Optimal Capital Structure, Endogenous Bankruptcy, and the Term Structure of Credit Spreads

Similar documents
Analyzing Convertible Bonds: Valuation, Optimal. Strategies and Asset Substitution

Pricing Convertible Bonds under the First-Passage Credit Risk Model

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

13.3 A Stochastic Production Planning Model

LECTURES ON REAL OPTIONS: PART III SOME APPLICATIONS AND EXTENSIONS

Growth Options and Optimal Default under Liquidity Constraints: The Role of Corporate Cash Balances

Introduction Credit risk

Corporate Bond Valuation and Hedging with Stochastic Interest Rates and Endogenous Bankruptcy

DYNAMIC DEBT MATURITY

Modelling Credit Spread Behaviour. FIRST Credit, Insurance and Risk. Angelo Arvanitis, Jon Gregory, Jean-Paul Laurent

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

Structural Models IV

The Use of Equity Financing in Debt Renegotiation

Valuation of a New Class of Commodity-Linked Bonds with Partial Indexation Adjustments

How Effectively Can Debt Covenants Alleviate Financial Agency Problems?

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

CMBS Default: A First Passage Time Approach

Multi-period mean variance asset allocation: Is it bad to win the lottery?

Brownian Motion and Ito s Lemma

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 3 : The Ramsey Growth Model

Credit Risk Modelling: A Primer. By: A V Vedpuriswar

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Numerical Evaluation of Multivariate Contingent Claims

Online Appendix to Financing Asset Sales and Business Cycles

Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications

Lecture 3 Growth Model with Endogenous Savings: Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Optimal default boundary in discrete time models

Short-Term Debt and Incentives for Risk-Taking

Amenity Potential, Private Benefits of Control, and the Value of Levered Family Firms. Worawat Margsiri (Fordham University)

Lifetime Portfolio Selection: A Simple Derivation

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Dynamic Principal Agent Models: A Continuous Time Approach Lecture II

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Credit Risk : Firm Value Model

Fixed-Income Options

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Do Bond Covenants Prevent Asset Substitution?

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.pr] 23 Nov 2017

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Quantifying credit risk in a corporate bond

Intertemporally Dependent Preferences and the Volatility of Consumption and Wealth

Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation

CoCos, Bail-In, and Tail Risk

Strategic Investment with Debt Financing

How Costly is External Financing? Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Christopher Hennessy and Toni Whited March 2006

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

The Black-Scholes Model

Credit Risk in Banking

Lecture 5A: Leland-type Models

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Option Approach to Risk-shifting Incentive Problem with Mutually Correlated Projects

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

The Black-Scholes Model

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs. Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Bandit Problems with Lévy Payoff Processes

Growth Options, Incentives, and Pay-for-Performance: Theory and Evidence

2.4 Industrial implementation: KMV model. Expected default frequency

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

Lattice (Binomial Trees) Version 1.2

Financial Derivatives Section 5

Robust Portfolio Decisions for Financial Institutions

Optimal Credit Limit Management

Rollover Risk and Credit Risk. Finance Seminar, Temple University March 4, 2011

The Forward PDE for American Puts in the Dupire Model

Investment strategies and risk management for participating life insurance contracts

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Characterization of the Optimum

Path Dependent British Options

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

Credit Risk. June 2014

Introduction Model Results Conclusion Discussion. The Value Premium. Zhang, JF 2005 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern.

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

OPTIMAL TIMING FOR INVESTMENT DECISIONS

CB Asset Swaps and CB Options: Structure and Pricing

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives

A Simple Approach to CAPM and Option Pricing. Riccardo Cesari and Carlo D Adda (University of Bologna)

Disagreement, Speculation, and Aggregate Investment

An Equilibrium Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Term Structure of Credit Spreads of A Firm When Its Underlying Assets are Discontinuous

Employee Reload Options: Pricing, Hedging, and Optimal Exercise

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

A new Loan Stock Financial Instrument

Smooth pasting as rate of return equalisation: A note

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE

Lecture 7: Bayesian approach to MAB - Gittins index

Internet Appendix to Idiosyncratic Cash Flows and Systematic Risk

Transcription:

