Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/ / 24

Similar documents
Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting MarketAFA, Disruptions 1/7/ / 14

Option Pricing Modeling Overview

Model Estimation. Liuren Wu. Fall, Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College. Liuren Wu Model Estimation Option Pricing, Fall, / 16

Dynamic Relative Valuation

Linearity-Generating Processes, Unspanned Stochastic Volatility, and Interest-Rate Option Pricing

Option P&L Attribution and Pricing

Simple Robust Hedging with Nearby Contracts

Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions

A New Framework for Analyzing Volatility Risk and Premium Across Option Strikes and Expiries

Simple Robust Hedging with Nearby Contracts

Predictability of Interest Rates and Interest-Rate Portfolios

Implied Volatility Surface

The Black-Scholes Model

A Multifrequency Theory of the Interest Rate Term Structure

Unified Credit-Equity Modeling

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

The Black-Scholes Model

Using Lévy Processes to Model Return Innovations

Parametric Inference and Dynamic State Recovery from Option Panels. Nicola Fusari

Parametric Inference and Dynamic State Recovery from Option Panels. Torben G. Andersen

Local Variance Gamma Option Pricing Model

Exploring Volatility Derivatives: New Advances in Modelling. Bruno Dupire Bloomberg L.P. NY

Calculating Implied Volatility

Portfolio Management Using Option Data

Modeling the Implied Volatility Surface. Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives and Risk Management 2003 Barcelona May 22, 2003

Applying stochastic time changes to Lévy processes

Stochastic Volatility and Jump Modeling in Finance

Pricing and hedging with rough-heston models

Credit-Implied Volatility

Counterparty Credit Risk Simulation

Option Pricing for a Stochastic-Volatility Jump-Diffusion Model

Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model

Two-Factor Capital Structure Models for Equity and Credit

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Valuation of Volatility Derivatives. Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives & Risk Management 2005 Paris May 24, 2005

Short-Time Asymptotic Methods In Financial Mathematics

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes

A Simple Robust Link Between American Puts and Credit Insurance

Hedging under Model Mis-Specification: Which Risk Factors Should You Not Forget?

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Implied Volatility Surface

1. What is Implied Volatility?

FX Smile Modelling. 9 September September 9, 2008

Short-Time Asymptotic Methods In Financial Mathematics

Quadratic hedging in affine stochastic volatility models

Pricing of a European Call Option Under a Local Volatility Interbank Offered Rate Model

Some remarks on VIX futures and ETNs

Modeling Yields at the Zero Lower Bound: Are Shadow Rates the Solution?

Near-expiration behavior of implied volatility for exponential Lévy models

Managing the Newest Derivatives Risks

Generalized Multi-Factor Commodity Spot Price Modeling through Dynamic Cournot Resource Extraction Models

A Simple Robust Link Between American Puts and Credit Protection

A Consistent Pricing Model for Index Options and Volatility Derivatives

Supplementary Appendix to The Risk Premia Embedded in Index Options

An Overview of Volatility Derivatives and Recent Developments

STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY MODELS: CALIBRATION, PRICING AND HEDGING. Warrick Poklewski-Koziell

Jump and Volatility Risk Premiums Implied by VIX

Lecture 11: Stochastic Volatility Models Cont.

Developments in Volatility Derivatives Pricing

On modelling of electricity spot price

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs. Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo

Heston Stochastic Local Volatility Model

Self-Exciting Corporate Defaults: Contagion or Frailty?

The Black-Scholes Model

A Closed-form Solution for Outperfomance Options with Stochastic Correlation and Stochastic Volatility

Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions

Lecture 9: Practicalities in Using Black-Scholes. Sunday, September 23, 12

Calibration Lecture 4: LSV and Model Uncertainty

Explaining the Level of Credit Spreads:

Short-Time Asymptotic Methods in Financial Mathematics

Option Pricing for a Stochastic-Volatility Jump-Diffusion Model with Log-Uniform Jump-Amplitudes

Pricing Variance Swaps under Stochastic Volatility Model with Regime Switching - Discrete Observations Case

A Simple Robust Link Between American Puts and Credit Insurance

INVESTMENTS Class 2: Securities, Random Walk on Wall Street

An Analytical Approximation for Pricing VWAP Options

Statistical methods for financial models driven by Lévy processes

MLEMVD: A R Package for Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Multivariate Diffusion Models

Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Models

Smile in the low moments

Rough volatility models

Wishart spectral dynamics

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

1 Introduction. 2 Old Methodology BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM DIVISION OF RESEARCH AND STATISTICS

Credit Risk Modelling: A Primer. By: A V Vedpuriswar

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Empirical Distribution Testing of Economic Scenario Generators

Chapter 18 Volatility Smiles

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pr] 18 Feb 2010

Rough Heston models: Pricing, hedging and microstructural foundations

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications

European option pricing under parameter uncertainty

Empirical Option Pricing

Transcription:

Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions Liuren Wu, Baruch College and Graduate Center Joint work with Peter Carr, New York University and Morgan Stanley CUNY Macroeconomics and Finance Colloquium November 4, 2011 Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 1 / 24

What are the roles of an option pricing model? 1 Interpolation and extrapolation. Broker-dealers: Calibrate the model to actively traded option contracts, use the calibrated model to generate option values for contracts without reliable quotes (for quoting or book marking). 2 Alpha generation. Investors: Hope that market deviations from model fair valuation are mean reverting. 3 Risk management. The estimated dynamics provide insights on how to manage/hedge the risk exposures of the option positions. 4 Answer economic questions with the help of option observations. Macro/corporate policies interact with investor preferences and expectations to determine financial security prices. Reverse engineering: Learn about policies, expectations, and preferences from security prices. You need a model to link them together. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 2 / 24

What can we learn from options... that we cannot learn as easily from primary securities? 1 Time variation in risk and risk premium: Options market is the natural market for volatility trading. Carr and Wu (RFS 2009): Document variance risk premium behaviors on stock indexes and single names. Bakshi, Carr, Wu (JFE, 2008): Identify pricing kernels from options on a currency triangle. 2 Time variation in crash risk: Deep out-of-money (DOOM) puts provide natural insurance for economic dooms. Carr and Wu (RFS 2011): Link DOOM puts to credit insurance. Bakshi and Wu (MS 2010): Understand/predict the Nasdaq bubble from QQQQ options. 3 This paper links capital structure decisions to option price behavior. Increasing financial leverage not only increases market risk (beta, equity vol), but also increase default risk (credit spread). Options market can be the information source for both. To do this, we need to go from statistical to structural... Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 3 / 24

Background: Reduced-form option pricing models Two general, tractable frameworks: 1 Affine models (Duffie, Pan, Singleton (2000)) Returns and variance rates are linear ( affine ) combinations of some hidden statistical factors. Factors can rotate, causing identification issues. Economic meanings of the factors are not clear. 2 Time-changed Lévy processes (Carr and Wu (2004)) Each source of economic shock is captured by one Lévy process. The time-varying intensity of the financial market response to each economic shock is captured by its stochastic time change business clock versus calendar clock. The framework facilitates the design of well-identified models with economically meaningful structures. 3 This paper: Add capital structure decisions on top of reduced-form option pricing models. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 4 / 24

Background: Capital structure models Capital structure decisions and their impacts on equity and bond pricing are often analyzed via structural models. The classic example, Merton (1974): Model asset value dynamics as Geometric Brownian motion. The firm only has a zero-coupon bond maturing at a fixed maturity. Equity is a call option on the asset, with strike equal to the debt principal and maturity equal to the debt maturity. Many extensions are proposed for more realistic asset value dynamics, debt structure, default mechanisms... Pros: Link equity volatility to capital structure decisions (financial leverage) and business composition (asset volatility). Cons: Stylized and not tractable for pricing equity options. Cremers, Driessen, Maenhout (RFS 2008): A big calibration effort to link the average credit spread to equity index option prices, resolving the credit spread puzzle... Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 5 / 24

A new, structural, reduced-form model We propose a reduced-form model with many economic structures. The model allows three distinct economic channels of interaction between equity return and volatility: 1 The leverage effect: With business risk fixed, an increase in financial leverage level leads to an increase in equity volatility. A financial leverage increase can come from stock price decline while the debt level is fixed Black (76) s classic leverage story. It can also come from active capital structure management. 2 The volatility feedback effect on asset valuation: A positive shock to business risk increases the discounting of future cash flows, and reduces the asset value, regardless of the level of financial leverage. 3 The self-exciting behavior of market disruptions: A downside jump in the index leads to an upside spike in the chances of having more of the same. We explore what structural questions can be answered from observations on stock index options. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 6 / 24

