Under-pricing of IPO and investors interest on UK, Germany, Austria, Poland and Czech Republic capital markets. during

Similar documents
The Influence of Underpricing to IPO Aftermarket Performance: Comparison between Fixed Price and Book Building System on the Indonesia Stock Exchange

IPO Underpricing: What about the Shipping Sector?

Initial Public Offerings

Investor Demand in Bookbuilding IPOs: The US Evidence

IPO Underpricing in Hong Kong GEM

Winner s Curse in Initial Public Offering Subscriptions with Investors Withdrawal Options

PROSIDING PERKEM IV, JILID 1 (2009) ISSN: X

Performance of Initial Public Offerings in Public and Private Owned Firms of Pakistan. Henna and Attiya Yasmin Javid

INITIAL PUBLIC OFFERINGS:

PRICE STABILIZATION AND IPO UNDERPRICING: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY IN THE INDONESIAN STOCK EXCHANGE

신규공모주에대한수요예측조사, 공모가결정및초기수익률

Arni Utamaningsih Politeknik Negeri Padang Eduardus Tandelilin Universitas Gadjah Mada

Do Underwriters Encourage Stock Flipping? A New Explanation for the Underpricing of IPOs

CHEAP IPO: DOES IT MATTER?

Advanced Corporate Finance. 8. Raising Equity Capital

Initial Public Offering. Corporate Equity Financing Decisions. Venture Capital. Topics Venture Capital IPO

The Role of Demand-Side Uncertainty in IPO Underpricing

Investor Preferences, Mutual Fund Flows, and the Timing of IPOs

Demand uncertainty, Bayesian update, and IPO pricing. The 2011 China International Conference in Finance, Wuhan, China, 4-7 July 2011.

Pre-IPO Market, Underwritting Procedure, and IPO Performance

Who Receives IPO Allocations? An Analysis of Regular Investors

An empirical investigation of underpricing in Greek IPO s:

Litigation Risk and IPO Underpricing

Ownership Concentration and Initial Public Offering Performance: Evidence from Thailand

1 An Analysis of Factors Affecting Investor Demand for Initial Public Offerings in Singapore*

Secrecy in Pricing of Initial Public Offering. An Empirical Review of Nairobi Securities Exchange

1. Introduction Uncertainty has a pervasive presence throughout the IPO process. Firm insiders don't know how successful the offering will be or the a

MAGISTERARBEIT. Titel der Magisterarbeit. ''How to Determine the IPO Share Price?'' Verfasser. Miho Katić. angestrebter akademischer Grad

DOES OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE EFFECT IPO UNDERPRICING: EVIDENCE FROM THAI IPOS

formal organization dealing in securities in Malaya then. Subsequently in 1964, the Stock

Underpricing, explained by ex-ante uncertainty

Should IPOs be Auctioned? The Impacts of Japanese Auction-Priced IPOs

Transparency in IPO Mechanism: Retail investors' participation, IPO pricing and returns

Pricing Taiwan s Initial Public Offerings

Does Ownership Structure Effect IPO underpricing: Evidence from Thai IPOs

Exchange Rate and Economic Performance - A Comparative Study of Developed and Developing Countries

THE FACTORS OF THE CAPITAL STRUCTURE IN EASTERN EUROPE PAUL GABRIEL MICLĂUŞ, RADU LUPU, ŞTEFAN UNGUREANU

Litigation Risk and IPO Underpricing

9. Assessing the impact of the credit guarantee fund for SMEs in the field of agriculture - The case of Hungary

Investor Sentiment and IPO Pricing during Pre-Market and Aftermarket Periods: Evidence from Hong Kong

WHAT EXPLAINS IPO UNDERPRICING ACROSS COUNTRIES?

Do Venture Capitalists Certify New Issues in the IPO Market? Yan Gao

Why Do IPO Underwriters Allocate Extra Shares when They Expect to Buy Them Back?

How Important Are Relationships for IPO Underwriters and Institutional Investors? *

Underwriter s Discretion and Pricing of Initial Public Offerings

Venture Capital Valuation, Partial Adjustment, and Underpricing: Behavioral Bias or Information Production? *

FIN 540 Initial Public Offerings (IPOs) Why Issue Public Equity?