Optimal Capital Structure, Endogenous Bankruptcy, and the Term Structure of Credit Spreads The Journal of Finance Hayne E. Leland and Klaus Bjerre Toft Reporter: Chuan-Ju Wang December 5, 2008 1 / 56

Outline 1 Introduction 2 Model 3 Application 4 Agency Effects 5 Conclusion 6 Dynamic Capital Structure 2 / 56

Introduction This article extends Leland s results (1994) to examine effect of debt maturity on bond prices, credit spreads, the optimal amount of debt. 3 / 56

Introduction Kim, Ramaswamy, and Sundaresan (1993), Longstaff and Schwartz (1995) and Nielsen, Saa-Requejo, and Santa-Clara (1993) have examined the pricing of bonds with credit risk and arbitrary maturity. Examining debt values only, do not consider optimal capital structure. Assuming either that bankruptcy is triggered at an exogenously specified asset value or that is is triggered when cash flow fails to cover interest payments. Allowing default-free interest rates to follow a stochastic process. 4 / 56

Leland (1994) This article derives closed-form results for the value of long-term risky debt (console bond) and yield spreads, for optimal capital structure. The unleveraged value V follows a diffusion process with constant volatility σ: dv = [µ(v, t)) δ] dt + σdz, (1) V where µ(v, t) is the total expected rate of return on asset value V ; δ is the constant fraction of value paid out to security holders; and dz is the increment of a standard Brownian motion. Note that δ = 0 in Leland (1994) paper. 5 / 56

Leland (1994) (cont.) Any claim on the firm (F (V, t)) that continuously pays a nonnegative coupon, C, per instant of time when the firm is solvent. It must satisfy the partial differential equation: (1/2)σ 2 V 2 F VV (V, t) + (r δ)vf V (V, t) rf (V, t) + F t (V, t) + C = 0. (2) When security have no explicit time dependence, the term F t (V, t) = 0, Eq. (2) has the general solution where X = 1 (r σ 2 δ σ2 2 F (V ) = A 0 + A 1 V + A 2 V X, (3) ) + Note that X = 2r/σ 2 as δ = 0. ( ) 2 r δ σ2 + 2rσ 2 2. (4) 6 / 56

Leland (1994) (cont.) Boundary conditions for the debt is AtV = V B, D(V ) = (1 α)v B (5) AsV, D(V ) C/r, (6) where a fraction 0 α 1 of value will be lost to bankruptcy cost. We can use the above conditions to obtain the debt value by finding A 0, A 1, and A 2 : D(V ) = C/r + [(1 α)v B C/r] [V /V B ] X. (7) 7 / 56

Leland (1994) (cont.) Boundary conditions for the bankruptcy cost is AtV = V B, BC(V ) = αv B (8) AsV, BC(V ) 0. (9) We can use the above conditions to obtain the bankruptcy cost by finding A 0, A 1, and A 2 : BC(V ) = αv B (V /V B ) X. (10) 8 / 56

Leland (1994) (cont.) Boundary conditions for the tax benefit is where τ denotes the tax rate. AtV = V B, TB(V ) = 0 (11) AsV, TB(V ) τc/r, (12) We can use the above conditions to obtain the tax benefit by finding A 0, A 1, and A 2 : TB(V ) = τc/r (τc/r)(v /V B ) X. (13) 9 / 56

Leland (1994) (cont.) The total value of the firm v(v ) is v(v ) = V + TB(V ) BC(V ) = V + (τc/r) [ 1 (V /V B ) X ] αv B (V /V B ) X. (14) where τ denotes the tax rate. The equity value is given by E(V ) = v(v ) D(V ) = V (1 τ)c/r + [(1 τ)c/r V B ] [V /V B ] X. (15) 10 / 56

