Valuation of Exit Strategy under Decaying Abandonment Value

Similar documents
Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets

Economic Risk and Decision Analysis for Oil and Gas Industry CE School of Engineering and Technology Asian Institute of Technology

Combining Real Options and game theory in incomplete markets.

EFFECT OF IMPLEMENTATION TIME ON REAL OPTIONS VALUATION. Mehmet Aktan

On the investment}uncertainty relationship in a real options model

The investment game in incomplete markets

Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market

REAL OPTIONS AND PRODUCT LIFE CYCLES *

The investment game in incomplete markets.

Probability in Options Pricing

Numerical Evaluation of Multivariate Contingent Claims

Real Options and Signaling in Strategic Investment Games

On the Real Option Value of Scientific Uncertainty for Public Policies. Justus Wesseler

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

Homework Assignments

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

FURTHER ASPECTS OF GAMBLING WITH THE KELLY CRITERION. We consider two aspects of gambling with the Kelly criterion. First, we show that for

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

Credit Risk and Underlying Asset Risk *

LECTURES ON REAL OPTIONS: PART III SOME APPLICATIONS AND EXTENSIONS

A Real Options Game: Investment on the Project with Operational Options and Fixed Costs

Quasi option value under ambiguity. Abstract

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited

STEX s valuation analysis, version 0.0

Fractional Liu Process and Applications to Finance

Smooth pasting as rate of return equalisation: A note

TEST OF BOUNDED LOG-NORMAL PROCESS FOR OPTIONS PRICING

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

The Investment Game under Uncertainty: An Analysis of Equilibrium Values in the Presence of First or Second Mover Advantage.

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Pricing CDOs with the Fourier Transform Method. Chien-Han Tseng Department of Finance National Taiwan University

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

CDS Pricing Formula in the Fuzzy Credit Risk Market

REVERSE HYSTERESIS : R&D INVESTMENT WITH STOCHASTIC INNOVATION *

TIØ 1: Financial Engineering in Energy Markets

1. Traditional investment theory versus the options approach

Real Option Analysis for Adjacent Gas Producers to Choose Optimal Operating Strategy, such as Gas Plant Size, Leasing rate, and Entry Point

Capacity Expansion Games with Application to Competition in Power May 19, Generation 2017 Investmen 1 / 24

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06

Pricing levered warrants with dilution using observable variables

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

OPTIMAL TIMING FOR INVESTMENT DECISIONS

The stochastic calculus

Appendix: Basics of Options and Option Pricing Option Payoffs

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

A Bayesian Approach to Real Options:

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.pr] 23 Nov 2017

Fuel-Switching Capability

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Portfolio Optimization using Conditional Sharpe Ratio

Pricing Convertible Bonds under the First-Passage Credit Risk Model

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS WITH ADVANCED TOPICS MTHE7013A

Cash Accumulation Strategy based on Optimal Replication of Random Claims with Ordinary Integrals

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Agency Cost and Court Action in Bankruptcy Proceedings in a Simple Real Option Model

The Value of Petroleum Exploration under Uncertainty

Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs. Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo

2.1 Mathematical Basis: Risk-Neutral Pricing

Uncertainty and the Dynamics of R&D*

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE

Computational Efficiency and Accuracy in the Valuation of Basket Options. Pengguo Wang 1

Luca Taschini. 6th Bachelier World Congress Toronto, June 25, 2010

Applied Mathematics Letters. On local regularization for an inverse problem of option pricing

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

Numerical Methods for Pricing Energy Derivatives, including Swing Options, in the Presence of Jumps

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SUNK COSTS AND REAL OPTIONS IN ANTITRUST. Robert S. Pindyck. Working Paper

Investigation of Dependency between Short Rate and Transition Rate on Pension Buy-outs. Arık, A. 1 Yolcu-Okur, Y. 2 Uğur Ö. 2

Investment, Capacity Choice and Outsourcing under Uncertainty

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products

The Application of Real Options to Capital Budgeting

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

Modern Corporate Finance Theory and Real Options PhD Course

Dynamic Capital Structure Choice and Investment Timing

Welfare and Profit Comparison between Quantity and Price Competition in Stackelberg Mixed Duopolies

Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology

Valuing Capacity Investment Decisions: Binomial vs. Markov Models

The Multistep Binomial Model

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

RISK MANAGEMENT IN PUBLIC-PRIVATE PARTNERSHIP ROAD PROJECTS USING THE REAL OPTIONS THEORY

Online Appendix: Extensions

Replication strategies of derivatives under proportional transaction costs - An extension to the Boyle and Vorst model.