Monetary Economics Portfolios Risk and Returns Diversification and Risk Factors Gerald P. Dwyer Fall 2015

Most public firms tend to finance their projects first with retained earnings, then with debt, and only finally with equity (as a last resort)

Interrelationship between Profitability, Financial Leverage and Capital Structure of Textile Industry in India Dr. Ruchi Malhotra

Stabilization Activities by Underwriters after Initial Public Offerings

RESEARCH ARTICLE. Change in Capital Gains Tax Rates and IPO Underpricing

Underpricing of New Equity Offerings by Privatized Firms: An International Test * Qi Huang Hofstra University. and

Public information and IPO underpricing

Cross Border Carve-out Initial Returns and Long-term Performance

IPO Underpricing on Aktietorget & First North - An empirical study on how Guarantors, Management ownership and

The Changing Influence of Underwriter Prestige on Initial Public Offerings

Declining IPO volume: Cold issue market or structural change in the capital markets?

The Short-Run and Long-Run Returns of Initial Public Offerings in Taiwan

UNDERPRICING IN THE MALAYSIAN IPO MARKET DURING

The Distribution of Fees Within the IPO Syndicate

Appendixes Appendix 1 Data of Dependent Variables and Independent Variables Period

Biases in the IPO Pricing Process

STOCK MARKET CRISIS AND IPOS UNDERPRICING: EXPERIENCE FROM INDIAN STOCK MARKET

Underpricing in Swedish IPOs An investigation of the current situation and possible causes

From the IPO to the First Trade: Is Underpricing Related to the Trading Mechanism?

The Winner s Curse and Lottery-Allocated IPOs in China

IPO Underpricing in a Simultaneous Equations Model of Supply and Demand: Evidence from a Market of Retailers

The Influence of R&D Policy on Performance of the Companies Listed with Bucharest Stock Exchange (through Intangible Assets)

Anchor Investors in IPOs

FACTORS INFLUENCING THE UNDERPRICING OF INITIAL PUBLIC OFFERINGS IN AN EMERGING MARKET: MALAYSIAN EVIDENCE

IPO Market Cycles: Bubbles or Sequential Learning?

The Variability of IPO Initial Returns

Does Corporate Hedging Affect Firm Value? Evidence from the IPO Market. Zheng Qiao, Yuhui Wu, Chongwu Xia, and Lei Zhang * Abstract

BANK REPUTATION AND IPO UNDERPRICING: EVIDENCE FROM THE ISTANBUL STOCK EXCHANGE

IPO Underpricing and Conflict of Interest inside the Intermediation Structure. November 9, Chatchai Thisadoldilok* Abstract. I.

PhD Course in Corporate Finance

IPO Underpricing in the Hospitality Industry: A Necessary Evil?

Who Failed to Go Public with Best Efforts Offerings

The performance of initial public offerings in the biotechnology industry

Impact of Working Capital Management on Profitability: A Case of the Pakistan Textile Industry

The Performance of Internet Firms Following Their Initial Public Offering

Privatization versus Private Sector Initial Public Offerings in Poland*

Flipping Activity in Fixed Offer Price mechanism allocated. IPO s

Institutional Allocation in Initial Public Offerings: Empirical Evidence

International Review of Financial Analysis

AN EXAMINATION FACTORS INFLUENCING UNDER-PRICING OF IPOS ON THE LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE. Yuan Tian. degree of Master of Finance. Saint Mary s University

Tie-In Agreements and First-Day Trading in Initial Public Offerings

ANALYSIS OF CORRELATION BETWEEN THE EXPENSES OF SOCIAL PROTECTION AND THE ANTICIPATED OLD AGE PENSION

The Existence of Inter-Industry Convergence in Financial Ratios: Evidence From Turkey

IPO s Long-Run Performance: Hot Market vs. Earnings Management

Empirical Research on Correlation Between Internal Control and Enterprise Value

Chapter 2 Macroeconomic Analysis and Parametric Control of Equilibrium States in National Economic Markets

Available online at ScienceDirect. Procedia Economics and Finance 10 ( 2014 )

Sentiment Traders & IPO Initial Returns: The Indian Evidence

Per Capita Housing Starts: Forecasting and the Effects of Interest Rate

Evaluation of Short-run Market Performance of Initial Public Offerings: Evidence from Karachi Stock Exchange. Khalil Ahmad

Investment and financing constraints in Iran

Factors Influencing IPO Decisions. Do Corporate Managers Use Market and Corporate Timing? A Survey

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INSTITUTIONAL ALLOCATION IN INITIAL PUBLIC OFFERINGS: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE. Reena Aggarwal Nagpurnanand R. Prabhala Manju Puri

