Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

Similar documents
Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Welfare

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model

Monetary Policy, In ation, and the Business Cycle. Chapter 5. Monetary Policy Tradeo s: Discretion vs Commitment Jordi Galí y CREI and UPF August 2007

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

Introducing nominal rigidities.

Complete nancial markets and consumption risk sharing

Welfare-based optimal monetary policy with unemployment and sticky prices: A linear-quadratic framework

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

Central bank credibility and the persistence of in ation and in ation expectations

Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model

Monetary Policy, In ation, and the Business Cycle. Chapter 3. The Basic New Keynesian Model

Journal of Central Banking Theory and Practice, 2017, 1, pp Received: 6 August 2016; accepted: 10 October 2016

The Limits of Monetary Policy Under Imperfect Knowledge

Is Lumpy Investment really Irrelevant for the Business Cycle?

The New Keynesian Approach to Monetary Policy Analysis: Lessons and New Directions

Monetary Policy, In ation, and the Business Cycle. Chapter 3 The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí CREI and UPF August 2007

Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

ECON Micro Foundations

Models of Wage-setting.. January 15, 2010

13. CHAPTER: Aggregate Supply

13. CHAPTER: Aggregate Supply

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 19/ Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

Determinacy, Stock Market Dynamics and Monetary Policy Inertia Pfajfar, Damjan; Santoro, Emiliano

Nominal Rigidities and Asset Pricing in New Keynesian Monetary Models

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

Monetary Economics. Lecture 11: monetary/fiscal interactions in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

In ation Premium and Oil Price Uncertainty

Introducing money. Olivier Blanchard. April Spring Topic 6.

Reconciling the Effects of Monetary Policy Actions on Consumption within a Heterogeneous Agent Framework

In ation Targeting: Is the NKM t for purpose?

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

INFLATION-OUTPUT GAP TRADE-OFF WITH A DOMINANT OIL SUPPLIER. Anton Nakov and Andrea Pescatori. Documentos de Trabajo N.º 0723

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #9 - Monopoly

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #7 - Competitive Markets

Monetary Economics Final Exam

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

Chasing the Gap: Speed Limits and Optimal Monetary Policy

Adaptive Learning in In nite Horizon Decision Problems

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Optimal Monetary Policy

The new Kenesian model

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

An Estimated Two-Country DSGE Model for the Euro Area and the US Economy

The Maturity Structure of Debt, Monetary Policy and Expectations Stabilization

Upward Pricing Pressure formulations with logit demand and endogenous partial acquisitions

The science of monetary policy

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

Problem Set 3. Consider a closed economy inhabited by an in ntely lived representative agent who maximizes lifetime utility given by. t ln c t.

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

The E ects of Technological Innovations On Employment: A New Explanation Chahnez BOUDAYA y

Simple e ciency-wage model

Advanced Macro and Money (WS09/10) Problem Set 4

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Inflation Persistence and Relative Contracting

In ation and Labor Market Dynamics Revisited

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Cost Channel, Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy under Zero Lower Bound

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

Monetary Policy: Rules versus discretion..

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model

1 Non-traded goods and the real exchange rate

Gali Chapter 6 Sticky wages and prices

Is There a Fiscal Free Lunch in a Liquidity Trap?

Chapters 1 & 2 - MACROECONOMICS, THE DATA

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality

Policy evaluation and uncertainty about the e ects of oil prices on economic activity

E cient Minimum Wages

Answer: Let y 2 denote rm 2 s output of food and L 2 denote rm 2 s labor input (so

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation

Fiscal Policy Multipliers in a New Keynesian Model under Positive and Zero Nominal Interest Rate. Central European University

The E ciency Comparison of Taxes under Monopolistic Competition with Heterogenous Firms and Variable Markups

Booms and Busts in Asset Prices. May 2010

Problem Set (1 p) (1) 1 (100)

Unemployment Persistence, Inflation and Monetary Policy, in a Dynamic Stochastic Model of the Natural Rate.