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

Transcription:

Communications in Mathematical Finance, vol. 4, no., 05, 3-4 ISSN: 4-95X (print version), 4-968 (online) Scienpress Ltd, 05 Valuation of Exit Strategy under Decaying Abandonment Value Ming-Long Wang and Chien-Chih Peng Abstract We examine the valuation of abandonment decision in a contingent claims model with uncertainty in future market conditions and analyze the effect of determinants on the abandonment value. We find the abandonment value is positively related with the number of abandonment opportunities. The increase in the volatility, variable cost, and facility value increases the expected abandonment value, whereas the increase in the growth rate and depreciation rate reduces the expected abandonment value. The volatility, growth rate, and depreciation rate are negatively related with the exit threshold, whereas the variable cost and facility value are positively related with the exit threshold. Mathematics Subject Classification: 60G5; 60H05; 60H0; 65D5 Keywords: Real option; Abandonment option; Exit strategy Introduction Capital budgeting methods based on option pricing theory have recently been developed to incorporate managers ability to respond to the resolution of uncertainty over time. Conventional capital budgeting procedure presumes that future cash flows and duration of a project are certain and salvage value is the last relevant cash flow. Thus, the only relevant decision is whether to accept or reject the project at time zero. In a real business environment, however, a firm makes production and investment decisions contingent on subsequent estimation of stochastic incremental cash flows. When the value of future production opportunity is less than the value of a project that is abandoned irreversibly, firms may either choose to delay abandonment or exercise abandonment option to collect the abandonment value of a project. Therefore, a firm s flexible strategic behavior to react on the future prospect of investment projects can affect their abandonment value. Graduate Institute of Finance & Banking, National Cheng-Kung University. Tainan, Taiwan. College of Business and Public Affairs, Morehead State University, Morehead, Kentucky, USA. Article Info: Received : March, 05. Revised : April 3, 05. Published online : June 0, 05

4 Ming-Long Wang and Chien-Chih Peng The abandonment value of capital assets is related to the economic depreciation rate which measures the decline in market value of capital assets through time. Since the abandonment value of capital assets is treated as a strike price and can decay at a depreciation rate through time, various abandonment decision criteria can be formulated under market uncertainty. The goal of this paper is to evaluate exit strategy and find abandonment decision criteria under the consideration of decaying abandonment value, flexible strategic behavior, and investment under market uncertainty. Robichek and Van Horne [] are the pioneers to recognize the practical importance of the option to abandon a project. They argue that a project is abandoned immediately as soon as the salvage value exceeds the net present value of subsequent expected operating cash flows. Dyl and Long [] argue that the decision rule proposed by Robichek and Van Horne [] may be sub-optimal, and that an optimal decision rule must consider the cases where it may be more profitable to wait and abandon in the future. If a project is not abandoned immediately, a firm retains the option to abandon in the future and the option can be valuable. Thus, an optimal abandonment decision on a project depends on the salvage value of the project and the optimal timing of exercising the abandonment option. Smit and Trigerogis [3] describe the abandonment option as the opportunity for firms to permanently abandon the current operation and realize the abandonment value of capital equipment and other assets in secondary markets if the market condition severely declines. An example where abandonment is important is research and development (R&D) programs. When results from experiments are not favorable, the line of research should be abandoned. Other examples are that mines can be abandoned and factories can be closed permanently. Whenever maintenance costs for maintaining idle production capacity are too costly, perceptibly decreasing salvage value due to technological progress or natural obsolesce may induce firms to abandon capital investment projects before they reach their terminal dates. Severe market competition or over-pessimistic economic condition can lead firms losing competitive niche and exit the market permanently. Baker and Powell [4] note that an often-cited decision rule for firms to abandon projects when the abandonment value of capital assets is greater than the present value of all cash flows generated by capital assets beyond the abandonment year, discounted to the abandonment decision point, is technically incorrect primarily because it ignores future abandonment opportunities. In theory, the option to abandon a project is widely recognized as an American put option on a dividend-paying stock, and is valuable because the option allows firms to do wait and see. If firms have the option to abandon investment projects before implementing the projects, the abandonment option can increase the value of the projects. The increase in the number of abandonment opportunities can increase the abandonment value. Several papers in the real options literature study the abandonment option. Brennan and Schwartz [5] use the techniques of continuous time arbitrage and stochastic control theory to evaluate natural resource projects, and provide the optimal abandonment decision rules at known intervals based on a constant salvage value and price of the underlying commodity. McDonald and Siegel [6] use option-pricing techniques to study the investment problem that a firm has the option to shut down production costlessly and temporarily. Dixit [7] analyzes the hysteresis effect on a firm s entry and exit decision when the firm s output price follows the random walk and the firm s assets depreciates immediately on abandonment. Myers and Majd [8] model abandonment option in an American put option framework and evaluate the abandonment option under assumption of stochastic project value, deterministic declining salvage value and constant payout

