Lecture 4: From capital/income ratios to capital shares

Similar documents
Econ 133 Global Inequality and Growth. Inequality between labor and capital. Gabriel Zucman

Capital in the 21 st century. Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Visby, June

Capital in the 21 st century. Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Cologne, December 5 th 2013

Inequality and growth Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics

Capital in the 21 st century

Capital in the 21 st century

Why are real interest rates so low? Secular stagnation and the relative price of capital goods

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

Lecture notes 2: Physical Capital, Development and Growth

Macroeconomics Module 3: Cobb-Douglas production function practice problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.)

About Capital in the 21 st Century

Capital is Back: Wealth-Income Ratios in Rich Countries Thomas Piketty & Gabriel Zucman Paris School of Economics October 2012

Econ 230B Graduate Public Economics. Models of the wealth distribution. Gabriel Zucman

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

Preferences and Utility

Reflections on capital taxation

Q: How does a firm choose the combination of input to maximize output?

INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS

The Effect of Interventions to Reduce Fertility on Economic Growth. Quamrul Ashraf Ashley Lester David N. Weil. Brown University.

Rethinking Wealth Taxation

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Neoclassical Growth Theory

Modelling Economic Variables

A PRODUCER OPTIMUM. Lecture 7 Producer Behavior

Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Should the Rich Pay for Fiscal Adjustment? Income and Capital Tax Options

Growth and Inclusion: Theoretical and Applied Perspectives

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

WEALTH, CAPITAL ACCUMULATION and LIVING STANDARDS

Economic Growth Models and Inequality

LECTURE 3: MEASURING THE WEALTH OF NATIONS. Dr. Aidan Regan Website:

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Midterm 2 Review. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics Professor Sims University of Notre Dame, Spring 2018

Model for rate of return to capital mathematical spiciness: ********** 10 stars (this appendix uses some advanced calculus) 1 Introduction

IN THIS LECTURE, YOU WILL LEARN:

Prof. J. Sachs May 26, 2016 FIRST DRAFT COMMENTS WELCOME PLEASE QUOTE ONLY WITH PERMISSION

Advanced Macroeconomics 9. The Solow Model

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Wealth, inequality & assets: where is Europe heading?

Topic 2: Consumption

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Spring Trade and Development. Instructions

Economic Growth. (c) Copyright 1999 by Douglas H. Joines 1. Module Objectives

SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY Department of Economics. Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory Spring PROBLEM SET 1 (Solutions) Y = C + I + G + NX

Profit Max and RTS. Compare F(tL, tk) to tf(l,k) (where t>1) Which is the same as comparing doubling 1 inputs to doubling outputs

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Wealth inequality, family background, and estate taxation

Wealth, Inequality & Taxation. Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Berlin FU, June 13 th 2013 Lecture 1: Roadmap & the return of wealth

/papers/dilip/dynamics/aer/slides/slides.tex 1. Is Equality Stable? Dilip Mookherjee. Boston University. Debraj Ray. New York University

Introduction to economic growth (2)

Department of Economics Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Intermediate Macroeconomics

Testing the predictions of the Solow model:

Econ 133 Global Inequality and Growth. What is Income? Gabriel Zucman

ECON 2123 Problem Set 2

Online Appendix for Missing Growth from Creative Destruction

Summer 2016 ECN 303 Problem Set #1

RETURNS TO SCALE. Right.

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Course Notes on Basic Theoretical Models of Economic Growth, Wealth Accumulation and Concentration

Financial Autarky and International Business Cycles (JME 2002)

Part V: Introduction to Macroeconomics 19. The Wealth of Nations: Defining and Measuring Macroeconomic Aggregates 20.

Lecture 6: The structure of inequality: capital ownership

Deciphering the fall and rise in the net capital share by Matthew Rognlie, MIT BPEA Conference Draft (March, 2015)

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Lecture 17: Investment (chapter 17)

LECTURE 3 NEO-CLASSICAL AND NEW GROWTH THEORY

Why are Banks Exposed to Monetary Policy?