Keynesian Multipliers with Home Production

The Basic New Keynesian Model

EUI WORKING PAPERS EUROPEAN UNIVERSITY INSTITUTE. Optimal Monetary Policy Rules, Asset Prices and Credit Frictions. Ester Faia and Tommaso Monacelli

The Role of Physical Capital

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

Comprehensive Review Questions

Notes From Macroeconomics; Gregory Mankiw. Part 4 - BUSINESS CYCLES: THE ECONOMY IN THE SHORT RUN

Policy Evaluation and Uncertainty about the Effects of Oil Prices on Economic Activity

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

1 Multiple Choice (30 points)

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Monetary Policy and Unemployment

The Optimal Perception of Inflation Persistence is Zero

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES NEW-KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS: AN AS-AD VIEW. Pierpaolo Benigno. Working Paper

Samba: Stochastic Analytical Model with a Bayesian Approach. DSGE Model Project for Brazil s economy

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

Transcription:

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy Ozan Eksi TOBB University of Economics and Technology November 2 Abstract The standard new Keynesian model is unable to generate the in ation-output trade-o that Central Banks face in the real world, unless uctuations are driven by shocks to desired price or wage markups. In this paper, I explore whether a model with endogenous markups can generate such a trade-o in response to more conventional shocks. In this setting, the elasticity of product demand, and therefore the price markup, depends on the market share of a rm. I rst prove that the change in markup, when combined with the e ect of the shock creating this change, does not lead to the trade-o I seek. Then I investigate the optimal policy under endogenous markup setting. I show that the exible price markup is not a ected; hence it is optimal to target the exible price equilibrium. Keywords: Monetary Policy, Endogenous Markups, In ation Output Trade-o JEL classi cation: E32, E52 Address for Correspondence: TOBB University of Economics and Technology, Department of Economics, Sogutozu Street, No:43, Ankara, 656, Turkey Tel: +9 32 292 4542 Fax: +9 32 292 44 E-mail: ozaneksi@gmail.com Web page: oeksi.etu.edu.tr

Introduction When y n t represents the natural rate of output and y t represents the realization of output under sticky prices, the standard New Keynesian Phillips Curve equation t = Et f t+ g + ~y t implies that stabilization of the output gap (~y = y t yt n ) also results in stabilization of in ation, called Divine Coincidence. This means the model is unable to create the in ation output tradeo that Central Banks face. To obtain this trade-o, Galí, Gertler & Clarida (999) use a cost push shock (exogenous changes in price or wage markups) as follows t = Et f t+ g + ~y t + u t This equation shows that a shock to u t should be confronted by opposite movements in output gap and in ation 2. However, exogeneity of these shocks is not a plausible assumption. Galí and Blanchard (26) use real imperfections to show how such an assumption endogenously leads to the in- ation output trade-o following technology or preference shocks. They show that under the real wage rigidity, the di erence between natural rate of output,and rst best output (occurring when rms do not use any markup over their marginal costs) is not constant. Hence, stabilizing in ation and output gap, (y t yt n ), is no longer equal to stabilizing the welfare relevant output gap, (y t y fb t ). Therefore it is no longer desirable from welfare point of view. I use endogenous markup setting that is applied to a monetarist model by Kimball (995) to investigate such a model can endogenously create the in ation output trade-o without changing the distance between natural and rst best levels of output. A standard new Keynesian model rests on Calvo (983) price and/or wage staggering, where only some rms adjust their prices each period. These models also have the constant elasticity of demand assumption of Dixit and Stiglitz (977). This implies that while adjusting their prices, rms neglect the change in the aggregate price index induced by their own pricing decisions. In the endogenous markup setting, rms take this e ect into account, and they do not change their prices (so their markups) as much as they do under the alternative constant elasticity of demand assumption 3. In the AS-AD framework, this situation can be visualized by noticing the ability of monetary authority for keeping the in ation constant and the output equal to its natural level by counteracting upon the changes in AD and LRAS curves 2 In the AS-AD framework, an exogenous change in price or wage level corresponds to the case where SRAS shifts. In response, monetary authority, by shifting the AD curve, can stabilize either price or output in the expense of letting the other variable deviate more compared to no intervention 3 Suppose a decrease in nominal spending. Then the producers, who are able to adjust their prices, lower them and sell more with respect to rest. Kimball (995) speci cation recognizes that these rms will be confronted with lower elasticity of demand, leaving them less incentive to reduce their prices. The case is analogous to an increase in spending. As a result, prices respond less to changes in nominal spending. Following this observation, 2

