0.19 percentage points of GDP. The results with all control variables included are reported in column 2. The coefficient on R H /Y is largely unchanged and the composition of GDP is the only statistically significant control variable, with nonhydrocarbon revenue ratios tending to be lower where agriculture is a large share of value added. 8 We carried out a number of robustness checks. First, we dropped the main outlier countries (Norway, Russia and Kuwait) from the sample; these estimates are reported in column 3 and are little different from the full sample estimates. Second, as revenue ratios tend to be persistent over time, and as shocks may last for more than one period, we estimate a dynamic specification and a specification allowing for first-order autocorrelation in the residuals, the results from which are reported in columns 4 and 5, respectively. The results reported in column 4 are from using the Arellano-Bond (1991) estimator, which allows the specification of a common lagged 8 Interestingly, the size of the offset coefficient is in line with that reported by Gupta et al. (2004) in their study of the impact of foreign aid on the domestic revenue effort.

8 Table 3. Panel OLS Results with Fixed Effects Dependant variables: R NH /Y R NH /Y NH (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) R H /Y -0.1852*** -0.1850*** -0.1727*** -0.2305*** -0.2581*** (0.0365) (0.0523) (0.0353) (0.0466) (0.0345) 0 < R H /Y < 0.15-0.3127*** (0.0655) 0.25 < R H /Y < 1-0.2601*** (0.0471) 0.15 < R H /Y < 0.25-0.2113*** (0.0365) High corruption -0.1790*** (0.0357) Low corruption -0.2179*** (0.0546) Periods of falling production -0.1855*** (0.0428) Periods of increasing production -0.1886*** (0.0380) R H /Y H -0.0955*** (0.0277) (R H /Y H )^2 0.0395*** (0.0114) R NH /Y (t-1) 0.2428*** (0.0670) Log (GDP per capita) -0.0005 0.0038-0.0027 0.0244*** -0.0031-0.0005-0.0020 0.0369*** (0.0089) (0.0072) (0.0101) (0.0055) (0.0074) (0.0073) (0.0079) (0.0072) Non hydrocarbon openness -0.0218-0.0242* -0.0006 0.0000-0.0195-0.0221-0.0159 0.0016 (0.0205) (0.0143) (0.0194) (0.0149) (0.0151) (0.0152) (0.0165) (0.0172) Corruption -0.0033-0.0027-0.0013 0.0139*** -0.0032-0.0014-0.0040 0.0109** (0.0041) (0.0032) (0.0037) (0.0036) (0.0032) (0.0039) (0.0035) (0.0048) Agriculture -0.0017* -0.0013* -0.0013-0.0006-0.0016** -0.0017** -0.0017** 0.0004 (0.0009) (0.0007) (0.0009) (0.0005) (0.0007) (0.0007) (0.0007) (0.0006) Constant 0.1575*** 0.2117** 0.1507** 0.1792** 0.0000 0.2438*** 0.2069*** 0.2233*** 0.0000 (0.0055) (0.0797) (0.0611) (0.0863) (0.0000) (0.0650) (0.0640) (0.0686) (0.0000) Time effects yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes R 2 0.20 0.20 0.20 0.74 0.72 0.22 0.20 0.21 0.66 F-test on equality of the coefficients 0.05 0.43 0.86 Observations 389 290 253 244 286 290 290 268 277 Number of countries 30 25 22 25 24 25 25 25 24 Column (4) report results using the Arellano Bond estimator, where corruption is instrumented with lagged values. The results in column (5) and (9) correct for member specific first order serial correlation in the residuals, and corrected standard errors. Standard errors are in parenthesis below the estimated coefficients. ***, ** and * indicate statistical significance at the 1 percent, 5 percent, and 10 percent levels, respectively. effect and allows us to instrument corruption with lagged variables to address potential endogeneity. The estimated dynamic effect is significant but modest in size (0.24). In column 5, we report results from an estimation that allows member specific autocorrelation and presents corrected standard errors. 9 The coefficient on R H /Y in columns 4 and 5 is somewhat larger, indicating a decline in non-oil and gas revenues of 0.25 percentage points of GDP. The control variables are not statistically significant in specification 4, but in specification 5 non- 9 The procedure assumes that disturbances are heteroskedastic and serially correlated, with member specific autocorrelation coefficients. The average estimated AR(1) coefficient is 0.66.