Separate the financial leverage variation from the asset value dynamics Decompose the forward value of the equity index F t into a product of the asset value A t and the equity-to-asset ratio (EAR) X t, F t = A t X t. This is just a tautology, (1) Model leverage X t as a stand-alone CEV process: dx t /X t = δx p t dw t, p > 0. (2) Leverage effect: A decline in X increases leverage [by definition], reduces equity value [via (1)], and raises equity volatility [via X p ]. Structural link: When A is fixed, the equity return volatility becomes a pure power function of the leverage ratio. A similar (more restricted) volatility structure can be obtained from the structural model of Leland (94). Firms can (and do) actively manage their leverages (Adrian & Shin (2008)). Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 7 / 24

The asset value dynamics Model the asset value A t separately, in addition to leverage variation, da t A t = vt Z dz t + 0 (ex 1) ( µ(dx, dt) π J (x)dxvt J dt ) ( ), dvt Z = κ Z θz vt Z dt + σz vt dzt v, E [dzt v dz t ] = ρdt, ( ) dvt J = κ J θj vt J 0 dt σj x ( µ(dx, dt) π J (x)dxvt J dt ). Volatility feedback ρ < 0. Self-exciting crashes σ J > 0. Negative jumps in asset return are associated with positive jumps in the jump arrival rate v J t. Jump specification: Variance gamma high-frequency jump: π J (x) = e x /v J x 1. When X is fixed, the equity dynamics follow the asset dynamics. ρ < 0 is often referred to as the leverage effect, without distinguishing whether the negative correlation is really driven by financial leverage change or just volatility feedback on the business valuation. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 8 / 24

A different notation for the asset value dynamics We can write the log asset return ln A T /A t as a summation of two time-changed Lévy processes, [ ln A T /A t = Z T Z t,t 1 ] [ ] 2 T t,t Z + J T J t,t k J (1)Tt,T J, Two types of movements for asset return: (i) normal-time market fluctuations (Brownian motion Z) and (ii) large market disruptions (jump J). Apply separate time changes (Tt,T Z, T t,t J ), defined via their respective activity rates, T T Tt,T Z vs Z ds, Tt,T J vs J ds, t t Think of t as calendar time, and T as the business clock on which each business activity runs. The intensities of the two types of movements can vary separately. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 9 / 24

The stock price dynamics The stock price dynamics: 1 {}}{ 2 3 ( ) p { }}{{ }}{ Ft df t /F t = δ dw t + vt Z dz t + (e x 1) ( µ(dx, dt) π(x)dxvt J dt ) A t Linking/extending 3 strands of literature: 1 The local volatility effect of Dupire (94): Scaling F t by A t (both in dollars) makes the return variance a unitless quantity, and renders the dynamics scale free. Power dependence on leverage is supported by structural models. 2 The stochastic volatility of Heston (93): Used purely for volatility feedback, regardless of leverage. 3 The high-frequency dampened power law jumps (Wu, 2006): Arrival rate varies stochastically, and jumps synchronously with jumps in return. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 10 / 24

Alternative representation Let vt X = δ 2 Xt 2p. The stock price dynamics can be written as a three-factor stochastic volatility model: df t /F t = v X t dw t + v Z t dz t + R 0 (e x 1) ( µ(dx, dt) π(x)dxv J t dt ). where dv X t = κ X (v X t ) 2 dt σ X (v X t ) 3/2 dw t, a 3/2-process. (3) with κ X = p(2p + 1) and σ X = 2p. Henceforth, normalize δ = 1. Financial leverage variation is a separate source of stochastic volatility for stock return. The 3/2-vol of vol dependence in (3) has been shown to perform better than square-root dependence, e.g., Bakshi, Ju, Yang (2006). The structurally derived non-stationarity (κ > 0) helps to match long-dated option pricing behaviors. The model can be represented either as a local vol model with level dependence or a pure scale-free stochastic volatility model without level dependence unifying the two strands of literature. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 11 / 24