In this study I investigate whether the endogenous change in markup leads to similar implications with the exogenous change in markup. I speci cally look for : whether such a model can generate in ation output trade-o 2: the optimal policy under this setting Both of which, to the author s knowledge, have not been investigated yet. I show that endogenous markup does not lead to in ation output trade-o like in the case of exogenous shocks in desired markup. The reason is the endogenous nature of such a change; to appear, it needs some other shock, and an endogenous change in markup just mitigates the e ect of this shock. For instance; following a negative supply shock; P t ( t ) yt n y t ~y t = y t yt n Flexible prices ## Sticky prices with constant markup # Sticky prices with endogenous markup This demonstration shows that in ation is lower and the output gap higher under the endogenous markup case when compared with the constant markup case. This could be de ned as a relatively countercyclical movement 4. However, with respect to the exible price case, output gap still increases along with in ation, and stabilizing one of these factors also implies stabilizing the other 5. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 formalizes endogenous markup setting. Section 3 explains the baseline model that I accommodate both the endogenous and exogenous changes in markup, and makes the comparison of their results. Section 4 analyses welfare implications and optimal policy under endogenous markup setting. 2 The Analytics of the Endogenous Markup Setup Following Kimball (995), to create an endogenous markup consumption aggregate C t is de ned as Z ( c t(i) C t )di = where () = and (x) is a strictly increasing and concave function for all x t (i) = c t(i) : When is constant and does not depend on the value of x (the assumption of constant C t Kimball and several other researchers use this setting to increase price stickiness and obtain real rigidity in their models 4 This occurs as the short run AS curve is less steep now. Therefore we have a smaller change in in ation but a larger change in output 5 The result continues to hold if a demand shock is used instead of a supply shock. 3

elasticity), (x) = x = and it implies Dixit and Stiglitz type consumption aggregator 2 C t = 4 Z c t (i) = di 3 5 = The consumer problem is de ned as (using c = y) Z min p t (i)y t (i)di s:t: = Z ( y t(i) )di This leads to the implicit demand curve (derivations are in appendix A) with elasticity ( y t(i) ) = () p t(i) () P t (x(i)) = ((i)) x(i) (x(i)) As it can be seen this elasticity depends on the market share of a rm, x(i). The markup (at least for the exible price supplies) is de ned by the Lerner formula (2) (x) = (x(i)) ((i)) (3) with elasticity (x(i)) Following Kimball(995) and Woodford (23), for an elasticity of markup with respect to market share of the rm, x(i), I will only use its value at x = and denote it by 3 Model The baseline model that I accommodate both the endogenous and exogenous changes in markup follows Galí & Blanchard (26). Firms use the production function Y = M N (in logs: y = m + ( )n) (4) where N is labor input and M is other non-produced input that allows for supply (technology) shocks within the model. Each good is non-storable and is sold to identical households, who consume it in the same period. Hence, consumption of each good must be equal to output. The marginal product of labor is MP N = ( )Y=N (in logs: mpn = (y n) + log( )) 4

The utility of consumers is U(C; N) = log(c) exp fg N + + where is preference parameter. This function implies marginal rate of substitution MRS = U n U c = exp fg N =C (in logs: mrs = c + n + ) I start with the equilibrium under the exible prices while maintaining the assumption of imperfect competition in the goods market. Setting c = y and using the equality = mpn mrs(= w) for markup 6, we obtain = ( + )n 2 : + log( ) where 2 denotes second best (natural) level of the variable found by exible prices. If we combine the last equation with (4), it nds = ( + ) y 2 m ( ) which gives the second best level of output y 2 = m + + log( ) (5) ( ) (log( ) )) ( + ) Now I turn to equilibrium with sticky prices. For the rms having sticky prices, deviation in real marginal cost is re ected with a minus sign in their markups (mc t = to the equation (5) mc t = ( + ) y t m ( ) t ). Hence parallel log( ) + (6) I use (5) & (6); together with (3); to derive NKPC (details are in appendix B.) t = Et f t+ g + + + (mc t + ) (7) where or in terms of outputs = ( )( ) t = Et f t+ g + ( )( ) ( + ) ( + + ) ( ) (y t y t;2 ) (8) 6 Markup is constant under exible prices because rms are symmetric, which results in rms to move their prices proportionally. This implies that there will be no extra demand for any of their products 5