Transcription:

Under-pricing of IPO and investors interest on UK, Germany, Austria, Poland and Czech Republic capital markets during 2009-2011 Author: Duca Elena Elisabeta Coordinator:Prof. Univ. Dr. Anamaria Ciobanu Introduction In a capitalist economy a company becomes important if its stocks and bonds are quoted to the stock exchange. Initial public offering is defined by Loughran, Ritter si Rydqvist in 1994 as: publicly initial selling of a company s stocks for the first time on primary capital market and it gives access to public equity capital. Raising public equity capital allows risk distribution among investors so may lower the company s operating and investment expenses. This will provide a higher financial autonomy to the company and the shareholders will obtain, besides dividends, capital gains and they will know permanently the real value of their stocks attributed by the market. The companies will beneficiate of publicity, conducting to high levels of investor s interest and high trading volumes of the stock. The act of going public attracts new obligations too; there will be new transparency and disclosure requirements imposed by regulatory commissions. Also there is the risk that unwilling investors take over the control of the company, or that the new investors be more focused on capital gains than in sustaining the development of the firm. There are a lot of studies regarding initial public offerings and most of them reflect high initial returns for investors than for the issuer as IPO are underpriced initially. The related literature shows that under-pricing is an assumed cost, when going public and it is seen as an efficient answer to a complex question regarding valuation of new issuing companies (Rock 1986, Beatty and Ritter 1986, Welch 1986, Benveniste and Spindt 1989, Loughran, Ritter and Rydqvist in 1994 and so on).

This paper analyzes the relationship between initial under-pricing and pre- and post- initial public offering level of investor interest. The IPO influences the offering price of the IPO and creates divergence among investor s opinions conducting to high/low subsequent trading volume on the capital market. Even if there are other studies related to this subject (Reese 1998, Sohail and Raheman 2006, Ritter ) most of them are based on a single market and are quite old. This analysis is based on five European capital markets: Austria, UK, Germany, Poland and Czech Republic during 2009-2011. It is well known that this period follows the financial crisis from 2008, which affected most of capital markets and stock prices lost minimum 20% and maximum 70% of the their value from 2006 and 2007. 2009 was a critical year, the economic activity contracted significantly: Czech Republic with 4.2%, UK with 5%, Germany with 5% and Austria with 4.3%. Poland was the only country that had economic growth (+1.7%). During 2010 and 2011 the economic activity continued to recover, the monetary conditions from euro zone improved until August 2011 when in Europe triggered the sovereign crisis. This influenced negatively the recovery of the European economy, and uncertainty returned on financial markets. During 2009 IPO market declined massively in Europe, in value and volume too, with 57% to 126IPOs comparing to 295 in 2008, while the value dropped with 49% from 13953 millions of euro in 2008 to 7112 millions of euro in 2009. Although London Stock Exchange was on the second place both in volume and value, the number of IPO was lower by 75% as in 2008. Warsaw Stock Exchange had the biggest transaction in value through privatization of the energy company PGE: 1407 millions of euro. Compared to 2009, in 2010 there were 380 new listings, their value raised from 7112 millions of euro to 26282 millions of euro. 2011 had a fresh start, but until the end the uncertainty returned. During 2011 there were 430 new IPOs, more with 13% than in 2010, and 6 important listings of which 3 of them on London Stock Exchange: Glencore, Vallares and Justice Holdings. London Stock Exchange was leader through European capital markets reasserting itself as key financial center. Warsaw Stock Exchange was on third place as value of new listings with 2067 million euro raised and 31 new IPOs. As of these conditions, I consider that the results of the study are interesting to analyze, because most of the IPOs in the research sample are under-priced, and are consistent with the working hypothesis: under-pricing and investor s interest are correlated and influences one another.

