ANALYSIS OF THE SOUTH AFRICAN INPUT-OUTPUT TABLE

Similar documents
Tutorial letter 102/3/2018

Economics 214. Macroeconomics

1 What does sustainability gap show?

The contribution of British American Tobacco South Africa to the Western Cape economy

A 2009 Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) for South Africa

The Economy Wide Benefits of Increasing the Proportion of Students Achieving Year 12 Equivalent Education

WHAT IT TAKES TO SOLVE THE U.S. GOVERNMENT DEFICIT PROBLEM

Economic Impact Assessment of Updated Delegate Projections for Proposed Redevelopment of the Halifax World Trade and Convention Centre

An overview of the South African macroeconomic. environment

International Journal of Business and Economic Development Vol. 4 Number 1 March 2016

Economic Impact Assessment Nova Scotia Highway Construction Program

NEW I-O TABLE AND SAMs FOR POLAND

The Economic Value of the Adult Social Care sector - Northern Ireland Final report

Determination of manufacturing exports in the euro area countries using a supply-demand model

TOPIC 1: IS-LM MODEL...3 TOPIC 2: LABOUR MARKET...23 TOPIC 3: THE AD-AS MODEL...33 TOPIC 4: INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT...41 TOPIC 5: MONETARY POLICY

The Centre for Spatial Economics

SOCIAL ACCOUNTING MATRIX (SAM) AND ITS IMPLICATIONS FOR MACROECONOMIC PLANNING

The Inforum LIFT Model: Analysis of Illegal Immigration

Exercise 1 Output Determination, Aggregate Demand and Fiscal Policy

What is Macroeconomics?

Economics is the study of decision making

Notes on the monetary transmission mechanism in the Czech economy

An Estimate of the Effect of Currency Unions on Trade and Growth* First draft May 1; revised June 6, 2000

INDIAN HILL EXEMPTED VILLAGE SCHOOL DISTRICT Social Studies Curriculum - May 2009 AP Economics

February 03, Chapter 10 AD_AS_Business Cycle.notebook. Chapter 10: Economic Fluctuations Pages ,

Regulatory Announcement RNS Number: RNS to insert number here Québec 27 November, 2017

THE INFLUENCE OF MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY ON AGGREGATE DEMAND

23/03/2012. Government Budgets

Chapter 10 AD_AS_Business Cycle.notebook. May 08, Jun 16 9:29 PM. Jun 16 9:38 PM. Jun 16 9:50 PM. Jun 16 9:46 PM

ECS1601. Tutorial Letter 201/1/2018. Economics 1B. First Semester. Department of Economics ECS1601/201/1/2018

THE KWAZULUNATAL ECONOMY A LEADS AND LAGS ANALYSIS 1 UPDATE 13

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s

Her Majesty the Queen in Right of Canada (2017) All rights reserved

ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE ANALYSIS OF THE AUSTRALIAN PROPERTY SECTOR USING INPUT-OUTPUT TABLES. YU SONG and CHUNLU LIU Deakin University

Glossary. Average household savings ratio Proportion of disposable household income devoted to savings.

General Equilibrium Analysis Part II A Basic CGE Model for Lao PDR

Objectives AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

Distinguish between the three broad functions of government.

FEEDBACK TUTORIAL LETTER

An ex-post analysis of Italian fiscal policy on renovation

Chapter 4 THE SOCIAL ACCOUNTING MATRIX AND OTHER DATA SOURCES

Ontario Economic Accounts

1 Introduction. 2 The empirical approach. Abstract. Philippe Burger Department of Economics, University of the Free State Accepted September 2009

2015 Ford World Men s Curling Championships Halifax, Nova Scotia

The Economic Value of the Adult Social Care sector - UK Final report

Monitoring the Performance

2. Aggregate Demand and Output in the Short Run: The Model of the Keynesian Cross

Advanced Market Analysis for Commercial Real Estate

download instant at

A Social Accounting Matrix for Scotland

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation

SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING TO DIFFERENT MEASURES OF POVERTY: LICO VS LIM

Multipliers: User s guide

The Economic Value of the Adult Social Care sector - Wales Final report

A comparison of economic impact analyses which one works best? Lukas van Wyk, Melville Saayman, Riaan Rossouw & Andrea Saayman

Regional convergence in Spain:

MEASURING GDP AND ECONOMIC GROWTH

THE KWAZULUNATAL ECONOMY A LEADS AND LAGS ANALYSIS 1 UPDATE 17

THE INFLUENCE OF MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY ON AGGREGATE DEMAND. Chapter 34

Advanced Market Analysis for Commercial Real Estate

Chapter 23. The Keynesian Framework. Learning Objectives. Learning Objectives (Cont.)

RESIDENTIAL REAL ESTATE MARKET OUTLOOK: 2019 WILL BE ANOTHER BANNER YEAR

National Minimum Wage in South Africa: Quantification of Impact

Economic Impacts of the BC Property Development Industry in 2016 (Report Date: February 2018)

1. The most basic premise of the aggregate expenditures model is that:

THE EFFECTIVENESS OF COMPETITION LAW IN PROMOTING ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT

Summary of Macroeconomic Models ECS2602 C O M P I L E D B Y S K E N N E D Y- PA L M E R & T U Y S ( R E V I S E D F E B R U A RY )

APPENDIX 7.0-B BC Stats BC Input - Output Model Report

SHORT-RUN EQUILIBRIUM GDP AS THE SUM OF THE ECONOMY S MULTIPLIER EFFECTS

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY LECTURE 3: AGGREGATE EXPENDITURE AND EQUILIBRIUM INCOME

G.C.E. (A.L.) Support Seminar- 2016

Analysis on the Input-Output Relevancy between China s Financial Industry and Three Major Industries

III. 9. IS LM: the basic framework to understand macro policy continued Text, ch 11

FINANCIAL ACCOUNTS OF HUNGARY DATA SOURCES, METHODS AND RESULTS OF DATA COMPILATION 2O18

= C + I + G + NX = Y 80r

BBPA Local impact of the beer and pub sector 2010/11

Econ 223 Lecture notes 2: Determination of output and income Classical closed economy equilibrium

