A.1. Verifying that the period-by-period household budget constraint (12) is satis ed and that the current account is zero, to rst order

Similar documents
International Portfolios, Capital Accumulation and Foreign Assets Dynamics ( ] )

International Portfolios, Capital Accumulation and Foreign Assets Dynamics *

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

Equilibrium Asset Returns

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

Lecture Notes 1

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Comparative Statics. What happens if... the price of one good increases, or if the endowment of one input increases? Reading: MWG pp

Real Exchange Rate and Terms of Trade Obstfeld and Rogo, Chapter 4

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set 3 Solutions

Advanced International Macroeconomics Session 5

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing

Multiperiod Market Equilibrium

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III

Gains from Trade and Comparative Advantage

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

The Role of Physical Capital

Economic Growth and Development : Exam. Consider the model by Barro (1990). The production function takes the

Optimal Monetary Policy

1 Multiple Choice (30 points)

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default

Exercises on chapter 4

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

Microeconomics 3. Economics Programme, University of Copenhagen. Spring semester Lars Peter Østerdal. Week 17

Department of Economics Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Intermediate Macroeconomics

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

ECON Micro Foundations

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade.

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

2. Find the equilibrium price and quantity in this market.

The Representative Household Model

1 Non-traded goods and the real exchange rate

Working Paper Research. Endogenous risk in a DSGE model with capital-constrained financial intermediaries. October 2012 No 235

Mean-Variance Analysis

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems I (Solutions)

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Fall 2009

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

1 Two Period Production Economy

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Problem Set # Public Economics

Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice

Tries to understand the prices or values of claims to uncertain payments.

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #9 - Monopoly

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice

Econ Homework 4 - Answers ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS OF CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION. 1. Assume that a rm produces product x using k and l, where

1 Unemployment Insurance

PREPRINT 2007:3. Robust Portfolio Optimization CARL LINDBERG

Answer: Let y 2 denote rm 2 s output of food and L 2 denote rm 2 s labor input (so

The Economics of State Capacity. Ely Lectures. Johns Hopkins University. April 14th-18th Tim Besley LSE

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

SOLUTION PROBLEM SET 3 LABOR ECONOMICS

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model

1 Modern Macroeconomics

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing

Robust portfolio optimization

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

G + V = w wl + a r(assets) + c C + f (firms earnings) where w represents the tax rate on wages. and f represents the tax rate on rms earnings

Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

The Solow Growth Model. Martin Ellison, Hilary Term 2017

Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 19/ Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

For Online Publication Only. ONLINE APPENDIX for. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market

Micro Theory I Assignment #5 - Answer key

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality

Booms and Busts in Asset Prices. May 2010

Expected Utility and Risk Aversion

Principles of Optimal Taxation

An Allegory of the Political Influence of the Top 1%

A Portfolio Theory of International Capital Flows 1

Problem Set (1 p) (1) 1 (100)

Topic 3: International Risk Sharing and Portfolio Diversification

Income Distribution and Growth under A Synthesis Model of Endogenous and Neoclassical Growth

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Problem set 1 ECON 4330

Advertising and entry deterrence: how the size of the market matters

Monetary Policy and the Financing of Firms

Complete nancial markets and consumption risk sharing

UNIVERSITY OF TORONTO Joseph L. Rotman School of Management SOLUTIONS

1 Mar Review. Consumer s problem is. V (z, K, a; G, q z ) = max. subject to. c+ X q z. w(z, K) = zf 2 (K, H(K)) (4) K 0 = G(z, K) (5)

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Fiscal Policy

Lectures on Trading with Information Competitive Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium (Grossman and Stiglitz AER (1980))

Review Seminar. Section A

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Answer for Homework 2: Modern Macroeconomics I

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward. Discount Puzzle 1

Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

Problem Set 3. Consider a closed economy inhabited by an in ntely lived representative agent who maximizes lifetime utility given by. t ln c t.