Before presenting literature review, below you will find a short description of each IPO mechanism of fixing the offer price and allotting the shares between the investors: fixed priced offerings, auctions and book-building procedures. In fixed-priced offerings, shares are offered to all categories of investors, private and institutional, at a single and unchangeable price set in advance by the underwriter and filed in the introduction of the prospectus. A pro rata is used to allocate shares. Auctions or tender offering are IPO mechanisms in which the issuer sets the minimum price at which is willing to sell its shares. All investors, individual or institutional, are invited to place subscription orders at prices above or equal to minimum price. Orders are served in the order of descending order of price limits until clearing the number of shares offered. The lowest price is the equilibrium price. Also pro rata can be used. In book-building procedure, also called placing in UK, shares are offered exclusively to institutions but not to individual investors. The underwriter sets a price range for the shares to be placed, and investors are invited to place purchase commitments in an order book at prices inside the price range. At the end of subscription period, the issue price is determined by monitoring the subscription orders received, and in case of over subscription, the underwriter has complete discretion to allocate the shares. 2. Literature and empirical review Theories based on asymmetric information assume that there is difference of information between investors, issuers and the underwriter. Winner s curse model of Rock (1986) assumes that there are some investors which are better informed about the true value of the shares of an offer than others, the issuing firm, or its underwriting bank. Informed investors will bid only for attractively priced IPOs, whereas the uninformed will bid indiscriminately. This leads to a winner s curse on uninformed investors: they will receive all the shares they have bid and pay more in unattractive offers, while their demand is partly crowded out by the informed investors in attractive offerings. Also Rock assumes that the primary market is dependent on the continued participation of uninformed investors as informed investors are insufficient to bid all the offerings even if there were only

attractive ones. Finally the conclusion is that issuers obtain benefits from going public, even if it is costly, they raise the money they need and attract the equity capital of uninformed investors. Starting from this model Koh and Walter (1989) in Singapore, Levis (1990) in UK, Keloharju (1993) in Finland, tested the empirical implication of hypothesis that uninformed investors earn zero initial returns and informed investors conditional returns just cover their costs of becoming informed. Their results were un concluding because of the lack of information about of the cost of being informed. Another empirical implication of this model tested by Michaely and Shaw (1994) was that under-pricing is lower if the information is distributed more homogeneously across investor groups. He demonstrates that winner curse disappear if heterogeneity of information incline to zero. Ritter (1984) and Beatty and Ritter (1986) find out that there is a strong positive relationship between initial returns and ex-ante uncertainty. Information revelation theories (Benveniste and Spindt (1989), Benveniste sand Wilhelm (1990), and Spatt and Srivastava (1991)) have as a starting point the allocation of the shares issue in book-building procedure, which gives discretion over allocations to the underwriter. Therefore the book-building can be a mechanism used by underwriter to stimulate investors to reveal their information truthfully, by making in their own interest doing so. Investors who bid aggressively and so reveal favorable information, on the other hand, are rewarded with disproportionately large allocations of shares. But the more aggressive are investors bids, the more the offer price is raised, and the underwriter has to be very careful to leave money on the table as truth reporting would be incentive compatible. Other empirical tests regarding this procedure were made by Cornelli and Goldreich (2001, 2003) and Jenkinson and Jones (2004) using information about IPOs traded by some leading European investment banks. While Cornelli and Goldreich (2001) sustain Benveniste and Spindt theory, Jenkinson and Jones study is not in favor of book-building procedure. Principal-agent models reveal the dark side of the institutional arrangements, by highlighting the potential agency problems between the investment banks and the issuing firm (Loughran and Ritter (2003)). As under-pricing represents a wealth transfer from the IPO company to investors, a rent-seeking behavior can appear, because investors compete for allocations of the underpriced stock and may offer to the underwriter side-payments. Such side-payments can take the form of excessive trading commissions paid on unrelated transactions. Underwriting fees are typically proportional to IPO proceeds, and thus inversely related to under-pricing. Although this would