Lecture 11. The firm s problem. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD II Semestre 2017 Last updated: October 16, 2017

ECON 450 Development Economics

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

Testing the predictions of the Solow model: What do the data say?

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Econ 133 Global Inequality and Growth. What is Income? Gabriel Zucman

Annuity Markets and Capital Accumulation

Dr Piketty on wealth and capital: Accumulation vs. finance

ECON 3010 Intermediate Macroeconomics. Chapter 3 National Income: Where It Comes From and Where It Goes

Check your understanding: Solow model 1

Price Elasticity of Demand

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory Ariel Zetlin-Jones and Ali Shourideh

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po

Robots, Growth, and Inequality: Should We Fear the Robot Revolution? The Correct Answer is Yes

Advanced Macroeconomics 8. Growth Accounting

Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand

Principles of Macroeconomics Lecture Notes L3-L4 (Production and the labor market.) Veronica Guerrieri

Traditional growth models Pasquale Tridico

14.13 Economics and Psychology (Lecture 5)

QI SHANG: General Equilibrium Analysis of Portfolio Benchmarking

Getting Started with CGE Modeling

ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section

Lecture 05 Production

Lecture 3: Quantifying the Role of Credit Markets in Economic Development

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Wealth Accumulation in the US: Do Inheritances and Bequests Play a Significant Role

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

Econ 302 Assignment 2 Answer Key

Transcription:

Economics of Inequality (Master PPD & APE, Paris School of Economics) Thomas Piketty Academic year 2014-2015 Lecture 4: From capital/income ratios to capital shares (Tuesday October 14 th 2014) (check on line for updated versions)

Capital-income ratios β vs. capital shares α Capital/income ratio β=k/y Capital share α = Y K /Y with Y K = capital income (=sum of rent, dividends, interest, profits, etc.: i.e. all incomes going to the owners of capital, independently of any labor input) I.e. β = ratio between capital stock and income flow While α = share of capital income in total income flow By definition: α = r x β With r = Y K /K = average real rate of return to capital If β=600% and r=5%, then α = 30% = typical values

In practice, the average rate of return to capital r (typically r 4-5%) varies a lot across assets and over individuals (more on this in Lecture 6) Typically, rental return on housing = 3-4% (i.e. the rental value of an appartment worth 100 000 is generally about 3000-4000 /year) (+ capital gain or loss) Return on stock market (dividend + k gain) = as much as 6-7% in the long run Return on bank accounts or cash = as little as 1-2% (but only a small fraction of total wealth) Average return across all assets and individuals 4-5%

The Cobb-Douglas production function Cobb-Douglas production function: Y = F(K,L) = K α L 1-α With perfect competition, wage rate v = marginal product of labor, rate of return r = marginal product of capital: r = F K = α K α-1 L 1-α and v = F L = (1-α) K α L -α Therefore capital income Y K = r K = α Y & labor income Y L = v L = (1-α) Y I.e. capital & labor shares are entirely set by technology (say, α=30%, 1-α=70%) and do not depend on quantities K, L Intuition: Cobb-Douglas elasticity of substitution between K & L is exactly equal to 1 I.e. if v/r rises by 1%, K/L=α/(1-α) v/r also rises by 1%. So the quantity response exactly offsets the change in prices: if wages by 1%, then firms use 1% less labor, so that labor share in total output remains the same as before

The limits of Cobb-Douglas Economists like Cobb-Douglas production function, because stable capital shares are approximately stable However it is only an approximation: in practice, capital shares α vary in the 20-40% range over time and between countries (or even sometime in the 10-50% range) In 19c, capital shares were closer to 40%; in 20c, they were closer to 20-30%; structural rise of human capital (i.e. exponent α in Cobb-Douglas production function Y = K α L 1-α?), or purely temporary phenomenon? Over 1970-2010 period, capital shares have increased from 15-25% to 25-30% in rich countries : very difficult to explain with Cobb-Douglas framework