Transcription:

TECHNICAL APPENDI FOR: May 6, 29 International Portfolios, Capital Accumulation and Foreign Assets Dynamics Nicolas Coeurdacier ( a,e ) Robert Kollmann ( b,c,e,* ) Philippe Martin ( d,e ) ( a ) Department of Economics; London Business School; Regent s Park; London NW 4SA; United Kingdom ( b ) ECARES; Université Libre de Bruxelles; CP 4; 5 Av. Franklin Roosevelt; B-5 Brussels; Belgium ( c ) ERUDITE, Faculté de Sciences Economiques; Université Paris II; 6 Av. du Général de Gaulle; 94 Créteil Cedex; France ( d ) Sciences Po; 27 rue Saint-Guillaume, 757 Paris, France ( e ) CEPR, 53-5 Gt. Sutton Street, London ECV ODG, United Kingdom. * Corresponding author. Send correspondance to: ECARES, Université Libre de Bruxelles; CP 4; 5 Av. Franklin Roosevelt; B-5 Brussels; Belgium E-mail addresses: ncoeurdacier@london.edu, robert_kollmann@yahoo.com, philippe.martin@sciences-po.fr - A.. Verifying that the period-by-period household budget constraint (2) is satis ed and that the current account is zero, to rst order In deriving the zero-order equilibrium portfolio (S; b), we replaced the period-by-period household budget constraint (2) by the static constraint (26). We now show that when a rst-order approximation of the static constraint holds at all dates, then a rst-order approximation of (2) holds likewise. Thus it is su cient to consider the static constraint (26) when solving for (S; b): 3

Following Devereux and Sutherland (26a,b), we express the period t budget constraint (2) of country i as NF A i;t+ = N i;t + NF A i;t R b;i t + i;t ; with NF A i;t+ p S j;ts i j;t+ p S i;ts j i;t+ + pb i;tb i i;t+ + p b j;tb i j;t+; j 6= i; N i;t p i;t y i;t P i;t C i;t P I i;ti i;t ; i;t S i j;tp S j;t (R S j;t R b i;t) S j i;t ps i;t (R S i;t R b i;t) + b i j;tp b j;t (R b j;t R b i;t); j 6= i: NF A i;t+ are country i s net foreign assets at the end of period t; and N i;t are i s net exports. R S i;t ; RS j;t ; Rb i;t ; Rb j;t are gross equity/bond returns between t and t (see (5)). i;t is the "excess return" on the country s net foreign assets (between t and t) relative to the return on the good-i bond. 39 As before, variables without time indices represent (deterministic) steady state values, and cz i;t (z i;t z i )=z i : Note that NF A i =, N i = ; p S p S H = ps F ; pb p b H = pb F ; d d H = d F ; p p H = p F, due to the symmetric structure of the two countries; also, RH S = RS F = Rb H = Rb F = =: A linear approximation of (??) around the steady state yields thus: NF A i;t+ = N i;t +NF A i;t =+S i jp S (d R S j;t dr b i;t ) Sj i ps (d R S i;t dr b i;t )+bi jp b (d R b j;t dr i;t b ); j 6= i (4) where S i j ; Sj i ; bi i and bi j are zero-order portfolio holdings. Symmetry implies Sj i = Si j = S; b = bi i = bi j ; for j 6= i. Hence: NF A i;t+ = N i;t + NF A i;t = + (S )p S (d R S i;t dr S j;t ) + bpb (d R b i;t dr j;t b ); j 6= i: (42) Solving the Euler equations (4) forward gives p S i;t = E P t %i t;t+ d i;t+ and p b i;t = E P t %i t;t+ p i;t+ :Up to rst order, the relative stock and bond prices and returns obey thus: cp S i;t dr S i;t cp S j;t = dr S j;t = ( E t (\d i;t+ \d j;t+ ); c p b i;t c p b j;t = E t (\p i;t+ \p j;t+ ); j 6= i; (43) )f E t (\d i;t+ \d j;t+ ); R db d i;t R b j;t = ( ) E f t (\p i;t+ \p j;t+ ); j 6= i: (44) 39 Note that i;t = Sj;t i (d j;t + p S i;t ) Sj i;t (d i;t + p S i;t ) + (p i;t + p b i;t )bi i;t + (p j;t + p b j;t )bi j;t NF A i;t Ri;t b : Thus, i;t is the di erence between country i s net external wealth (including net dividend and coupon income) at the beginning of period t, minus the hypothetical value of i s net external wealth at the beginning of t that would obtain if i fully invested her net external wealth at the end of t in the good-i bond. 3