HOW STRONG ARE SECTORS LINKED TO EACH OTHER? AN INPUT-OUTPUT ANALYSIS FOR THE CASE OF TURKEY

ECON 1102: MACROECONOMICS 1 Chapter 1: Measuring Macroeconomic Performance, Output and Prices

FINANCIAL SOCIAL ACCOUNTING MATRIX: CONCEPTS, CONSTRUCTIONS AND THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK ABSTRACT

The Impact of Tax Policies on Economic Growth: Evidence from Asian Economies

Economic impact of the demand for human capital in Ghana: An input-output multiplier analysis

In understanding the behavior of aggregate demand we must take a close look at its individual components: Figure 1, Aggregate Demand

Chapter 4. Determination of Income and Employment 4.1 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ITS COMPONENTS

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data

Focus on Household and Economic Statistics. Insights from Stats SA publications. Nthambeleni Mukwevho Stats SA

LETTER. economic COULD INTEREST RATES HEAD UP IN 2015? JANUARY Canada. United States. Interest rates. Oil price. Canadian dollar.

SUMMARY (Danish Economy Autumn 1997)

Effect of tariff increase on residential sector preliminary results. Dr Johannes C Jordaan

One of the major recommended

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS OF FLORIDA AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS TO CUBA

ANNEX 3. Overview of Household Financial Assets

Analyzing Properties of the MC Model 12.1 Introduction

The effect of increasing subsidies for health on household welfare using a general equilibrium model (CGE) in Iran

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus)

Economic Policies in the New Millennium

Macroeconomics, 12e (Gordon) Chapter 2 The Measurement of Income, Prices, and Unemployment

Introduction to economic growth (2)

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Problem Set # 1, Answers

Econ 102 Exam 2 Name ID Section Number

Transcription:

SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No 4:661689 661 ANALYSIS OF THE SOUTH AFRICAN INPUTOUTPUT TABLE TO DETERMINE SECTOR SPECIFIC ECONOMIC IMPACTS: A STUDY ON REAL ESTATE Douw Boshoff Construction Economics, University of Pretoria Reyno Seymore School of Economics, University of Pretoria Accepted: October 2016 Abstract Inputoutput analysis is a well known method of analysing specific economic activity and the influence of different sectors on the economy and on one another. This study investigates the ability of inputoutput analysis to consider the importance of commercial real estate on the economy. It analyses the economic activity, contribution to GDP, employment created and taxes generated with reference to direct, indirect and induced impacts. The research shows the contribution of the specific sector on the economy and highlights the ability of inputoutput analysis to determine the impact of different types of property and locational analysis. The interaction of property with the economy is discussed, which also enables the use of the analysis reported here for short term future forecasting, whereby expected real estate activity is used to forecast the direct, indirect and induced effects on the economy. Key words: South Africa, inputoutput analysis, real estate economics, economic impact, property activity, shortterm economic forecasting JEL: A120, C670, R110, 150 1 Introduction Real Estate is considered globally as a very important contributor to economic activity. Not only does it provide the space needs for virtually all other economic activities to take place, including manufacturing, retail activities, business services etc., but itself also contributes directly and indirectly to economic activity and job creation. Altogether the real estate subsector is reported by the South African Reserve Bank within the financial intermediation, insurance, real estate and business services sector. During 2013 the sector contributed a total of R1 320 billion to the fixed capital stock of the country, while the gross fixed capital formation for the sector added R97 856 million to this figure for the same period, which represents 20.9 per cent and 14.95 per cent respectively of the whole economy. Of the abovementioned capital formation, R69 697 million, or 71.2 per cent of the sector, is attributable to nonresidential buildings. Apart from the capital investment of the sector in the economy, nonresidential real estate also contributed R81 billion to the gross domestic product of South Africa during 2013, before the effects of taxes and subsidies are taken into consideration, which resulted in approximately 212 000 jobs, 1.5 per cent of all jobs in the economy. The objective of the study is to analyse the property sector by making use of inputoutput (IO) analysis in order to determine the influence of this sector on the economy. The originality of the paper is vested in the multidisciplinary view it uses to show the total impact of the sector on the economy, including its direct, indirect and induced impacts. The paper is structured as follows: Section 2 provides the theoretical framework consisting of basic principles and previous literature. Section 3 provides an overview of historical economic as well as sectorspecific activity while the impact of such activity is measured and documented in Section 4. The theory and interrelatedness of concepts are discussed and validated in Section 5, whereafter a shortterm forecasting of impact is provided in Section 6. How to cite DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.17159/22223436/2016/v19n4a13 ISSN: 22223436

662 SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 2 Theoretical framework The South African National Income and Production Accounts (NIPA) provides a good overview of the South African economic system. In addition, there are various models and literature that explain the relationships within the property sector, collectively referred to as space and capital markets (Archer & Ling, 1997; ArchourFischer, 1999; Dipasquale & Wheaton, 1992; Du Toit, 2002; Fisher, 1992; Fisher, HudsonWilson & Wurtzebach, 1993; Viezer, 1998; and Viezer, 1999). Boshoff (2013) performed a case study on the applicability of these models to the South African economy. The explanation of space and capital markets by various authors highlights the interrelatedness of real estate and certain economic applications. It is important to note that real estate forms a critical part of the economic system and that it is equally influenced by economic variables. Boshoff (2013) shows that a long term relationship exists between the demand for space and construction activity that forms the supply of real estate and thus dictates the equilibrium point of real estate activity. The South African NIPA accounts provide an overview of the general economic system and how the property sector fits into this system. The more specific property activities could then be explained by theories on space and capital markets so that these variables and their interrelated impact could be measured by way of IO analysis. An inputoutput (IO) matrix is a representation of national or regional economic accounting that records the way industries trade with one another and produce (in other words; the flow of goods and services). Flows are registered in a matrix, simultaneously by origin and by destination (OECD, 2006). The inputoutput analysis is the standard method for measuring the spread effects of changes in the final demand for a product of an industry or sector (Surugiu, 2009). A standard IO table is shown in Figure 1. Input flows are recorded in the columns of the table, and outputs are recorded in the rows (Sporri, Morsuk, Peters & Reichert, 2007). Intermediate demand (Z) represents the interindustry transactions table, a matrix of transactions between the producing sectors. Final demand (y) consists of the household, government and rest of the world sectors. Value added to the producing sector consists of capital and labour, and receives interest and wages. Figure 1 An illustrative IO table Source: Sporri et al. (2007)

SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 663 An IO analysis is typically used to calculate the economic effects of exogenous changes in y; for example, the economic impact (in terms of industry output, employment and income) of a new harbour development, in both the short and longterm, on a specific economy. If x represents the vector of industry outputs, y the vector of final demand and Z the matrix of interindustry transactions, then the relationship between these is (Sporri et al., 2007): æ1ö ç ç. x = Zç. + y ç ç. ç è1ø Equation 1 A matrix of technical coefficients (A) is then derived by dividing interindustry transactions by output: zij a ij = Equation 2 x j The elements of A describe the direct, first round impact of any change in final demand. In other words, how much input from sector i is used per monetary output of sector j. When this is solved 1 for production as a function of final demand, the Leontief inverse matrix ( L = ( I A) ) is calculated. The Leontief inverse matrix can then be used to calculate the output multiplier, the income multiplier and income effects (D Hernoncourt, Cordier & Hadley, 2011). The output multiplier for a particular industry can be defined as the total of all outputs from each domestic industry required in order to produce one additional unit of output. ( Outputmult iplier) j = å i L Equation 3 ij The income multiplier indicates the increase in income from employment as result of a change of R1 of income from employment in each industry. vi Lij ( Incomemult iplier ) j = Equation 4 å i v Where: viz the ratio of employment to output for each industry. Lastly, the income effects show the impact on income from employment throughout the economy arising from a unit increase in final demand for industry j s output. j ( Incomeeffe cts) j = å i vi L Equation 5 ij The following assumptions underlie any IO analysis: The production functions of industries do not change. The economy can be described with linear production functions. The region is large enough to make imports by individuals insignificant. It is important to note that IO tables assume linear relations between inputs and outputs from different sectors as well as linear relations between outputs and final demand (D Hernoncourt, Cordier & Hadley, 2011). Employment impact The Leontief inverse matrix together with employment data can be used to calculate the employment multiplier and employment effects (D Hernoncourt, Cordier & Hadley, 2011). The employment multiplier shows the total increases in employment throughout the economy resulting from an increase in final demand.

664 SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 wi Lij ( employment multiplier ) j = Equation 8 å i w Where: w is equal to one fulltime job per rand of total output for each industry. Employment effects calculate the impact on employment throughout the economy arising from a change in final demand for industry j s output of one unit. ( employment effects) j = å j wi Lij separate employment from effects Equation 9 Depth of impact estimation The analysis will estimate direct, indirect and induced impacts. Table 1 provides definitions of the direct and indirect impacts. They distinguish between GDP (economic growth) and employment (by skill level). Direct impact The direct economic impact is the change in economic activity directly related to the scenario simulated. Direct impact Total employment created / destroyed directly related to the scenario simulated. Table 1 Definitions of direct and indirect impact GDP (Economic growth) j Indirect impact The indirect economic impact seeks to capture the knockon benefits to the host economy (e.g. the additional money spent in the local area by say a reduction in property taxes in the longrun). Indirect impact, also known as the multiplier effect, includes the respending within the local economy. Employment (by skill level) Indirect impact Indirect employment comprises the total jobs created/destroyed as a result of specific scenarios simulated. Local companies that provide goods and services to the property sector increase/decrease their number of employees as property investment changes, thus creating an employment multiplier. The induced impact measures the next round of impacts which are the results from a change in household spending in the general economy. 3 Economic activity within the real estate subsector This section will provide some statistics on the activities within the real estate sector. This is in order to understand the extent of the sector in the economy, as well as to indicate the trends of activity. It is important to note that the relationship between the real estate sector within the wider economy, as well as the activity in the construction is typically explained under FDW and REEFM models (Boshoff, 2013). a) General economic activity i Economic activity The economic activity for South Africa over the past ten years, up to the end of 2013, is displayed in Figure 2. In the context of inputoutput analysis, total economic activity is calculated as the sum of the value of all inputs on the production side (intermediate demand), as well as the value of final demand (final demand from households, government and exports). It is evident that there was a gradual increase with a stable growth in activity, with the actual figures in R million indicated by the bars and the yeartoyear growth displayed in figures next to each bar. The period between 2004 and 2008 was characterised by large increases in economic prosperity which were felt throughout the economy, with growth of up to 14.4 per cent per year during the 2007/2008 period.

SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 665 During the 2009 recessionary period, economic activity slowed down to just above 7 per cent and has remained below 8 per cent ever since, with economic activity growing to just below R10 trillion by the end of 2013. Figure 2 Actual economic activity at current prices 10 000 000 9 000 000 8 000 000 7 000 000 6 000 000 5 000 000 4 000 000 3 000 000 2 000 000 1 000 000 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 16,00% 14,00% 12,00% 10,00% 8,00% 6,00% 4,00% 2,00% 0,00% Source: South African Reserve Bank (2014) Although economic activity showed stable increases, it is considered to be a weak indicator of the real state of economic growth in the country since it partly reflects price increases. It is nevertheless important to note this as it indicates the sum of all activity in the different sectors of the economy. ii Gross domestic product The real GDP (at constant 2005 prices), defined as the market value of final goods and services newly produced within South Africa during one year, at constant 2005 market prices, shows a 10 year average growth of 3.40 per cent. It is also indicated in Figure 4 that during the 2009 recessionary period a negative growth of 1.53 per cent was experienced and although increasing again to 3.14 per cent and 3.60 per cent in 2010 and 2011 respectively, the growth slowed down to 2.47 per cent and 1.89 per cent during 2012 and 2013 respectively. This caused the average growth for the past five years, or the period since the start of the 2009 recession, to slow to 1.9 per cent. The GDP should, however, be considered also taking into consideration the number of people that contributes to this. In this regard the per capita GDP, or GDP divided by the population of the country, provides another insight into the economic situation. Still remaining on the real GDP, the yoy per capita GDP at constant 2005 prices is indicated by Figure 5. From this it is evident that the growth started to slow down from 2008, turning negative in 2009 and although positive again in 2010 and 2011, it slowed down again in 2012 and 2013. If a fiveyear moving average growth is considered, as indicated by Figure 6, it can also be seen that the period immediately prior to the 2009 recession was a particularly prosperous one, with fiveyear average growth for three consecutive years being the highest in the history of South Africa, or at least for the period that data is available. This, however, slowed down significantly in the subsequent years and, if this trend continues, might turn negative soon.