Finite Maturity Debt Consider a bond issue with maturity t periods from the present, which continuously pays a constant coupon flow c(t) and has principal p(t). Let ρ(t) be the fraction of asset value V B which debt of maturity t receives in the event of bankruptcy. Using risk-neutral valuation, and letting f (s; V, V B ) denote the density of the first passage time s to V B from V when the drift rate is (r δ), gives debt with maturity t the value d(v ; V B, t) = t 0 e rs c(t) [1 F (s; V, V B )] ds + e rt p(t) [1 F (t; V, V B )] + t 0 e rs ρ(t)v B f (s; V, V B )ds. (16) 11 / 56

Finite Maturity Debt (cont.) Integrating the first term by parts yields where d(v ; V B, t) = c(t) r [ + e rt p(t) c(t) r [ + ρ(t)v B c(t) r G(t) = t 0 ] [1 F (t)] (17) ] G(t) (18) e rs f (s; V, V B )ds. (19) We can find expressions for F (t) from Harrison (1990) and for G(t) from Rubinstein and Reiner (1991). 12 / 56

Finite Maturity Debt (cont.) Note that as t, d(v ; V B, t) c( ) r [ ( ) ] X ( ) X V V 1 + ρ( )V B (20) V B which is the same equation as Leland (1994) derived for infinite-horizon risky debt when ρ( ) = (1 α). V B 13 / 56

Finite Maturity Debt (cont.) As in Longstaff and Schwartz (1995), the analysis above has assumed that V B is an exogenous constant. For arbitrary capital structures, however, this is unlikely to be optimal. If the firm has only a single issue of debt outstanding, debt service requirements are time-dependent. Prior to maturity, asset value may be low (less than P) but still sufficient to justify paying the coupon to avoid default. A debt structure consistent with a constant endogenous-determined bankruptcy level V B. This capital structure has time-independent debt service payments. 14 / 56

A Stationary Debt Structure The firm continuously sells a constant (principal) amount of new debt with maturity of T years. New bond principal is issued at a rate p = (P/T ) per year, where P is the total principal value of all outstanding bonds. As long as the firm remains solvent, at any time s, the total outstanding debt principal will be P, and have a uniform distribution of principal over maturities in the interval (s, s + T ). Bonds with principal p pay a constant coupon rate c = (C/T ) per year, where C is the total coupon paid by all outstanding bonds per year. 15 / 56

A Stationary Debt Structure (cont.) Assume that ρ(t) = (1 α)/t. Let D(V ; V B, T ) denote the total value of debt, when debt of maturity T is issued. T D(V ; V B, T ) = d(v ; V B, t)dt 0 = C ( r + P C ) ( 1 e rt r rt ( + (1 α)v B C r ) I (t)) ) J(t), (21) where I (T ) = 1 T J(T ) = 1 T T 0 T 0 e rt F (t)dt G(t)dt. 16 / 56

A Stationary Debt Structure (cont.) Following Leland (1994) (Eq. (14)), total firm value will be [ v(v ; V B ) = V + τc ( ) ] X ( ) X V V 1 αv B, (22) r V B V B where we recall in this paper the payout rate δ is not zero. The value of equity is given by E(V ; V B, T ) = v(v ; V B ) D(V ; V B, T ). (23) 17 / 56

Determining the Bankruptcy-Triggering Asset Level V B To determine the bankruptcy-triggering asset value V B endogenously, we solve the equation E(V ; V B, T ) V = 0. (24) V =VB The solution for V B is V B = (C/r)((A/(rT ) B) AP/(rT ) τcx /r. (25) 1 + αx (1 α)b Observe that V B will depend upon the maturity of debt chosen, for any given P and C. 18 / 56

Introduction Model Application Agency Effects Conclusion Dynamic Capital Structure Determining the Bankruptcy-Triggering Asset Level V B (cont.) 9878 81 83 850 07 01 03 01020304050678 The smooth-pasting condition has the property of maximizing (with respect V B ) both the value of equity and the value of the firm, subject to E(V ) 0 for all V V B. It also implies E(V B ) VV 0. 19 / 56