Market prices of risks and Active capital structure decisions The specifications so far are on the risk-neutral dynamics: Simplifying assumptions: Constant market prices (γ v, γ J ) for diffusion variance risk (Z t ) and jump risk (J t ). Capital structure questions: Financial managers make financial leverage decisions based on the current levels of all three types of risks: dx t = Xt 1 p ( ax κ XX X t κ XZ vt Z κ XJ vt J ) dt + X 1 p t dwt P. Market price of W t risk is γ X t = a X κ XX X t κ XZ v Z t κ XJ v J t. κ XX : Mean reversion, leverage level targeting. κ XZ : Response to diffusion (normal-market) business risk. κ XJ : Response to jump (crash) business risk. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 12 / 24

Data OTC implied volatility quotes on SPX options, January 1996 to March 2008, 583 weeks. 40 time series on a grid of 5 relative strikes: 80, 90, 100, 110, 120% of spot. 8 fixed time to maturities: 1m, 3m, 6m, 1y, 2y, 3y, 4y, 5y. Listed market focuses on short-term options (within 3 years). OTC market is very active on long-dated options. Why include long-dated options? At one maturity, an implied volatility smile/skew can be generated by many different mechanisms all you can learn is a heavy-tailed distribution. To distinguish the different roles played by the different mechanisms and answer the structural questions, we need to look at how these smiles/skews evolve across a wide range of maturities and over different time periods. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 13 / 24

The average implied volatility surface and skew: CLT? 9 8 Implied volatility, % 30 25 20 15 80 90 100 Relative strike, % 110 120 1 2 3 4 5 Maturity, years Mean implied volatility skew, % 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 1 2 3 4 5 Maturity, years Implied volatilities show a negatively sloped skew along strike. Return distribution has a down-side heavy tail. The skew slope becomes flatter as maturity increases due to scaling: 80% strike at 5-yr maturity is not nearly as out of money as 80% strike at 1-month maturity. When measured against a standardized moneyness measure d = ln(k/100)/(iv τ), the skew defined as, SK t,t = IV t,t (80%) IV t,t (120%) d t,t (80%) d t,t (120%), does NOT flatten as maturity increases. Central limit theorem does NOT kick in up to 10 years. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 14 / 24

Principal component analysis 80 A. Relative contributions B. Loading of the 1st PC Normalized eigenvalue, % 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 80 90 100 4 110 3 2 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 120 0 Principal component Relative strike, % Maturity, years C. Loading of the 2nd PC D. Loading of the 3rd PC Factor loading on P1 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0.2 0.4 5 0.6 0.6 Factor loading on P2 0.4 0.2 0 0.2 0.4 Factor loading on P3 0.4 0.2 0 0.2 0.4 80 80 90 100 110 Relative strike, % 120 0 1 4 3 2 Maturity, years 5 90 100 110 Relative strike, % 120 0 1 4 3 2 Maturity, years 5 Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 15 / 24

Asymmetric interactions 4 Weekly implied volatility level change, % 3 2 1 0 1 2 3 4 Weekly implied volatility skew change, % 1 0.5 0 0.5 1 5 10 5 0 5 10 Weekly index return, % 10 5 0 5 10 Weekly index return, % Self-exciting behavior: Implied volatility and skew respond more to large downside index jumps than upside index jumps. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 16 / 24

Option pricing and model estimation Option pricing: Quadrature integration of FFT option prices on asset [ c (F t, K, T ) = E t E t [(X A T K) + ] ] (XT = X ) Xt Estimation: Fix model parameters and use the 3 states (X t, v Z t, v J t ) to capture the variation of the 5 8 implied volatility surface: Let V t [X t, v Z t, v J t ] be the state. State propagation equation: V t = f (V t 1 ; Θ) + Q t 1 ε t. Let the 40 option series be the observation. Measurement equation: y t = h(v t ; Θ) + Re t, (40 1) y: OTM option prices scaled by the BS vega of the option. Assume that the pricing errors on the scaled option series are iid. Estimate 17 parameters over 23,320 options (11 years, 583 weeks, 40 options each day), using (quasi) maximum likelihood method joint with unscented Kalman filter. The model is very parsimonious and well-identified. Option pricing performance is miles better than any models in the literature. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 17 / 24