with f E t z E t z E t z (revision of expectation between t and t): Thus, E t ( \ R S i;t+ \R S j;t+ ) = E t ( \ R b i;t+ \R j;t+ b ) = for > : up to rst order, the expected value of future excess returns is zero. Solving (42) forward (imposing the no-ponzi/transversality condition lim! E t NF A i;t+ = ) gives the following present value budget constraint: E t ( N i;t+ ) = NF A i;t =+(S )de f t (\d i;t+ \d j;t+ )+bpe f t (\p i;t+ \p j;t+ ); j 6= i; (45) where we used that fact that p S = d=( ), p b = p=( ): (45) holds if and only if: fe t ( N i;t+ ) = (S )de f t (\d i;t+ \d j;t+ ) + bpe f t (\p i;t+ \p j;t+ ); j 6= i (46) and E t ( N i;t+ ) = NF A i;t =: (47) (46) shows that, up to rst order, date t innovations to the expected present value of current and future country i net imports have to equal innovations to the present value of net dividend and net bond income received by country i: The static budget constraint In deriving the zero-order equilibrium portfolio, we replaced the period-by-period household budget constraint (2) by the static budget constraint: P i;t C i;t = w i;t l i;t +Sd i;t +( S)d j;t +b(p i;t p j;t ) (see (26)). This constraint can be expressed as: N i;t = (S )(d i;t d j;t ) + b(p i;t p j;t ). 4 Equivalently: N i;t = (S )d( c d i;t c dj;t ) + bp( cp i;t cp j;t ); j 6= i: (48) It is clear that when (48) holds at all dates, then the present value budget constraint (46) is also satis ed. We show next that (47) entails a restriction on the rst-order (time-varying) deviations of portfolio holdings from zero-order portfolio holdings. This implies that, when solving for the zero-order portfolio zero-order portfolio (S; b); it is su cient to consider the static budget constraint (26). A restriction on rst-order accurate (time-varying) portfolio holdings 4 Subtracting w i;t l i;t and d i;t from both sides of the static constraint gives: P i;t C i;t w i;t l i;t d i;t = (S )(d i;t d j;t ) + b(p i;t p j;t ):The left-hand side of this expression equals N i;t (as d i;t p i;t y i;t w i;t l i;t P I i;t I i;t): 32

Substitution of (48) into (47) yields: NF A i;t = (S )E t d(\d i;t+ \d j;t+ ) + be t p(\p i;t+ \p j;t+ ); j 6= i: (49) Using the formulae for relative asset prices (43), we can write this as: NF A i;t = (S )p S ( \ p S i;t \p S j;t ) + bpb ( \ p b i;t \p b j;t ); j 6= i: (5) Linearizing the expression NF A i;t = p S j;t Si j;t p S i;t Sj i;t + pb i;t bi i;t + pb j;t bi j;t gives NF A i;t (S )p S ( \ p S i;t \ p S j;t )+bpb ( \ p b i;t \ p b j;t )+(5Si j;t 5S j i;t )ps +(5b i i;t+5b i j;t)p b ; j 6= i; (5) where 5Sj;t i Si j;t ( S); 5S j i;t Sj i;t ( S); 5b i i;t bi i;t b; 5b i j;t bi j;t ( b) denote the deviations of portfolio holdings at the end of period t from the zero-order portfolio. (5) and (5) imply that, to rst order, the value of country net external assets, evaluated at steady state asset prices is zero: (5S i j;t 5S j i;t )ps + (5b i i;t + 5b i j;t)p b = (S i j;t S j i;t )ps + (b i i;t + b i j;t)p b = ; j 6= i: (52) The current account The period t current account of country i is: CA i;t = (S i j;t+ S i j;t )ps j;t (S j i;t+ S j i;t )ps i;t + (bi i;t+ b i i;t )pb i;t + (bi j;t+ b i j;t )pb i;t : Linearization of this expression gives: CA i;t = f(si j;t+ S i j;t ) (Sj i;t+ S j i;t )gps + (b i i;t+ b i i;t + bi j;t+ b i j;t )pb : It thus follows from (52) that CA i;t =, up to rst order. A.2. Returns and the equilibrium portfolio Equation (37) in the main text shows that the zero-order local equity position S depends on the covariance between components of relative (Home vs. Foreign) wage incomes and dividend payments that are orthogonal to the terms of trade: S = 2 2 Cov bq ( w d tl t; d b t) V ar bq ( d b : We now show that S can equivalently t) be expressed as a function of the covariance between components of relative (Home vs. Foreign) human capital returns and equity returns that are orthogonal to the return di erential between the Home-good and Foreign-good bonds. As shown above, country i net imports can be expressed as: N i;t = P i;t C i;t w i;t l i;t d i;t ; this can be written as: N i;t = py i ( ) \ P i;t C i;t ( )py i \w i;t l i;t py i ( ) c d i;t. 4 Inserting this 4 NB Steady state consumption spending is a fraction ( ) of output, where is the steady state ratio of investment spending to GDP; wage income and dividends account for fractions and of output, respectively. 33