9 hydrocarbon revenues would appear to increase as GDP per capita increases and as the level of corruption decreases. Columns 6 to 8 of Table 3 report results from the interaction of R H /Y with the dummy variables for the relative importance of hydrocarbon revenues, low and high levels of corruption, and periods of increasing and falling hydrocarbon revenue, respectively. The results in column 6 are somewhat counter-intuitive with the coefficients on the three interaction variables for the relative importance of hydrocarbon revenues indicating that the adverse effect of hydrocarbon revenues on the domestic revenue effort decreases as the share of hydrocarbon revenues in total revenues increases; moreover, the result of an F-test on the equality of the interacted coefficients rejects the hypothesis that the coefficients are equal (p value=0.05). The results reported in column 7 indicate that the negative response of the domestic revenue effort to hydrocarbon revenues is broadly the same in countries with low or high corruption; and in this case, an F-test on the equality of the interacted coefficients does not allow us to reject the hypothesis that the coefficients are equal (p value=0.45). In column 8, the coefficient on the interaction of R H /Y with the indicator variable for periods of rising and of falling hydrocarbon revenue suggests no difference in the size of the offset during these periods: the coefficients are virtually identical and an F-test does not allow rejection of the hypothesis that they are equal. Finally, column 9 presents the results for the specifications where R H and R NH are normalized by Y H and Y NH, respectively. The estimated coefficients on R H /Y H is -0.1, which is smaller than in any of the previous estimates of R H /Y, and the signs on the coefficients of the control variables are broadly in line with the previous estimates. However, the coefficient from this estimate has a NH H somewhat different interpretation as the narrower tax bases ( Y and Y ) increase the value of the ratios on both sides of the equation (see the summary statistics in Table 2). Evaluating the estimated coefficient for R H /Y H at the sample means indicates an offset of about 33 percent between hydrocarbon and non-hydrocarbon revenues. In this case, an interesting non-linearity emerges, suggesting that the offset decreases as hydrocarbon revenues increase. 10 IV. CONCLUSIONS The recent development literature suggests that countries receiving large revenues from natural resource endowments are likely to raise less revenue from domestic taxation, and that this creates governance problems because of the reduced incentive for the public scrutiny of government. This argument implies that there is a negative relation between government revenues from natural resources and revenues from other domestic sources, and causality running from a (reduced) domestic revenue effort to (increased) corruption. Our results from a panel of 30 hydrocarbon producing countries support the first part of this hypothesis. Thus, we find a statistically significant negative relation, with a typical result being that a 1 percentage point increase in hydrocarbon revenue (in relation to GDP) lowers non-hydrocarbon revenues by about 0.2 percent after controlling for other factors that might be expected to impact on domestic revenues. However, our finding that the negative response of the domestic revenue effort to hydrocarbon revenues is broadly the same in countries with low and high corruption levels, which suggests that factors other than the domestic revenue effort are the more important determinants of governance problems. 10 In columns 1 8 such nonlinearities are not significant.

10 REFERENCES Arellano, Manuel, and Stephen R. Bond, 1991, Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 58, pp. 277-297. Bauer, Peter, 1976, Dissent on Development (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press). Collier, Paul, 2006, Is Aid Oil? An Analysis of Whether Africa Can Absorb More Aid, World Development, Vol. 34, pp. 1482-97. Collier, Paul, and Anke Hoeffler, 2005, Democracy and Natural Resource Rents, Working paper GPRG-WPS-016 (Department of Economics, Oxford University). Gupta, Sanjeev, Benedict Clements, Alexander Pivovarsky, and Erwin Tiongson, 2004, Foreign Aid and Revenue Response: Does the Composition of Aid Matter? in Helping Countries Develop: The Role of Fiscal Policy, ed. by S. Gupta, B. Clements, and G. Inchauste (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Gupta, Abhijit Sen, 2007, Determinants of Tax Revenue Efforts in Developing Countries, Working Paper 07/184 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Keefer, Philip, and Stephen Knack, 1997, Why Don t Poor Countries Catch Up? A Cross- National Test of an Institutional Explanation, Economic Inquiry, Vol. 35, pp. 590-602. Lewis, Arthur, 1955, The Theory of Economic Growth (London: Allen and Unwin). Moore, Mick, 1998, Death Without Taxes: Democracy, State Capacity and Aid Dependence in the Fourth World, in The Democratic Development State, ed. by Mark Robinson and Gordon White (Oxford: Oxford University Press). Moore, Mick 2007, How Does Taxation Affect the Quality of Governance? IDS Working Paper 280, Brighton: IDS Tanzi, Vito, 1992, Structural Factors and Tax Revenue in Developing Countries: A Decade of Evidence, in Open Economies: Structural Adjustment and Agriculture, ed. by I. Goldin and L.A. Winters (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Viner, Jacob, 1952, International Trade and Economic Development (Glencoe, Illinois: Free Press).