Relative variance and skew contributions Θ Estimates Std Error p 2.9952 0.0086 ρ -0.8388 0.0038 σ J 5.6356 0.0321 v J 0.1926 0.0004 Average instantaneous return variance contributions from (X t, v Z t, v J t ): Source Variance Volatility Leverage: E P [Xt 2p ] = 0.0117 (10.84%) Asset diffusion: E P [vt Z ] = 0.0231 (15.19%) Asset jump: E P [(vj 2 + v 2 + J )v J t ] = 0.0136 (11.67%) All three types of interactions are strong: Leverage effect: p = 2.8427 volatility feedback: ρ = 0.8354 self-excitement: σ J = 5.6355 Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 18 / 24

Implied volatility responses to financial leverage shocks 0.27 Effects of X t variation 0.45 Effects of X t variation At the money implied volatility, % 0.26 0.25 0.24 0.23 0.22 0.21 0.2 0.19 0.18 One month implied volatility, % 0.4 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.17 0 1 2 3 4 5 Maturity, years 0.1 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115 120 Relative strike, % Leverage v X t : Mean-repelling (drift=p(2p + 1)(v X t ) 2 dt) Responses to shocks become larger at longer maturities. An increase in leverage increase ATM vol more than OTM vol. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 19 / 24

Implied volatility responses to diffusion business shocks 0.26 Effects of v Z variation t 0.5 Effects of v Z variation t At the money implied volatility, % 0.24 0.22 0.2 0.18 0.16 0.14 One month implied volatility, % 0.45 0.4 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.12 0 1 2 3 4 5 Maturity, years 0.1 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115 120 Relative strike, % Diffusion business risk v Z t : Strong mean reversion (κ Z = 3.0112) Responses decline quickly as option maturity increases. An increase in diffusion business risk flattens the skew. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 20 / 24

Implied volatility responses to crash business shocks 0.24 Effects of v J t variation 0.5 Effects of v J t variation 0.23 0.45 At the money implied volatility, % 0.22 0.21 0.2 0.19 0.18 0.17 One month implied volatility, % 0.4 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.16 0 1 2 3 4 5 Maturity, years 0.1 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115 120 Relative strike, % Jump business risk v J t : Slow mean reversion (κ J = 0.0009) Responses do not decline. An increase in crash business risk increases the skew (OTM put option price). The variation of the implied volatility level and skew at different maturities helps us identify the variations of the three different risk sources. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 21 / 24

Sample variation of the three types of risks The S&P 500 Index 1600 1500 1400 1300 1200 1100 1000 900 800 v t X 0.035 0.03 0.025 0.02 0.015 0.01 0.005 700 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 0 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 0.14 0.12 0.1 0.08 4.5 4 3.5 3 2.5 v Z t 0.06 0.04 0.02 v J t 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 0 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 Financial leverage (v X t ) reached historical highs before the burst of the Nasdaq bubble. The diffusion variance risk (v Z t ) peaked during the 2003 recession. The crash risk (vt J ) spiked during the LTCM crisis. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 22 / 24

The capital structure decision dx t = Xt 1 p ( ax κ XX X t κ XZ vt Z κ XJ vt J Θ Estimates Std Error a X 0.0003 0.0003 κ XX 0.0001 0.0000 κ XZ 17.5341 0.4735 κ XJ -0.0774 0.0000 ) dt + X 1 p t dwt P κ XX = 0.0001: Capital structure is very persistent. κ XZ = 17.534: High diffusion business risk reduces X t and hence increases the financial leverage. κ XJ = 0.0774: High jump business risk increases X t and hence reduces the financial leverage. The key concern of financial leverage decision is default/crash (sustainability), not daily fluctuations Levering up increases your fluctuation, but also increases your return,... if only you can survive. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 23 / 24

Concluding remarks Many structural models have been proposed to answer capital structure questions, in stylized manners. Many reduced-form models have been proposed to match implied volatility smiles, without worrying about their structural meanings. We propose a model that is tractable and generates very good option pricing performance. Meanwhile, it can infer structural information from equity options. It is helpful to model the variation of the financial leverage and the business risk separately to bring structures to reduced-form models, to link local volatility models with stochastic volatility models, to generate good pricing performance on equity options over both short and long option maturities. The approach has potentials in analyzing single name stock options. Link the different capital structure management styles to the different behaviors of the option implied volatility surface. Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/2011 24 / 24