666 SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 Figure 4 Gross domestic product at constant 2005 prices Source: South African Reserve Bank (2014) Figure 5 Year on year growth of per capita GDP at constant 2005 prices Source: South African Reserve Bank (2014) 4,00% 3,00% 2,00% 1,00% 2,47% 2,32% 2,35% Figure 6 5 Year moving average growth of per capita GDP at constant 2005 prices 1,34% 1,48% 1,83% 1,23% 0,87% 0,53% 0,23% 0,74% 1,33% 1,29% 0,37% 0,64% 0,77% 0,63% 0,46% 0,68% 0,40% 0,62% 1,15% 1,67% 1,98% 2,64% 3,10% 3,26% 2,14% 1,79% 1,40% 0,83% 0,68% 0,00% 0,23% 1,00% 2,00% 3,00% 1969 1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 0,88% 1987 1,89% 1,38% 0,16% 0,66% 1989 0,46% 0,64% 1991 1993 1995 1,46% 2,04% 1,88% 1,20% 0,16% 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 Source: South African Reserve Bank (2014)

SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 667 iii Employment It was mentioned in the previous section that the population size should be taken into consideration when looking at the GDP figures. In addition to this, the official employment and unemployment figures should also be considered in order to comprehend the influence of real estate on the economy. According to the 2011 census, the total population of South Africa is approximately 51,77 million people. For the past 20 years the average annual population growth was approximately 1.7 per cent, slowing down to an average of 1.34 per cent for the past ten years and 1.18 per cent for the past five years. This gives an estimated current population of approximately 53,01 million people. Statistics South Africa (2015a) defines unemployed persons as those, aged 15 64 years, who: a) were not employed in the reference week; and b) actively looked for work or tried to start a business in the four weeks preceding the survey interview; and c) were available for work, i.e. would have been able to start work or a business in the reference week; or d) had not actively looked for work in the past four weeks but had a job or business to start at a definite date in the future and were available. The total employed workforce was approximately 14,07 million people in 2011, with a total unemployment of 24.8 per cent (narrow definition) during that year, indicating a total workforce of approximately 18,70 million people. The distribution of employment vs. unemployment is displayed in Figure 7. Figure 7 Percentage of workforce employed Source: Adapted from Statistics South Africa (2013a) Of the total employed workforce, approximately 72.4 per cent is formally employed and 27.6 per cent informally employed as indicated by Figure 8, while the former is divided into 17.4 per cent highly skilled, 42.2 per cent skilled and 40.4 per cent semiskilled and unskilled, shown in Figure 9.

668 SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 Figure 8 Distribution of formal employment vs. informal employment Source: Adapted from Statistics South Africa (2013a) Figure 9 Distribution of level of skill iv Source: Adapted from Statistics South Africa (2013a) Tax generated Total taxes generated in the economy could be viewed from the total taxes on products and production in order to compare the amount of taxes on products and production generated by the real estate sector to that of the rest of the economy. In the context of inputoutput analysis, net taxes on products and other taxes less subsidies, are captured in the value added matrix. This total is indicated in Figure 10. The total nominal tax generated is approximately R439 billion for taxes on products and R374 billion in taxes on production and imports as at the end of 2013. This amounts to a total increase of approximately 11.45 per cent and 11.61 per cent per annum respectively over the past 20 years. Another two sets of taxes that are recorded by the SARB are the national government tax revenue from property and the local government cash receipts from taxes. These are displayed in Figure 11 and provide an indication of propertyspecific taxes. They are not the same as taxes in products and production in the property sector, but should be viewed separately.

SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 669 R millions 900 000 800 000 700 000 600 000 500 000 400 000 300 000 200 000 100 000 0 Figure 10 Distribution of taxes generated Taxes on products Taxes on production and imports Source: South African Reserve Bank (2014) R millions 40 000 35 000 30 000 25 000 20 000 15 000 10 000 5 000 Figure 11 Level of tax revenue 0 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 National government tax revenue: Total taxes on property Local governments: Cash receipts from operating activities: Taxes Source: South African Reserve Bank (2014) b) Industryspecific economic activity In this section, the past economic activity within the construction sector and real estate subsector will be provided. The link between construction and real estate needs to be reaffirmed, as the real estate subsector creates the opportunities for the construction sector, while the latter provides additional stock to the former, which changes the general equilibrium levels, as per space and capital market theory. The emphasis of this section will be to indicate the activity specifically with regard to building plans passed and buildings completed. This makes it possible to distinguish between the relative size of the economic activity within different geographical areas as well as different types of buildings. Lastly, by considering the amount spent on buildings completed in relation to the total square meter size of buildings completed, it is possible to provide an indication of the cost per square meter spent on these buildings, which provides an indication of cost changes over time, but more importantly, also provides an indication of the quality of buildings being built in different geographical areas and for different purposes.