Determining the Bankruptcy-Triggering Asset Level V B (cont.) The bankruptcy condition can be further analyzed by computing the expected appreciation of equity around the endogenous bankruptcy trigger. Since E V = 0 when V = V B, the appreciation of equation simplifies to de V =V = 1 V B 2 σ2 V 2 E VV dt 0. (26) =VB 20 / 56

Determining the Bankruptcy-Triggering Asset Level V B (cont.) Evaluating and further simplifying yields de V =VB = ((1 τ)c + p)dt (d(v B ; V B, T ) + δv B )dt, (27) where d(v B ; V B, T ) = (1 α)v B /T. The l.h.s of Eq. (27) is the change in the equity value at V = V B ; the r.h.s is the additional cash flow required from equity holders for current debt service. The cost of debt service (the after-tax coupon expense plus the principal expense less the sum of the revenues from selling an equal principal amount of debt at their market price). The cash flow available for payout generated by the firm s activities. 21 / 56

Determining the Bankruptcy-Triggering Asset Level V B (cont.) For long term debt, V B < P. However, as T 0, V B P/(1 α), which exceeds P when α > 0. When debt is short term and α > 0, bankruptcy will occur despite net worth being positive. Because the anticipated equity appreciation does not warrant the additional contribution required from equity holder to avoid default on bond service payment. 22 / 56

Determining the Bankruptcy-Triggering Asset Level V B (cont.) The tax deductibility is lost whenever V falls below some value V T, where V T > V B. V B = (C/r)(A/(rT ) B) AP/(rT ) 1 + X (τc/(rv T ) + α) (1 α)b, (28) where V B in Eq. (28) will exceed V B in Eq. (25). This lowers the value of debt and firm. 23 / 56

Numerical Settings The base case: r = 0.075, τ = 0.35, α = 0.5, and σ = 0.2. Assume that the firm pays out an amount to security holders equal to δv, with δ = 0.07. Presume that the tax deductibility of debt is lost when all available cash flow is needed to pay interest to bond holders. At V = V T such that δv T = C. When V B < V < V T, current equity holders willingly contribute to the firm to avoid default (e.g., equity dilution). At the initial asset value (V=100), we assume the coupon (c) is set so that newly-issued debt sells at par value (d = p). 24 / 56

Optimal Leverage Figure 1: Firm value as a function of leverage. The leverage ratio which maximizes firm value is larger for debt with longer maturity. The maximize firm value is also greater. 25 / 56

Optimal Leverage (cont.) Maturity Firm Value Bankruptcy Optimal (Year) (Dollars) Trigger Leverage 0.5 104.10 27.70 19 1.0 104.85 28.80 22 2.0 106.00 30.55 26 5.0 108.25 35.75 37 10.0 110.45 36.60 43 20.0 111.95 35.30 46 Infinity 113.80 32.80 49 Table 1: Characteristic of Optimally Levered Firm Optimal Leverage Ratio Positive correlation between leverage and debt maturity (consistent with empirical evidence of Barclay and Smith (1995a)). For any maturity, the optimal leverage ratio will fall when σ and α increase and r decrease. 26 / 56

Optimal Leverage (cont.) Maturity Firm Value Bankruptcy Credit Spread, (Year) (Dollars) Trigger Total Debt (bps) 0.5 104.10 27.70 0 1.0 104.85 28.80 0 2.0 106.00 30.55 0 5.0 108.25 35.75 13 10.0 110.45 36.60 55 20.0 111.95 35.30 86 Infinity 113.80 32.80 107 Credit Spread Table 1: Characteristic of Optimally Levered Firm Credit Spreads at the optimal leverage are negligible for issuance maturities of 2 years or less. Longstaff and Schwartz (1995) report that, over the period 1977-1992 average credit spreads on Moody s Industrial bond ranged from 48 bps (Aaa) to 184 bps (Baa), with an average credit spread of 109 bps (investment-graded). 27 / 56