be an incentive for the underwriter to keep the under-pricing low, investment banks can gain more by making the offers more attractive to investors. Ljungqvist and Wilhelm (2003) made several empirical studies on US capital market which certified the existence of the principalagent problems described above. They show that the lower first-day returns are, the greater monitoring incentives of the issuing firms decision-makers (CEOs) are. Monitoring incentives are given to decision-makers in the form of equity ownership level and the higher equity ownership the decision-maker has he is getting a greater stake in the outcome of the pricing negotiations. Under-pricing as a signal of firm quality model (Ibbotson (1975)) sustain the idea if companies have better information about the present value or risk of their future cash flows than do investors, under-pricing may be used to signal the company s true high value. This cost may signal the quality of the company, and may allow the issuer to return to the market to sell equity on better terms at a later date. Allen and Faulhaber (1989), Grinblatt and Hwang (1989), and Welch (1989) sustained this theory adding some arguments in its favor. Starting from the premise of existing two types of firms (low-quality and high-quality), high-quality firms have incentive to credibly signal their higher quality, in order to raise capital on more advantageous terms. The proposed signal in the IPO signaling models is the issue price. Institutional theories have three approaches to explain IPO under-pricing. First is inspired from the insurance business as it works as a legal insurance seeking lawsuit avoidance. Logue (1973) and Ibbotson (1975), is that companies deliberately sell their stock at a discount to reduce the likelihood of future lawsuits from shareholders disappointed with the post- IPO performance of their shares. Empirical studies were made by Drake and Vetsuypens (1993) showing that firms sued were as much as under-priced as the other firms but Lowry and Shu (2002) consider that the study examined only ex-post events. Empirical analysis regarding the under-pricing and litigation probability relationship should take into account also the risk of being sued (the ex-ante probability). The second institutional approach is based on the practice of price support. One of the services that underwriters provide in connection with an IPO is price stabilization, intended to reduce price drops in the after-market for a few days or weeks. Ruud (1993) sustain the idea that IPO are not under-valuated deliberately, but the offer prices are fixed at the level expected by the market, and their evolution represent price stabilization imposed by the market itself. Benveniste,

Busaba, and Wilhelm (1996) consider this practice as a mechanism to consolidate the relationship between the underwriters and investors. As a result of book-building procedure there is evidence that institutional investors benefit from price stabilization, but Chowdhry and Nanda (1996) demonstrates that private investors too. Third institutional explanation may be that issuers could benefit from tax deductions from IPO under-pricing, but it still remains a challenge to create equilibrium between the cost of underpricing and the fiscal benefits. There is some evidence that under-pricing could be advantageous: Rydqvist (1997) showed that some companies from Sweden preferred to pay their employees through assets allocation in order avoid tax on salaries. Another study was made by Taranto (2003) which noticed that in US equity options were taxed differently in two stages: once at the option exercise and then later at the selling of the stock. While the tax on capital gain being deferred, and lower than on salaries, there is an explanation why management of companies preferred distribution of under-priced stocks towards employees. Going public is in many cases a step forward to the eventual separation of ownership and control. There are two models that seek to explain the under-pricing phenomenon in the context of agency cost approach regarding ownership and control. The results are diametrically opposed: while Brennan and Franks (1997) view under-pricing as a means to strengthen managerial control and the attendant agency costs by avoiding monitoring by a large outside shareholder, Stoughton and Zechner s (1998) analysis instead suggests that under-pricing may be used to minimize agency costs by encouraging monitoring by a large outside shareholder. Behavioral explanations for IPO under-pricing assume either the presence of irrational investors who bid up the price of IPO shares beyond true value, or that issuers are subject to behavioral biases and therefore fail to put pressure on the underwriting banks to have underpricing reduced. Welch (1992) shows that informational cascades can develop in some forms of IPOs if investors make their investment decisions sequentially: later investors can be influenced by the bids of earlier investors, rationally disregarding their own information. Successful initial sales are interpreted by subsequent investors as evidence that earlier investors held favorable information, encouraging later investors to invest whatever their own information. Conversely, disappointing initial sales can discourage later investors from despite of their private signals.

Investor sentiment model of Ljungqvist, Nanda, and Singh (2004) assume that investors hold optimistic beliefs about the future evolution of the IPO company. The issuer s objective is to obtain as much as possible from the investors surplus on the downward-sloping demand curve, and that is to maximize the excess valuation over the fundamental value of the stock. A large quantity of stock in the market will depress the price, so the optimal strategy involves holding back the stock in inventory in order to avoid price falling and naturally the market will adjust the price up to its real value. This explains the under-performance on the long run demonstrated by Ritter (1991). Loughran and Ritter (2002) propose an explanation for IPO under-pricing that combines prospect theory of Kahneman and Tversky (1979) with mental accounting concept of Thaler s (1980). They assume that the decision-makers initial valuation beliefs are reflected in the mean of the indicative price range reported in the issuing firm s IPO prospectus. This serves as a starting point in assessing the result of the IPO process. The offer price for an IPO differs from this reference point, because of the underwriter who can influence the decision maker s beliefs or maybe he has information revealed by institutional investors, both conducting to lowering the price range. The decision-maker finds a positive revision from the reference point as a wealth gain, while a positive initial return is perceived as a wealth loss under the assumption that shares could have been sold at the higher first-day trading price. 3. Methodology and data The objective of the study is to assess the relationship between initial under-pricing and investors interest pre-and after IPO procedure using a research sample of 214 IPOs from UK, Germany, Austria, Poland and Czech Republic during 2009-2011. The data are collected from each country stock exchange (London Stock Exchage, Deutsche Boerse, Vienna Stock Exchange, Warsaw Stock Exchange si Prague Stock Exchage) and from Bloomberg database. First I will analyze the daily return of the IPO and daily trading volume during one month after going public, and I have divided the sample into two groups: under-priced IPOs (which have positive initial returns) and over-priced IPOs (which have negative initial returns). Then using Eviews 5.1 I have made a multiple regression to analyze the influence of all variables on the initial return having the model below:

Initial return = a x Log (Initial trading volume) + b x Subscription rate + c x Log (Offer Size) + d x Market volatility + e x Log (Firm size ) + f 4. Results Comparing roughly the mean of the daily return with the mean of the daily trading volume there can be noticed that there is a positive relationship between the these two variables; from the two graphics below the initial return is much higher that the rest of the days (around 12% compared to 2%) and the initial trading volume is decreasing too from around 10% of the shares issued to 1% of the shares issued during the rest of the days. Figure 1. Daily evolution of the mean return / trading volume of IPOs After running the regression I have observed that the model is verified (both overall (F test) and individual for each estimated parameter (t test) are under the significance level of 5%) and the conclusion is that the daily return and the size of the company explains in a large proportion the evolution of the daily trading volume (adjusted R 2 = 25%) (see table below). Table 1. Regression result daily trading volume daily return firm size Dependent Variable: LOG(VTZ) Method: Panel Least Squares Date: 06/02/12 Time: 10:38 Sample: 1 4237 Cross-sections included: 20 Total panel (unbalanced) observations: 3475 White cross-section standard errors & covariance (no d.f. correction) Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-statistic Prob. RCP 0.238646 0.072107 3.309625 0.0009 LOG(MF) 0.437590 0.050640 8.641155 0.0000 C -5.972300 0.369373-16.16873 0.0000

R-squared 0.253514 Mean dependent var -3.064443 Adjusted R-squared 0.248974 S.D. dependent var 2.746992 S.E. of regression 2.380591 Akaike info criterion 4.578886 Sum squared resid 19568.89 Schwarz criterion 4.617842 Log likelihood -7933.814 F-statistic 55.84164 Durbin-Watson stat 1.725359 Prob(F-statistic) 0.000000 In the end I have tested the relationship between initial return (as dependant variable) and the initial trading volume, subscription rate, size offer, size of the company and volatility of the market (as independent variable). The result was that all these factors explain in proportion of 66% the variability of initial return; a raise of 1% of the subscription rate as measure of the pre- IPO investors interest contribute with a raise of 0.03% of the initial return (more than initial trading volume). Table 2. Regression result initial return initial trading volume subscription rate Dependent Variable: RI Method: Least Squares Date: 05/28/12 Time: 13:13 Sample: 1 214 Included observations: 214 Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-statistic Prob. LOG(VTI) 0.005780 0.002689 2.149032 0.0328 LOG(MO) -0.490809 0.026936-18.22112 0.0000 LOG(MF) 0.484758 0.026714 18.14614 0.0000 RS 0.032229 0.009526 3.383193 0.0009 VP 0.795302 2.190735 0.363030 0.7170 C 0.047188 0.035244 1.338878 0.1821 R-squared 0.667217 Mean dependent var 0.073415 Adjusted R-squared 0.659217 S.D. dependent var 0.174544 S.E. of regression 0.101893 Akaike info criterion -1.702151 Sum squared resid 2.159492 Schwarz criterion -1.607778 Log likelihood 188.1302 F-statistic 83.40633 Durbin-Watson stat 2.051587 Prob(F-statistic) 0.000000 After testing the behavior of the residual variable of the multifactor regression model, it results the validation of the three assumptions of the model: the normal distribution, homoskedasticity and nonauto-correlated errors. The validation of these assumptions shows that the model s parameters obtained through the least squares method are efficiently estimated.