670 SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 i Building plans passed The total building plans passed in all larger municipal areas as indicated in Figure 12 increased gradually from 2001 through to a peak in May 2007, after which a reduction could be seen during the recessionary period before a gradual increase since the first half of 2010. It is, however, evident that the total number of building plans passed is approximately at the same level as in 2007 before the decline, although the economy has strengthened a fair amount since then. This leaves the total number in real terms still behind 2008, with a total value of just over R85 billion at the end of 2013, or a monthly average of approximately R7.1 billion, compared to approximately R86.5 billion during 2007, with a monthly average of R7.2 billion. 10000000 9000000 8000000 7000000 6000000 5000000 4000000 3000000 2000000 1000000 Figure 12 Total national building plans passed per month and Nonresidential buildings plans passed as percentage of all property nationally 45,0% 40,0% 35,0% 30,0% 25,0% 20,0% 15,0% 10,0% 5,0% 0 0,0% Jan 2000 Jan 2001 Jan 2002 Jan 2003 Jan 2004 Jan 2005 Jan 2006 Jan 2007 Jan 2008 Jan 2009 Jan 2010 Jan 2011 Jan 2012 Jan 2013 Nominal value of building plans passed Nonresidential buildings as % of total Source: Adapted from Statistics South Africa (2013b) This total figure, R7.2 billion, includes all property, and the contribution of nonresidential property as a percentage of all property can be seen in Figure 12. From this it is evident that commercial property remains between approximately 15 per cent and 30 per cent of total property, with a gradual increase since early 2004 up to 2010 and after a short steep decline, another increase since early 2011. Although not empirically tested, this seems to follow a similar trend to the economic activity, suggesting a relationship between economic activity and real estate demand. This is in line with the a priori expectation due to property being required for all commercial activity, i.e. offices for business services, shopping centres for retail and industrial buildings for manufacturing and other industrial activity. It furthermore suggests that residential property is less sensitive to economic activity, but more to affordability (refer Boshoff, 2010). ii Buildings completed The statistics for buildings completed provide a view on the addition of stock to the property market and are useful in determining the economic activity between different types of buildings and in different geographical locations. Furthermore, by considering the economic cycle in both building plans passed and buildings completed, it is possible to see how long it takes for the value of buildings completed to react to a change in building plans passed. This provides an economic

SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 671 lag which could then be used to forecast the value of buildings to be undertaken, by considering the current level of building plans being passed and also to evaluate the percentage of buildings that are actually built after the plans are passed. In Figure 13 the total annual value of buildings completed nationally is shown alongside the value of nonresidential buildings completed. Figure 14 then shows the total value of nonresidential buildings as a percentage of the total. 70 000 000 Figure 13 Nonresidential buildings completed vs. total buildings completed 60 000 000 50 000 000 R'000 40 000 000 30 000 000 20 000 000 10 000 000 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 Total Nonresidential buildings Source: Adapted from Statistics South Africa (2013b) 35,0% Figure 14 Nonresidential buildings completed as percentage of total buildings 30,0% 25,0% 20,0% 15,0% 10,0% 5,0% 0,0% 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Source: Adapted from Statistics South Africa (2013b)

672 SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 iii Construction costs per m 2 Figure 15 provides the information with regard to the cost of construction of different building types at constant 2010 prices. This provides a view on the change in cost due to specification level changes. It can be seen that office and banking space is lately being provided at the highest cost of construction, although there are a number of periods where shopping space is very similar. This is then followed by other nonresidential buildings and additions and alterations while industrial and warehouse space is being added at the lowest cost of construction. Of importance in these figures is also the fluctuations in costs over time, caused by specification levels and geographical areas. 8 000 7 000 6 000 5 000 Figure 15 National construction cost per square meter R/m 2 4 000 3 000 2 000 1 000 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Office and banking space Shopping space Industrial and warehouse space Other nonresidential buildings Other buildings Source: Adapted from Statistics South Africa (2013b) 4 Contribution to the South African economy This section will specifically consider the results of the IO analysis and discusses the influence that different property types in different geographical areas has on the South African economy. The first set of results provides the economic activity that is created within the real estate subsector, followed by the influence on the GDP, employment opportunities created and lastly tax generated. It should be noted that the following figures are based on the economic relationships between real estate and other sectors only. They exclude the physical aspect of property being used for any economic activity and the influence of that on the economy. a) Economic activity As mentioned in Section 3, the total economic activity in South Africa amounted to R9,316,400 million. Of this, the contribution of nonresidential realestate is calculated by the IO analysis to be approximately 0.66 per cent through direct impact, 1.22 per cent through indirect impact and 1.87 per cent by including induced impact. This comes to a total contribution of R61,416 million direct impact, R113,604 million indirect impact and R173,973 million induced impact. This impact on economic activity by nonresidential real estate as attributed to the different provinces is provided as per Figures 16 and 17. It is evident that the greatest economic activity occurs in Gauteng, followed by the Western Cape and then KwaZuluNatal. The direct impact is measured using the technical coefficients as derived by equation 2. The direct impact considers the value of the real estate necessary to enable the current level of economic activity or GDP. The tax generated by the real estate sector, associated with this level, is

SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 673 also reported. The indirect impact applies equations 39 and considers the indirect impact of the real estate sector, by including the knockon benefits of the real estate industry. This is also known as type 1 multipliers. Lastly, the induced impact is measured using type 2 multipliers, taking into account changes in household spending. Household spending is effectively endogenized in the transaction matrix. This could be seen as the broadest measure of economic impact. Type 2 multipliers are used as published by Statistics South Africa (2015b). Figure 16 Economic activity contribution All property per province 250 000 208 919 200 000 150 000 100 000 50 000 44 905 82 829 126 427 7 925 14 666 22 474 1 359 2 516 3 859 4 622 8 557 13 117 29 397 54 300 83 016 5 364 9 930 15 220 74 637 137 298 6 603 12 222 18 731 2 247 4 160 6 379 Direct Indirect Induced Source: Authors calculations Figure 17 Economic activity contribution Nonresidential property per province 70 000 60 000 60 574 50 000 39 587 40 000 30 000 20 000 10 000 9 899 18 318 28 064 2 569 4 757 7 293 230 425 652 952 1 763 2 704 8 772 16 233 24 872 980 1 816 2 784 21 416 1 804 3 341 5 122 704 1 305 2 001 Direct Indirect Induced