Optimal Leverage (cont.) Maturity Firm Value Bankruptcy Optimal (Year) (Dollars) Trigger Leverage 0.5 104.10 27.70 19 1.0 104.85 28.80 22 2.0 106.00 30.55 26 5.0 108.25 35.75 37 10.0 110.45 36.60 43 20.0 111.95 35.30 46 Infinity 113.80 32.80 49 Table 1: Characteristic of Optimally Levered Firm Write-Down for Debt Write-Down in this model is (1 (1 α)v B /P) (1 ((1 0.5) 35.3)/(111.95 0.46)) = 65.7. Altman (1991) calculates average write-down for a simple default bonds over period 1971-1991 (52.8 for rated A, 61.5 for BBB, and 69.7 for BB). 28 / 56

Optimal Leverage (cont.) Maturity Firm Value Bankruptcy Optimal Principal (Year) (Dollars) Trigger Leverage Value (P) Bankruptcy Level 0.5 104.10 27.70 19 19.8 1.0 104.85 28.80 22 23.1 2.0 106.00 30.55 26 27.6 5.0 108.25 35.75 37 40.1 10.0 110.45 36.60 43 47.5 20.0 111.95 35.30 46 51.5 Infinity 113.80 32.80 49 55.8 Table 1: Characteristic of Optimally Levered Firm For long-term debt, V B < P. For short-term debt, V B > P. 29 / 56

Optimal Leverage (cont.) Firm Value Maturity Firm Value Bankruptcy Optimal (Year) (Dollars) Trigger Leverage 0.5 104.10 27.70 19 1.0 104.85 28.80 22 2.0 106.00 30.55 26 5.0 108.25 35.75 37 10.0 110.45 36.60 43 20.0 111.95 35.30 46 Infinity 113.80 32.80 49 Table 1: Characteristic of Optimally Levered Firm Maximum firm value increases monotonically with debt maturity. Why would firms ever issue short term debt? (lower agency costs) 30 / 56

Debt Value and Debt Capacity Figure 2: Debt value as a function of leverage. The maximum debt value is smaller for shorter maturity. Maximal debt value tends to occur at approximately the same leverage (about 80-85 present). 31 / 56

Debt Value and Debt Capacity (cont.) Investment-Grade Bond and Junk Bond Debt value falls as σ or r increases when leverage is low. Debt value increases with σ and with r when leverage is (very) high and the bond is junk. As r or σ increases, the endogenous bankruptcy level V B is pushed down. 32 / 56

Debt Value and Debt Capacity (cont.) Figure 3: Bond price and yield to maturity as functions of time to maturity. Low and intermediate leverages show hump market values of bonds. Very risky debt show a different price pattern. 33 / 56

The Term Structure of Credit Spreads Figure 4: Credit spread as a function of debt maturity. For high leverage levels, spreads are high but decrease as issuance maturity T increase beyond 1 year. For moderate-to-high leverage levels, spreads are distinctly humped. For low leverage level, credit spreads are low but increase with insurance maturity T. 34 / 56

The Term Structure of Credit Spreads (cont.) Panel A: Panel B: Fixed P and C Fixed P, C, and V B T = 0.5 T = 5 T = 20 T = 0.5 T = 5 T = 20 Base case 0.00 31.27 111.10 0.00 31.27 111.10 σ = 20%, r = 7.5%, α = 50% 27.70 35.75 35.32 27.70 35.75 35.32 High volatility 0.00 86.74 178.09 0.00 103.94 196.41 σ = 25%, r = 7.5%, α = 50% 26.98 33.72 32.48 27.70 35.75 35.32 High risk-free rate 0.00 10.23 39.56 0.00 16.03 48.93 σ = 20%, r = 10%, α = 50% 26.15 33.03 32.14 27.70 35.75 35.32 Lower bankruptcy costs 0.00 11.53 77.54 0.00 18.83 81.9 σ = 20%, r = 7.5%, α = 50% 20.94 31.83 33.80 27.70 35.75 35.32 Table 2: Credit Spread and Endogenous Bankruptcy Trigger V B for Various Parameter Values. The Effect of Endogenous versus Exogenous Bankruptcy on Credit Spreads Intermediate and long term debt always pay lower credit spreads in Panel A than in Panel B (higher V B lower debt value higher cs). 35 / 56