7 Both equations (7) and (8) show that we end up with no trade-o ; stabilization of the output gap is still equal to stabilization of in ation. Using an endogenous markup has just caused an increase in real rigidity as is used in the literature. Instead of being endogenous, if the change in markup results from any direct exogenous e ect (as it is used in the literature), then the NKPC equation could be written as (in appendix B.2) or t = Et f t+ g + ( + ) (mc t + ) + ( + ) ( t ) (9) t = Et f t+ g + ( + ) (mc t + t ) () implying that not only deviation from exible price equilibrium, but also a change in the existing markup plays a distinct role. Equation (9) explicitly shows that the shock to t should be either confronted with an increase in t, or a decrease in mc t, which means a decrease in y t 4 Optimal Policy We used equation (5) to derive the second best level of output under endogenous markup setting. y 2 = m + ( ) (log( ) )) ( + ) E cient ( rst best) allocation can be found by setting = hence y = m + y y 2 = ( ) (log( ) ) ( + ) ( ) ( + ) = (2) So the distance between rst and second best outputs is constant under the endogenous markup setting with exible prices, like the constant markup setup of Galí & Blanchard (26). Thus, utility losses associated with deviations from e cient allocation, y, should remain parallel to deviation from the exible price allocation, y 2. This implies that the optimality of the monetary rules derived for the equation (see Galí (28)) t = Et f t+ g + (y t y t;2 ) 7 If (x) is not approximated by the solution implies t = Et f t+g + (x)= + (mct + ) + 6

should be still valid. The only di erence is that now = ( )( ) ( + ) ( + + ) ( ) instead of the one implied by constant elasticity of demand assumption = ( )( ) ( + ) ( ) Thus optimal policy should still target exible price output and zero in ation. Evaluating monetary policies under the endogenous markup setting should be equivalent to doing the same under any e ect increasing price stickiness and creating real rigidity, but I abstract myself from doing so and do not go any further. However, it seems the appropriateness of any monetary policy now should bene t from less variance in in ation, but should su er more from the variance in the output gap. 5 Conclusion My motivation for using an endogenous markup was to create an output gap in ation trade-o with a more realistic model than the one with an exogenous shock. The purpose of using an endogenous markup in the literature is to create price stickiness, and its trade-o implications seemed at rst as a missing element not yet investigated. To this end I applied both endogenous and exogenous changes in markup settings in a single macro model. However, my result suggests that endogenous markup is unable to create the desired trade-o like an exogenous shock does. I also show that with the endogenous change in markup exible price markup is una ected. Hence, the model does not create welfare losses for the exible price equilibrium, and targeting this equilibrium is still the optimal policy as it is equivalent to stabilizing the welfare relevant output gap. Acknowledgements I wrote the rst draft of this paper at Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona when I was a Ph.D. student. From that institution I would like to thank to Prof. Jordi Galí for his suggestions and my previous colleagues for their useful comments. From TOBB University of Economics and Technology, I would like to thank to Prof. Unay Tamgac for reviewing this paper. 7

APPENDIX A-Derivation of Demand Side Equations Z min p t (i)y t (i)di s:t: = Z ( y t(i) )di taking derivative with respect to y t (i) nds p t (i) = ( y t(i) ) where is the Lagrange Multiplier. By calculating this equation at p t (i) = P t and y t (i) =, we nd = P t () hence the inverse demand equation for good i is de ned as Rearranging the elasticity of demand p t (i) = P t ( y t(i) ) () () (x t (i)) = @y t(i)=y t (i) @p t (i)=p t (i) = p t(i) y t (i) @p t (i)=@y t (i) and inserting p t (i) and @p t (i)=@y t (i) into it (x t (i)) = y t (i) P t ( y t(i) ) () P t ( y t(i) ) () = y t (i)= ( y t(i) ) ( y t(i) ) = x t (i) (x t (i)) (x t (i)) (2) Finally, log linearizing around the steady state at x t (i) = we have the familiar demand equation for monopolistically competitive markets ln( y t(i) ) = ln( p t(i) P t ) where = () or y t (i) = ( p t(i) ) P t 8

B-Firms Pro t Maximization Problem Maximization problem of rms is (parallel to the baseline model of Galí (28)) max P t k E t Qt;t+k (Pt +k=t t+k(+k=t )) where ( ) is the probability that the rm may reset its price (Calvo (983)), Q t;t+k = k (U (C t+k )=U (C t ))(P t =P t+k ) is the stochastic discount factor, is the nominal cost function, +k=t denotes output in period t + k for a rm that last reset its price in period t, and p is the optimal price set by a rm at time t: The problem is is subject to demand constraints After taking derivative, I nd +k=t = ( P t P t+k ) +k k E t Qt;t+k +k=t (Pt (x t (i)) t+k (+k=t)) = The derivative of the nominal cost function by, t+k (+k=t ), divided by P t+k gives the real cost of marginal production. Hence, this equation, after dividing both hand side of the equality by P t, can be written as k E t Q t;t+k +k=t ( P t P t+k (x t (i))mc P t+k=t = t P t using Q t;t+k = k and +k=t = Y at steady state, and applying log linearization gives p t p t = ( ) () k E t ^(xt+k (i)) + m^c t+k=t + (p t+k p t ) () B.: If deviation in markup is endogenous The elasticity of markup with respect to the market share of the rm can be written as ^(x t+k (i)) = (y t+k (i) y t+k ) = (p p t+k ) (4) The real marginal cost can be written as mc t (i) = (! t p t ) mpn t (i) = (! t p t ) [y t (i) n t (i) + log( )] 9