expression into (46) gives: ( ) f E t P i;t+ \ C i;t+ = ( ) f E t w i;t+ \ l i;t+ + S( ) E f t \d i;t+ +( S)( ) E f t \d j;t+ + e be f t (\p i;t+ \p j;t+ ); j 6= i: (53) where e b b=y i is the local-good bond holding divided by steady state output. yields: Subtracting the linearized present value budget constraint (53) of country F from that of country H ( ) f E t [ P H;t+ \ C H;t+ P F;t+ \ C F;t+ ] = ( ) f E t (2S )( ) E f t [ \d H;t+ [ \ w H;t+ l H;t+ \ w H;t+ l H;t+ ]+ \d F;t+ ] + 2 e be f t dq t+ ; (54) where q t p H;t =p F;t are the Home terms of trade. E ective market completeness (up to rst order) implies that P H;t \ C H;t P\ F;t C F;t = ( )q t (see (28)). Thus, innovations to the present value of relative consumption spending are perfectly correlated with the return di erential between Home-good and Foreign-good bonds (from (44)): fe t [ P H;t+ \ C H;t+ P F;t+ \ C F;t+ ] = ( ) (Rb H;t RF;t): b De ne the return on country i Human capital as: Ri;t W P W i;t +wi;tli;t ; where P W Pi;t W i;t E P t %i t;t+ w i;t+ l i;t+ is the present value of the country i labor income; linearizing these formulae gives: [R W H;t dr W F;t = ( ) f E t [ \ w H;t+ l H;t+ \ w F;t+ l F;t+ ]: Using the expression for the cross-country equity return di erential shown in (44), we can thus express (54) as: ( )( )Rb t = ( )R W t + (2S )( )R S t + 2 e br b t: where R b t R b H;t R b F;t ; RW t R W H;t R W F;t ; RS t R S H;t R S F;t are Home-Foreign return di erentials for bonds, Human capital and equity, respectively. This condition implies: S = 2 2 Cov R b(rt W ; Rt S ) V ar R b(rt S ; (55) ) 34

with Cov R b(rt W ; Rt S ) EfRt W P [Rt W jrt]gfr b t S P [Rt S jrt]g; b V ar R b(rt S ) EfRt S P [Rt S jrt]g b 2 ; where P [Rt W jrt] b is the linear projection of Rt W on Rt: b Thus, the local equity share can be expressed as a function of the covariance between the components of relative (Home vs. Foreign) human capital returns and (relative) equity returns that are orthogonal to (relative) bond returns: equity home bias arises when that covariance is negative. The model here generates a negative covariance. In the main text we showed that a combination of exogenous shocks that raises relative Home real investment spending, without a ecting the terms of trade has these consequences: relative Home wage income rises, and the relative dividend of the Home rm falls. The same logic also applies directly to capitalized income streams, and thus to returns. Consider a combination of exogenous innovations that raises the present discounted value of relative Home real investment spending, without changing the present value of (current and future) Home terms of trade; that combination of shocks raises the present value of relative Home wage income, while lowering the present value of relative Home dividends; in other terms, such a combination of shocks has no e ect on the return di erential between Home-good and Foreign-good bonds, and no e ect on the present value of e cient relative Home consumption spending; however, it raises the relative return on Home human capital, while reducing the relative return of the Home stock. Holding constant the bond return di erential, the relative return on Home human capital co-moves thus negatively with the relative Home stock return: Cov R b(rt W ; Rt S ) < : 35