The Term Structure of Credit Spreads (cont.) Panel A: Panel B: Fixed P and C Fixed P, C, and V B T = 0.5 T = 5 T = 20 T = 0.5 T = 5 T = 20 Base case 0.00 31.27 111.10 0.00 31.27 111.10 σ = 20%, r = 7.5%, α = 50% 27.70 35.75 35.32 27.70 35.75 35.32 High volatility 0.00 86.74 178.09 0.00 103.94 196.41 σ = 25%, r = 7.5%, α = 50% 26.98 33.72 32.48 27.70 35.75 35.32 High risk-free rate 0.00 10.23 39.56 0.00 16.03 48.93 σ = 20%, r = 10%, α = 50% 26.15 33.03 32.14 27.70 35.75 35.32 Lower bankruptcy costs 0.00 11.53 77.54 0.00 18.83 81.9 σ = 20%, r = 7.5%, α = 50% 20.94 31.83 33.80 27.70 35.75 35.32 Table 2: Credit Spread and Endogenous Bankruptcy Trigger V B for Various Parameter Values. Risk-Free Interest Rate Credit spreads fall when the default-free interest rate rises (unexpected results). 36 / 56

The Term Structure of Credit Spreads (cont.) Panel C: Optimal P, C, and V B T = 0.5 T = 5 T = 20 Base case 0.00 31.27 111.10 σ = 20%, r = 7.5%, α = 50% 27.70 35.75 35.32 High volatility 0.00 52.63 149.36 σ = 25%, r = 7.5%, α = 50% 20.47 29.88 29.32 High risk-free rate 0.00 42.45 66.22 σ = 20%, r = 10%, α = 50% 39.64 42.10 39.67 Lower bankruptcy costs 0.00 66.86 109.94 σ = 20%, r = 7.5%, α = 50% 38.27 43.92 39.63 Table 2: Credit Spread and Endogenous Bankruptcy Trigger V B for Various Parameter Values. Exogenous Parameter Change before Debt is Issued A rise in the default-free rate will increase credit spreads of shorter term debt, but decrease spreads of long term debt. 37 / 56

The Term Structure of Credit Spreads (cont.) Panel C: Optimal P, C, and V B T = 0.5 T = 5 T = 20 Base case 0.00 31.27 111.10 σ = 20%, r = 7.5%, α = 50% 27.70 35.75 35.32 High volatility 0.00 52.63 149.36 σ = 25%, r = 7.5%, α = 50% 20.47 29.88 29.32 High risk-free rate 0.00 42.45 66.22 σ = 20%, r = 10%, α = 50% 39.64 42.10 39.67 Lower bankruptcy costs 0.00 66.86 109.94 σ = 20%, r = 7.5%, α = 50% 38.27 43.92 39.63 Table 2: Credit Spread and Endogenous Bankruptcy Trigger V B for Various Parameter Values. Bankruptcy Cost For intermediate term debt, lower bankruptcy costs lead to greater leverage, thereby increase yield spreads. 38 / 56

The Duration and Convexity of Risky Debt Figure 5: Effective duration as a function of Macaulay duration. Macaulay duration Dur = 1 e RT R. (29) Effective duration: the percentage change in the value of newly issued bond with maturity T for a 1 percent change in r. 39 / 56

The Duration and Convexity of Risky Debt (cont.) Figure 6: Bond price as a function of interest rates. Riskless debt value is a convex function of the default-free interest r. As debt becomes increasingly risky, convexity is reduced and ultimately turns to concavity. 40 / 56

Bankruptcy Rates and Bond Ratings Figure 7: Cumulative bankruptcy probabilities. The cumulative probability of the firm going bankruptcy over the period (0, s] is given by where λ = µ δ 0.5σ 2. N ( ) b λs σ +e 2λ/σ2 N s ( ) b+λs σ, (30) s 41 / 56

Bankruptcy Rates and Bond Ratings (cont.) Bond Ratings Probability of default versus credit spread. Credit spread seems more important variable to predict when market prices are unavailable. 42 / 56