If we take n t from equation (4), the previous equation becomes mc t (i) = (! t p t ) + (y t (i) m t ) log( ) and mc t+k=t (i) = (! t+k p t+k ) + (y t+k=t (i) m t+k ) log( ) (! t+k p t+k does not depend on the decision of rm i at time t as it depends on economy wide labor market). Hence mc t+k=t = mc t+k + (y t+k=t y t+k ) = mc t+k (p p t+k ) (5) Inserting equations (4) and (5) into equation () and rearranging the equation nds p t p t = ( ) () k E t m^ct+k ( + )(p p t+k ) + (p t+k p t ) by adding ()( + )p t to RHS of the equation, it becomes p t p t = ( ) () k E t m^ct+k ( + )(p p t ) + ( + + )(p t+k p t ) now collecting the all p t p t terms at the LHS and then divide the equation by (+ + ), similarly, E t (p t+ p t p t = ( ) () k E t ( + + ) m^c t+k + (p t+k p t ) p t ) can be written as E t (p t+ p t ) = ( ) () l E t ( + + ) m^c t++l + (p t++l p t ) combining the last two equations l= p t p t = ( ) ( + + ) m^c t + E t (p t+ p t ) + ( )(p t p t ) using t = ( )(p t p t ) (saying that in ation is determined by the number of rms able to set their prices to the optimal level), the last equation becomes t = Et f t+ g + ( )( ) ( + + ) m^c t (7)

inserting equation (6) and its exible price equivalent into equation (7) nds that t = Et f t+ g + ( )( ) ( + ) ( + + ) ( ) (y t y t;2 ) (8) B.2: If deviation in markup is exogenous Equation () combined with equation (5) gives p t p t = ( ) () k E t ^t+k + m^c t+k (p p t+k ) + (p t+k p t ) adding ()()p t to RHS of the equation, it becomes p t p t = ( ) () k E t ^t+k + m^c t+k ()(p p t ) + ( + )(p t+k p t ) collecting all the p t p t terms at the LHS and dividing the equation by ( + ), I get p t p t = ( ) () k E t ( + ) ^ t+k + ( + ) m^c t+k + (p t+k p t ) similarly, E t (p t+ p t ) can be written as E t (p t+ p t ) = ( ) () l E t ( + ) ^ t++l + ( + ) m^c t++l + (p t++l p t ) l= Combining the last two equations p t p t = ( ) ( + ) ^ t + ( ) ( + ) m^c t + E t (p t+ p t ) + ( )(p t p t ) nally using t = ( )(p t p t ); I obtain t = Et f t+ g + ( )( ) ( + ) m^c t + ( )( ) ( + ) ^ t (9) References Blanchard, O. J., Galí, J., 25. Real Wage Rigidities and the New Keynesian Model, MIT Department of Economics. Working Paper No:5-28. Bullard, J., Mitra, K., 22. Learning about monetary policy rules. Journal of Monetary Economics 49, 5-29.

Calvo, G., 983. Staggered prices in a utility maximizing framework. Journal of Monetary Economics 2, 383 398. Clarida, R., Galí, J., Gertler, M., 999. The science of monetary policy: A New Keynesian perspective. Journal of Economic Literature 37, 66-77. Dixit, A. K., Stiglitz, J. E., 977. Monopolistic Competition and Optimal Product Diversity. American Economic Review 67, 297-38. Galí, J., Gertler, M., 999. In ation Dynamics: A Structural Econometric Analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics 44, 95 222. Galí, J., 28. Monetary Policy, In ation and the Business Cycle: An Introduction to the New Keynesian Framework, Monograph, Princeton University Press. Kimball, M. S., 995. The Quantitative Analytics of the Basic Neomonetarist Model. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 27, 24-277 Woodford, M., 23. Interest and Prices:Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy, Princeton University Press. Yang, X., Heijdra, B. J. 993. Imperfect Competition and Product Di erentiation: Some Further Results. Mathematical Social Sciences 25, 57-7. 2