A.3. Corporate Debt The following results hold when rms (partly) nance investment spending by issuing debt: () The structure of equilibrium equity portfolio is una ected (i.e. the equity portfolio continues to be given by (32)); (2) Households s holdings of corporate debt exhibit a home bias in the same proportion as for stocks; (3) The net external bond positions are altered; if rms issue debt denominated in their local good, the range of parameters increases for which a country s net local-good debt position is negative. To understand these results note that, in the economy here, the Modigliani-Miller theorem holds, i.e. the issuance of corporate debt does not a ect rm values or equilibrium consumptions. Assume that rms issue bonds denominated in the good that they produce, and that one unit of a corporate bond pays one unit of output in all future periods; assume also that a constant share of the net investment of the country i rm P I i;t (I i;t K i;t ) is nanced by issuing debt. 42 The rest of investment spending P I i;t I i;t P I i;t (I i;t K i;t ) is nanced through retained earnings. Let D it denote the outstanding debt of the country i rm, at the beginning of period t. The price of one unit of the debt is p b it : Suppose that the country i household holds a fraction S [ S] of local [foreign] equity and of the outstanding local [foreign] corporate bonds. This portfolio strategy allows the household to o -set the implicit debt position entailed by its equity position. When S is set at the optimal value in the baseline model (where rms are fully equity nanced, = ), such a portfolio strategy thus generates the same nancial income as the household s portfolio in the baseline model; hence that portfolio strategy replicates the e cient consumption allocation (up to rst order). To see this, note that in the present setting the period t dividend of the country i rm equals a share of its output, p i;t y i;t (NB is the capital share) minus retained earnings P I i;t I i;t P I i;t (I i;t K i;t ); less the coupon payment p it D it made be the rm (to holders of its bonds). Thus, the date t dividend is: d it () p i;t y i;t P I i;t I i;t P I i;t (I i;t K i;t ) p it D it The rm s issuance of new corporate bonds in period t is given by: p D it (D it+ D it ) = Pi;t I (I i;t K i;t ). When the country i household holds a share S of local equity and local corporate debt, then that household derives the following income from local equity and corporate debt, in period t (net of the amount spent 42 Note that results () and (2) do not hinge on these assumptions. 36

at t to purchase a S fraction of the newly issued local corporate debt): Sd it () + Sp it D it Sp D it (D it+ D it ) = S p i;t y i;t P I i;ti i;t = Sdit ( = ): This corresponds to the dividend income of the household, from her holdings of local equity, in the baseline model in which rms do not issue debt d it ( = ): By the same reasoning, the portfolio strategy described above ensures that the household receives an income from her holdings of foreign equity and foreign corporate debt that equals her dividend income from foreign equity, in the baseline model. In order to replicate e cient risk-sharing (up to rst order), the household in addition has to hold the same amount of local-good and foreign-good non-corporate debt as in the baseline model. In summary, the equilibrium holdings of local and foreign equity shares and of non-corporate bonds are the same as in the baseline model, but investors now also hold a share S of domestic corporate debt and a share S of foreign corporate debt. When the country i rm issues one unit of debt denominated in local good i, then the country s overall (household+ rm) net local good debt position changes by S < units, as a share S of the new debt is purchased by the local household (while a share S of the new debt is bought by the foreign household). Thus the presence of local-good corporate debt lowers the country s overall net local-good debt. When all corporate debt is denominated in the local good, the country s overall (household+corporate) local-good debt position is b + (S )D Ht < b; where b is the local household s holding of local-good non-corporate debt (as discussed above, b has the same value as in the baseline model without corporate debt). 37