The conclusion of this study was that the more the IPO are under-priced the more investors attract causing high level of the trading volume in the aftermarket, this analysis is providing evidence of a positive relationship between the pre IPO and post IPO investors interest and the initial return and the subsequent trading volume. Investor s interest tends (through the trading volume and the subscription rate) to be an essential problem for the success of an IPO, and companies accept the cost of under-pricing hoping that to attract the capital of more and more investors. Also specific factors that characterize each company are strong predictors of the under-pricing, confirming the results of other empirical studies (Michaely and Shaw (1994), Reese (1998), Ritter (2002)). Bibliography Agarwal S, Liu C, Rhee SG, 2008. Investor demand for IPO s and aftermarket performance: Evidence from the Hong Kong stock market. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 18: 176 190. Aussenegg W., 2000, Privatization versus Private Sector Initial Public Offerings in Poland, Multinational Finance Journal, 69 99. Aussenegg W., 2006, Underpricing and the Aftermarket Performance of Initial Public Offerings: the Case of Austria, in G. N. Gregoriou (Ed.), Initial Public Offerings: An International Perspective, Elsevier, Quantitative Finance Series, Amsterdam, 187-213. Beatty, R.P., and J.R. Ritter, 1986, Investment Banking, Reputation, and the Underpricing of Initial Public Offerings, Journal of Financial Economics 15, 213-232. Benveniste, L.M., and P.A. Spindt, 1989, How Investment Bankers Determine the Offer Price and Allocation of New Issues, Journal of Financial Economics 24, 343-361. Chowdhry, B., and V. Nanda, 1996, Stabilization, Syndication, and Pricing of IPOs, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 31, 25-42. Codirlaşu, A., 2007. Note de curs. MODULUL: Econometrie aplicată utilizând EViews 5.1, Masterat Managementul Sistemelor Bancare; Cornelli, F., and D. Goldreich, 2001, Bookbuilding and Strategic Allocation, Journal of Finance 56, 2337-2369.

Cornelli, F., and D. Goldreich, 2003, Bookbuilding: How Informative is the Order Book?, Journal of Finance 58, 1415-1443. Gajewski J-F., si C. Gresse, 2006, A survey of the European IPO Market, ECMI research report. Gujarati D, 2003. Basic Econometrics. New York: McGraw-Hill Hanley, K., 1993, The Underpricing of Initial Public Offerings and the Partial Adjustment Phenomenon, Journal of Financial Economics 34, 231-250. Ibbotson, R.G., and J.F. Jaffe, 1975, Hot Issue Markets, Journal of Finance 30, 1027-1042. IPO Watch Europe 2009, 2010 and 2011, Pricewaterhouse Coopers Jelic R. and R. Briston, 2003, Privatisation Initial Public Offerings: the Polish Experience, European Financial Management, 9(4), 457-484. Levis M., 1993, The Long-Run performance of Initial Public Offerings: The UK experience 1980-1988, Financial Management, 22(1), 28-41. Ljungqvist, A., 1997, Pricing Initial Public Offerings: Further Evidence from Germany, European Economic Review 41, 1309-1320 Ljungqvist, A., V. Nanda, and R. Singh, 2004, Hot Markets, Investor Sentiment, and IPO Pricing, Journal of Business. Loughran, T., and J.R. Ritter, 2002, Why Don t Issuers Get Upset About Leaving Money on the Table in IPOs?, Review of Financial Studies 15, 413-443. Loughran, T., and J.R. Ritter, 2003, Why Has IPO Underpricing Increased Over Time?, Financial Management, 5-37. Lowry, M., and G.W. Schwert, 2004, Is the IPO Pricing Process Efficient?, Journal of Financial Economics 71, 3-26. Miller, R.E., and F.K. Reilly, 1987, An Examination of Mispricing, Returns, and Uncertainty for Initial Public Offerings, Financial Management 16, 33-38. Reese WA, 1998. IPO under-pricing, trading volume, and investor interest. Working Paper, Tulane University Ritter, J. R., 2003, Differences between European and American IPO Markets, European Financial Management, 9(4), 421-434. Ruud, J.S., 1993, Underwriter Price Support and the IPO Underpricing Puzzle, Journal of Financial Economics 34, 135-151.

Rydqvist, K., 1997, IPO Underpricing as Tax-Efficient Compensation, Journal of Banking and Finance 21, 295 313. Sohail MK, Raheman A, 2009. Determinants of under-pricing of IPOs regarding financial & nonfinancial firms in Pakistan. European Journal of Economics, Finance and Administrative Sciences, 15: 62-73. Thaler, R., 1985, Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice, Marketing Science 4, 199-214. Welch, I., 1996, Equity Offerings Following the IPO: Theory and Evidence, Journal of Corporate Finance 2, 227-259.