The CES production function CES = a simple way to think about changing capital shares CES : Y = F(K,L) = [a K (σ-1)/σ + b L (σ-1)/σ ] σ/(σ-1) with a, b = constant σ = constant elasticity of substitution between K and L σ : linear production function Y = r K + v L (infinite substitution: machines can replace workers and vice versa, so that the returns to capital and labor do not fall at all when the quantity of capital or labor rise) ( = robot economy) σ 0: F(K,L)=min(rK,vL) (fixed coefficients) = no substitution possibility: one needs exactly one machine per worker σ 1: converges toward Cobb-Douglas; but all intermediate cases are also possible: Cobb-Douglas is just one possibility among many Compute the first derivative r = F K : the marginal product to capital is given by r = F K = a β -1/σ (with β=k/y) I.e. r as β (more capital makes capital less useful), but the important point is that the speed at which r depends on σ

With r = F K = a β -1/σ, the capital share α is given by: α = r β = a β (σ-1)/σ I.e. α is an increasing function of β if and only if σ>1 (and stable iff σ=1) The important point is that with large changes in the volume of capital β, small departures from σ=1 are enough to explain large changes in α If σ = 1.5, capital share rises from α=28% to α =36% when β rises from β=250% to β =500% = more or less what happened since the 1970s In case β reaches β =800%, α would reach α =42% In case σ =1.8, α would be as large as α =53%

Measurement problems with capital shares In many ways, β is easier to measure than α In principle, capital income = all income flows going to capital owners (independanty of any labor input); labor income = all income flows going to labor earners (independantly of any capital input) But in practice, the line is often hard to draw: family firms, selfsemployed workers, informal financial intermediation costs (=the time spent to manage one s own portfolio) If one measures the capital share α from national accounts (rent+dividend+interest+profits) and compute average return r=α/β, then the implied r often looks very high for a pure return to capital ownership: it probably includes a non-negligible entrepreneurial labor component, particularly in reconstruction periods with low β and high r; the pure return might be 20-30% smaller (see estimates) Maybe one should use two-sector models Y=Y h +Y b (housing + business); return to housing = closer to pure return to capital

Recent work on capital shares Imperfect competition and globalization: see Karabarmounis-Neiman 2013, «The Global Decline in the Labor Share»; see also KN2014 Public vs private firms: see Azmat-Manning- Van Reenen 2011, «Privatization and the Decline of the Labor Share in GDP: A Cross- Country Aanalysis of the Network Industries» Capital shares and CEO pay: see Pursey 2013, «CEO Pay and Factor shares: Bargaining effects in US corporations 1970-2011»

Summing up The rate of return to capital r is determined mostly by technology: r = F K = marginal product to capital, elasticity of substitution σ The quantity of capital β is determined by saving attitudes and by growth (=fertility + innovation): β = s/g The capital share is determined by the product of the two: α = r x β Anything can happen

Note: the return to capital r=f K is dermined not only by technology but also by psychology, i.e. saving attitudes s=s(r) might vary with the rate of return In models with wealth or bequest in the utility function U(c t,w t+1 ), there is zero saving elasticity with U(c,w)=c 1-s w s, but with more general functional forms on can get any elasticity In pure lifecycle model, the saving rate s is primarily determined by demographic structure (more time in retirement higher s), but it can also vary with the rate of return, in particular if the rate of return becomes very low (say, below 2%) or very high (say, above 6%)

In the dynastic utility model, the rate of return is entirely set by the rate of time preference (=psychological parameter) and the growth rate: Max Σ U(c t )/(1+δ) t, with U(c)=c 1-1/ξ /(1-1/ξ) unique long rate rate of return r t r = δ +ξg > g (ξ>1 and transverality condition) This holds both in the representative agent version of model and in the heteogenous agent version (with insurable shocks); more on this in Lecture 6