Agency Effects After debt is issued, equity holders will wish to increase the riskiness of the firm s activities. This is presumed to transfer value from debt to equity, create the asset substitution problem. This presumption follows from regarding equity as a call option on the firm s asset, as indeed is the case when debt has no coupon, and taxes and bankruptcy costs are ignored. Barnea, Haugen, and Senbet (1980) suggest that shorter term debt may reduce shareholder incentives to increase risk. 43 / 56

Agency Effects (cont.) Equity in this paper is not precisely analogous to an ordinary call option. Default may occur at any time. V B varies with the risk of the firm s activities. The existence of tax benefit and potential bankruptcy cost. 44 / 56

Agency Effects (cont.) Figure 8: Effects of an increase in risk σ on bond and equity values. For either short or intermediate term debt, increasing risk will not benefit both bond and equity holders, except when bankruptcy is imminent. 45 / 56

Agency Effects (cont.) Figure 8: Effects of an increase in risk σ on bond and equity values. The incentives for increasing risk are much more pronounced for longer term debt. 46 / 56

Agency Effects (cont.) Figure 8: Effects of an increase in risk σ on bond and equity values. At all maturity, the incentives for increasing risk become positive for both equity and bond holders as the bankruptcy level is approached. Incentives to increase risk become positive for equity holders before they become positive for bond holders. 47 / 56

Agency Effects (cont.) Bankruptcy Cost Firms with higher bankruptcy cost α will choose lower optimal amounts of debt. But they will lengthen the maturity of debt. This is due to the fact that longer maturity tends to reduce V B and thereby serves to postpone bankruptcy and its associated cost. 48 / 56

Agency Effects (cont.) Payout The incremental firm value using long versus short term debt is significant reduced when δ falls. However, the incremental agency costs associated with asset substitution alone are lower for firms with lower payout rates. In this paper, they cannot predict whether optimal maturity should be shorten when δ falls. 49 / 56

Agency Effects (cont.) Growth Prospects Firm with greater growth prospects typically have lower cash flows (as a fraction of asset value) available for payout to security holders, greater risk, and higher bankruptcy cost. Barclay and Smith s (1995) empirical results show that firms with greater growth prospects do use shorter term debt. 50 / 56

Agency Effects (cont.) Figure 9: Effects of an increase in risk σ on bond and equity values zero taxes and bankruptcy costs. The extent of conflict between equity holders and bond holders increase as tax rate and bankruptcy costs decline. 51 / 56

Agency Effects (cont.) In sum, these results suggest that the general asset substitution problem may have been overstated, except when debt is very long term, or when taxes and bankruptcy costs are minimal. The incompatibilities arise as bankruptcy is approached. On the very brink of bankruptcy, incentive compatibility is again restored. 52 / 56

Conclusion This article develops a model of optimal leverage and risky corporate bond prices for arbitrary debt maturity. Optimal leverage depends upon debt maturity and is markedly lower when the firm is financed by shorter term debt. The fact that longer term debt generates higher firm value poses the question of why firm issue short term debt. 53 / 56

Conclusion (cont.) The choice of debt maturity represents a trade-off between tax advantages, bankruptcy costs, and agency costs. Risker firm should issue shorter term debt in addition to using less debt. A firm with higher bankruptcy costs will prefer longer term debt. The tax benefit of long term debt are significantly reduced when cash flows relative to asset value are small. 54 / 56

Conclusion (cont.) Risky corporate debt behaves very differently from default-free debt. Effective duration may be shorter than Macaulay duration. Their techniques allow computation of the default probabilities, given the actual drift of the asset value process. 55 / 56

An EBIT-Based Model of Dynamic Capital Structure Robert Goldstein, Nengjinu Ju, Hayne Leland (2001), Journal of Business. They model the dynamics of the claim to earnings before interest and taxes (EBIT) as log-normal. The implication is that all contingent claimants (equity, debt, and government, etc.) to future EBIT flows are treated in a consistent fashion. The claim to EBIT flow should in practice be reasonably insensitive to changes in capital structure. This feature makes their framework ideal for optimal dynamic capital structure. 56 / 56