674 SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 Figure 18 Economic activity contribution Nonresidential property per property type 50 000 45 000 40 000 35 000 30 000 25 000 20 000 15 000 10 000 14 652 13 606 15 159 3 910 14 089 27 100 25 169 28 036 7 239 26 060 41 497 38 544 42 928 11 097 39 907 5 000 Direct Indirect Induced Office and banking space Shopping space Industrial and warehouse space Other nonresidential buildings Additions and alterations b) Gross domestic product (GDP) The total GDP for South Africa in 2013 was approximately R3,385,369 million. Of this, 1.41 per cent was created by nonresidential real estate through direct activity, while the indirect impact was 1.55 per cent and the induced impact 2.39 per cent. This amounts to a total contribution of approximately R47,817 million added to the GDP by the real estate subsector directly, R52,357 million indirectly and R81,051million through induced impact, and is distributed in the different provinces as per Figure 19. The contribution of nonresidential real estate to the GDP in the different provinces is shown in Figure 20, while the contribution by different property types nationally is shown in Figure 21. Figure 19 Contribution to GDP All property per province 120 000 100 000 96 832 80 000 60 000 40 000 20 000 34 829 38 111 58 744 6 174 6 762 10 475 1 060 1 161 1 800 3 603 3 946 6 116 22 844 25 005 38 624 4 181 4 578 7 096 57 679 63 074 5 145 5 635 8 732 1 752 1 919 2 975 Direct Indirect Induced

SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 675 Figure 20 Contribution to GDP Nonresidential property per province 30 000 28 202 25 000 20 000 15 000 10 000 5 000 7 711 8 444 13 079 2 003 2 194 3 401 179 196 304 742 813 1 261 6 834 7 483 11 592 765 837 1 299 16 658 18 237 1 407 1 541 2 389 549 602 933 Direct Indirect Induced Figure 21 Contribution to GDP Nonresidential property per property type 25 000 20 000 19 331 17 958 19 997 18 591 15 000 10 000 5 000 11 406 10 594 11 800 3 048 10 969 12 489 11 600 12 920 3 338 12 010 5 174 Direct Indirect Induced Office and banking space Shopping space Industrial and warehouse space Other nonresidential buildings Additions and alterations a) Employment created Employment opportunities are an important aspect to take into account when determining the influence of any aspect of the economy on the economy as a whole in order to assess the level to which the economic wealth is distributed to all people in the economy and the level of possible prosperity within the country. It is estimated that nonresidential real estate created 212,270 jobs in total, which could be divided into 169,311 formal jobs and 42,960 informal ones as displayed in Figure 22.

676 SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 Within the total numbers, the distribution of jobs between the different types of property nationally is estimated as per Table 2. Figure 22 Employment created Nonresidential Informal 42 960 Semi & unskilled 38 341 Skilled 98 520 Highly skilled 32 449 Formal employment 169 311 Formal and Informal 212 270 50 000 100 000 150 000 200 000 250 000 Table 2 Employment created Total nonresidential employment per property type Office & banking Shopping Industrial & warehouse Other nonresidential Additions & alterations Formal & informal 65,724 61,028 68,000 17,518 63,194 Formal employment 52,423 48,677 54,238 13,973 50,405 Highly skilled 10,047 9,329 10,395 2,678 9,660 Skilled 30,504 28,324 31,561 8,131 29,330 Semi & unskilled 11,871 11,023 12,283 3,164 11,414 Informal 13,301 12,351 13,762 3,545 12,789 b) Taxes generated The estimation of taxes generated within the real estate subsector is limited to net taxes on products as well as net taxes on production and other taxes. Net taxes include all taxes paid less subsidies received and are therefore an indication of the level of taxes generated, which could be applied to other functions in the economy. However, it excludes an indication of taxes and subsidies that cause structural changes within the sector, i.e. subsidies received by households for residential property and which are funded by taxes from nonresidential real estate. This would cause the net taxes for residential property to be lower than indicated here, while net taxes for nonresidential real estate would actually be higher. It would, however, require a further, more indepth study to obtain details of this. The estimated net taxes generated by all property activity are shown in Figure 23 while the estimated taxes generated by nonresidential property are shown in Figure 24, both shown per province. Table 3 provides the national net taxes as estimated per property type.

SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 677 Figure 23 Taxes generated All property per province 9 000,00 8 000,00 7 401,65 7 949,96 7 000,00 6 000,00 5 000,00 4 000,00 4 438,91 4 767,74 2 901,03 3 115,93 3 000,00 2 000,00 1 000,00 328,83 57,80 780,24 838,04 9,90 133,69 143,60 33,70 454,92 488,62 214,91 39,11 527,98 567,10 548,31 48,15 650,02 698,17 16,38 221,07 237,44 Net taxes on products Net other taxes Total net taxes Figure 24 Taxes generated Nonresidential property per province 2 500,00 2 111,66 2 268,08 2 000,00 1 500,00 1 000,00 974,89 1 047,10 863,72 927,70 500,00 72,22 18,73 252,79 271,51 1,67 22,59 24,27 6,94 93,66 100,60 63,98 7,15 96,45 103,60 156,43 13,15 177,50 190,64 5,13 69,31 74,44 Net taxes on products Net other taxes Total net taxes

678 SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 Table3 Taxes generated Nonresidential property per property type Net taxes on products Net other taxes Total net taxes Office & banking space 106.94 1,443.64 1,550.58 Shopping space 99.30 1,340.49 1,439.79 Industrial & warehouse space 110.65 1,493.64 1,604.29 Other nonresidential buildings 28.51 384.79 413.30 Additions & alterations 102.83 1,388.07 1,490.90 5 Validation of theory In Section 2, the basic principles of the IO analysis were provided. Section 3 then gave the details of economic activity in general as well as in the real estate sector specifically, while Section 4 provided a view of the impact of the real estate sector on the economy. In order to validate this theory, it is necessary to make reference to the FDWmodel or other similar space and capitalmarket models, as well as the South African NIPA accounts. The FDWmodel is provided in Figure 25 and its applicability to the South African commercial property market is previously explained by Boshoff (2013). Figure 25 Diagrammatic FDWmodel Rent Asset valuation 2 1 Market for space Construction sector 3 4 Construction Stock adjustment Source: Adapted from Boshoff (2013) The circular flow of activities in the FDWmodel is initiated by a demand for space in Quadrant 1 in the form of rent per square meter. The value of rent as carried forward to asset valuation Quadrant 2, whereby the rent is capitalised into a market value, represented by the slope of the asset value line and the subsequent intersection of the capitalised value on the xaxis. If this intersecting point is higher than the entry level cost of construction, represented by the construction sector line s intersecting point with the xaxis in Quadrant 3, new construction will take place at a rate represented by the slope of the construction line. With new construction, stock is created which adjusts the total stock, or supply of space, in Quadrant 4. This creates a new equilibrium level of supply and demand for rental to be paid in Quadrant 1. With reference to the NIPA accounts, four accounts are differentiated, each consisting of two balancing computations as follows: Account 1: GDP and Expenditure Gross domestic product at market prices

SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 679 Expenditure on gross domestic product at market prices Account 2: National disposable income and appropriation Gross national disposable income Appropriation of disposable income Account 3: Gross capital formation and financing thereof Gross capital formation Financing of gross fixed capital formation Account 4: Transactions with the rest of the world Receipts Disbursements The FDWmodel and NIPA accounts can be integrated by considering the flow of funds through the NIPA accounts. Economic activity is captured under Account 1 on the income or production method as well as the expenditure method. On the expenditure side is included the consumption expenditure of households and general government. Consumption expenditure also includes expenditure on housing or other property, which is funded from compensation received as accounted for in the income or production method for calculating the GDP. On the other hand, the income or production method also includes the net operating surplus of business organisations, which is the profits made after accounting for operational expenses, such as rental of business premises, usually in the form of real property. This consumption of space as accounted for in Account 1 of the NIPA accounts, is thus reflected in Quadrant 1 of the FDW model as the demand for space i.e. rent paid. Included in the calculation of GDP is compensation of employees, which is carried over to Account 2, ultimately leading to the calculation of gross national disposable income and the appropriation thereof. All income that is not consumed by households or general government is saved, and carried over as gross savings to the financing of gross fixed capital formation in Account 3. Gross saving includes personal savings, corporate saving, saving of general government and the consumption of fixed capital. These savings, together with net capital movements from the rest of the world and changes in gold and foreign reserves, account for the financing of gross capital formation. The availability of funds in this regard would affect interest rates and other returns on investment, which ultimately affects the rate at which rent is capitalised in Quadrant 2 of the FDW model. Depending on the cost of construction, as indicated in Quadrant 3 of the FDW model and the interaction between demand and supply of space as per Account 1 of NIPA and Quadrants 1 and 4 of the FDW, new stock will be added in the form of construction, which forms part of gross fixed capital formation in Accounts 3 and 1 of NIPA. From the above, it is evident that general economic activity creates demand for space and subsequently also the expansion thereof by way of construction or fixed capital formation. It is, however, also the case that these properties that form part of the gross fixed capital stock within the economy, need to be managed, financed, developed, etc., which is usually done by professional service companies within the financial and real estate sector. The income earned in this way is also included in total income that makes up the calculation of GDP or Gross National Disposable Income and used as consumption expenditure or savings. The property activity is thus based on demand for property due to other economic activity, but at the same time it also generates income that is spent in the economy, forming part of total economic activity. This latter income earned from direct property activity creates further economic activity, indicated previously as indirect impact on the economy, and also stimulates further entrance into the economy, indicated as induced impact. Of importance is the twoway interaction between property and the economy: firstly, through the services provided by property to the economy; but also through new economic activity that is created within the property sector itself. This principle forms the basis for this research and the calculation of the impact of commercial real estate on the total economy by considering the economic activity that is generated within the

680 SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 real estate sector and how this is then generating further economic activity due to indirect and induced impact. To validate this, a twoway causality test is performed on the gross fixed capital formation and gross value added at basic prices, both within the finance, insurance, real estate and business services sectors, using timeseries data from 1994 to 2014 at current as well as at constant 2010 prices. The data is transformed by taking the first difference in order to avoid coincidental correlation. The three years between 2009 and 2011, however, were removed due to an outlier effect caused by the global financial crises and further research would be required in order to explain data movement in this period of time. The results indicated for current prices that a one year lag is evident based on stronger correlation with a lag applied, but interestingly, is evident in both ways, i.e. there is evidence of two way causality between economic activity and property activity, but both ways of causality have a oneyear lag. The correlation for gross value added leading and gross fixed capital formation lagging by one year is stronger (0.745) than when the lead and lag relationship is reversed (0.650). Both ways, however, indicate a stronger correlation than for a correlation without any lag (0.570). With gross fixedcapital formation leading and gross valueadded lagging, the correlation reduces for lags longer than one year, but remains stronger than without any lag for up to a four year lag. With the relationship reversed and gross value added leading and gross capital formation lagging, the correlation reduces to a lower level than the nolag correlation immediately after year one. For the constant 2010 prices, results indicated a stronger correlation (0.656) when a one year lag is applied to gross valueadded behind gross fixed capital formation than the correlation of the two variables with no lag (0.430). The correlation remains stronger (0.516) with a twoyear lag, but falls significantly for longer lags. With the reversed leadlag relationship, the correlations are lower than nolag for any lag applied. To summarise the above, current prices indicate that there is a oneyear lag of gross fixedcapital formation behind gross value added in the financial intermediation, insurance, real estate and business services sectors. There is, however, also evidence of a oneyear lag in the opposite direction, although not to the same level of confidence. It is furthermore also indicated that this reversed lag is evident when constant 2010 prices are applied. This indicates strong evidence of twoway causality between capital formation and value added, a relationship which is obscured in the latter when current prices are investigated, which might be due to the sensitivity of the two variables to economic changes as well as their magnitude. In the case of gross value added, the total volume has varied between three and six times that of gross capital formation. The fact that positive twoway causality is evident indicates that capital formation in the property sector has an influence on other economic activity in the sector which is up to six times more than the capital formation itself. This confirms the interaction between the space and capital markets as discussed, as well as the variables explained in the NIPA accounts. With these relationships confirmed, it is possible to perform shortterm future forecasting by considering the number of building plans approved, the expected buildings to be completed based on that and the impact that such capital formation would then have on the wider economy. This will be performed in Section 6. 6 Shortterm future forecasting In order to do some shortterm forecasting, a view is taken on the average percentage of plans that are approved, are actually completed, as well as the lag between plan approval and completion. This provides the opportunity to forecast the total value of building activity, which would add stock to the real estate sector and provide a view of the expansion of the sector and the associated addition to economic activity, contribution to GDP, jobs created and taxes generated. These figures do, however, become fairly erratic and thus attempts have not been made to do the forecasting per property type in each province, but only for each property type nationally and each province across all property types.

SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 681 As indicated in Figure 26, it is estimated that the nonresidential real estate sector will contribute an additional approximately R2,750 million in direct economic activity in South Africa during 2014 over and above the activity that is already taking place. In addition to this, the direct impact will also cause indirect and induced impacts, causing these to increase economic activity created by the sector to R5,093 million and R7,809 million respectively. In line with this, the contribution to GDP will be R2,161 million through direct activity, R2,367 million through indirect activity and R3,670 million by induced activity. This will also result in a total of 13,065 new jobs being created, which are made up by 10,421 formal jobs and 2,644 informal jobs being created as per Figure 27. The sector will also contribute an additionally estimated R20,800,000 in net taxes, made up of R1,400,000 net taxes on products and R19,300,000 net taxes on production as displayed in Figure 28. 9 000 8 000 Figure 26 Nonresidential real estate economic activity and GDP growth 7 000 6 000 5 000 4 000 3 000 2 000 1 000 2 750 2 161 5 093 2 367 7 809 3 670 Direct Indirect Induced Output GDP Figure 27 Nonresidential real estate new jobs to be created 14 000 12 000 10 000 8 000 13 065 10 421 6 000 4 000 6 064 2 000 1 997 2 360 2 644 Formal and Informal Formal employment Highly skilled Skilled Semi & unskilled Informal

682 SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 Figure 28 Nonresidential real estate net taxes to be generated 25,0 20,0 19,3 20,8 15,0 10,0 5,0 1,4 Net taxes on products Net other taxes Total net taxes a) Influence on economic activity The total growth in economic activity to be generated by the real estate sector as estimated per province is indicated in Figure 29. For the nonresidential real estate sector, this is then shown nationally per property type in Figure 30 and for all nonresidential property per province in Figure 31. It is clear that Gauteng dominates the expected economic growth in all real estate, while KwaZuluNatal is estimated to contribute the second highest level of growth in economic activity, followed by the Western Cape. In terms of nonresidential real estate, KwaZuluNatal is expected to fall slightly behind the Western Cape, indicating that the expected activity in KwaZuluNatal is expected to be focussed more on the residential side, while the Western Cape s figure for nonresidential real estate is higher than total real estate growth expected, suggesting a decline in residential real estate activity in that province. The Free State has the opposite, with a negative growth in the nonresidential real estate sector, while the total is positive, indicating a possible larger expansion in the residential real estate sector. In terms of property types, it can be seen in Figure 30 that growth is largely dominated by shopping centre development, followed by industrial and warehouse properties, then office and banking properties. Figure 29 All real estate economic activity growth 9 000 8 000 7 000 6 000 5 000 4 000 3 000 2 000 1 000 267 495 759 770 1 427 2 188 179 331 507 105 194 297 1 173 2 172 3 330 531 983 1 507 2 996 5 547 8 505 289 535 820 40 74 114 Direct Indirect Induced

SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 683 Figure 30 Nonresidential real estate economic activity growth per property type 12 000 10 000 9 823 8 000 6 407 6 000 4 000 3 461 2 000 284 400 64 42 525 740 118 77 805 1 135 181 119 Direct Indirect Induced Office and banking space Shopping space Industrial and warehouse space Other nonresidential buildings Additions and alterations Figure 31 Nonresidential real estate economic activity growth per province 4 500 4 143 4 000 3 500 3 000 2 500 2 000 1 500 1 000 500 229 423 649 1 011 1 872 2 871 67 125 191 828 1 534 2 352 53 99 152 1 459 2 702 123 229 351 26 48 73 500 1 000 120 223 342 Direct Indirect Induced

684 SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 b) Influence on gross domestic product The growth in GDP is directly related to the growth in economic activity, although the scale differs. The result is, however, a different contribution to the GDP of the country. In line with economic activity, the GDP growth for which the real estate sector will be responsible, as estimated per province, is indicated in Figure 32. The nonresidential sector s growth is then shown per property type nationally in Figure 33 and for all property per province in Figure 34. Figure 32 All real estate GDP growth 4 500 3 997 4 000 3 500 3 000 2 500 2 000 1 500 1 000 500 210 230 357 605 663 1 028 140 154 239 82 90 140 922 1 009 1 565 417 457 708 2 354 2 578 227 248 385 32 35 54 Direct Indirect Induced Figure 33 Nonresidential real estate GDP growth per property type 5 000 4 500 4 616 4 000 3 500 3 000 2 500 2 000 2 719 2 978 1 500 1 000 500 223 314 50 33 244 344 55 36 379 534 85 56 Direct Indirect Induced Office and banking space Shopping space Industrial and warehouse space Other nonresidential buildings Additions and alterations

SAJEMS NS 19 (2016) No No 4:661689 685 Figure 34 Nonresidential real estate GDP growth per province 2 500 2 000 1 500 1 000 500 180 197 305 795 870 1 350 53 58 90 651 713 1 106 42 46 71 1 147 1 256 1 947 97 106 165 20 22 34 500 95 104 161 Direct Indirect Induced c) Employment to be created The growth in economic activity and resultant GDP growth will also create new jobs within the sector, directly as well as indirectly. The total number of new jobs to be created in the nonresidential real estate sector due to planned activity is estimated to be in excess of 13,000 as shown at the beginning of this section. The total number of real estate jobs to be created is estimated as per Figure 35, shown per province. The new jobs to be created due to nonresidential real estate activity is indicated in Figure 36, as distributed per property type, while Figure 37 shows the results for the different provinces. Figure 35 All real estate new jobs to be created 16 000 14 000 12 000 14 231 11 351 10 000 8 000 6 000 4 000 2 000 1 269 1 012 194 589 229 257 3 658 2 918 1 698 559 661 740 848 677 130 394 153 172 497 396 76 231 90 101 5 570 4 443 2 585 851 1 006 1 127 2 520 2 010 385 1 170 455 510 2 175 6 605 2 570 2 880 1 371 1 093 210 636 248 277 191 152 29 89 34 39 Formal and Informal Formal employment Highly skilled Skilled Semi & unskilled Informal