Valuation of Exit Strategy under Decaying Abandonment Value 5 ratios. In contrast, Dixit and Pindyck [9] study the abandonment option by considering an infinitely lived dividend paying investment with constant salvage value and derive optimal abandonment rules. Clark and Rousseau [0] investigate how abandonment option can be used as a management tool to evaluate the invest/abandon decision and analyze ongoing project management, financial forecasting and the timing of strategic moves. Pfeiffer and Schneider [] explore how an abandonment option influences the optimal timing of information in a sequential adverse selection capital budgeting model. Wong [] examines how the presence of an abandonment option affects the timing and intensity of a firm s investment. This paper extends this development of real option approach by focusing on optimal abandonment decisions. We analyze and evaluate the option to abandon a project for its salvage value by developing a multi-period contingent claims model under the assumption of stochastic market demand and projects decaying salvage value. Our paper is also related to recent studies in real options incorporating firms strategic behavior into investment project evaluation. For example, Grenadier [3] develops an equilibrium framework for strategic option exercise games to analyze the timing of real estate development. Kulatilaka and Perotti [4] provide a strategic rationale for growth options under uncertainty and imperfect competition. Childs and Triantis [5] examine dynamic R&D investment policies and the valuation of R&D programs by considering several important characteristics of R&D programs. This paper also considers a firm s strategic behavior in formulating optimal abandonment decision criteria. The paper is organized as follows. Section describes and formulates mathematical model for abandonment option valuation. Section 3 presents numerical solutions. We conclude in Section 4, and the proof is given in Appendix. Valuation Model We follow Kulatilaka and Perotti (998) and assume a firm has monopoly power in both the investment opportunity and the product market. Since future market condition is unknown, we assume that the demand for the product is linear in prices and increasing in the random variable θ. Let P(Q) be the inverse demand function expressing the market price as a function of product quantity Q: P(θ, Q) = θ Q and dθ = μdt + σdz, θ where θ is the market condition following lognormal distribution with drift term µ and variance σ. dz is the standard Wiener process. The firm produces at a unit cost of only when the market is profitable. The firm v chooses an output level Q = (θ T v) and generates operating profits π = 4 (θ T v). The firm will not produce if θ T < θ (T) v. Therefore, the payoff function at time T can be expressed as: π T = { (θ T v) 4, if θ T θ (T) 0, if θ T < θ (T) () Assuming that the capital investment is irreversible, we discount the firm s expected operating profits at the cost of capital r and express the present value of operating profit

6 Ming-Long Wang and Chien-Chih Peng V 0 as: V 0 = e rt [ (θ T v) ] prob(θ 4 T v θ 0 ) = θ 0 4 exp [ (μ r + σ ) T] N(d ) vθ 0 exp[(μ r)t] N(d ) + v 4 e rt N(d 3 ) () where d = ln (θ 0 v )+(μ+3 σ )T σ T, d = d σ T, and d 3 = d σ T. In contrast, if the firm makes an initial reversible investment of on a production facility that depreciates at a rate ρ, the downside of payoff function in Equation () needs to modify to recognize the value of abandonment option. When exiting the market, the firm can cease the operation, sell the facility, and get the abandonment value in return. The abandonment value at time t is Fe ρt. We now consider that a firm can only exercise the abandonment option at the end of investment project (terminal). This case is similar to European put options. We can express the payoff at time T as: F (θ T v), if θ π T = { 4 T θ (T) Fe ρt, if θ T < θ (T) (3) where θ (T) is the criteria at time T and can be expressed as θ (T) = v + Fe ρt. The criteria show that even though operating profits are higher than unit cost of production, firms may exit the market. The expected payoff at time T, E(π T θ 0 ), is: E(π T θ 0 ) = [ (θ T v) ] prob[θ 4 T θ (T) θ 0 ] + Fe ρt prob[θ T < θ (T) θ 0 ] = θ 0 σ exp [ (μ + 4 ) T] N(d ) vθ 0 eμt N(d ) + v 4 N(d 3) + Fe ρt [ N(d 3 )] where d = ln[ θ 0 θ (T) ]+(μ+3 σ )T σ T, d = ln[ θ 0 θ (T) ]+(μ+ σ )T σ T, and d 3 = ln[ θ 0 θ (T) ]+(μ σ )T Given the expected payoff at time T, we can express the present value of expected future payoff as: e rt E(π T θ 0 ) = θ 0 4 exp [ (μ σ T r + σ ) T] N(d ) vθ 0 exp [(μ r)t]n(d ) + v 4 e rt N(d 3 ) + Fe (ρ+r)t [ N(d 3 )] (4) Comparing Equation (4) with Equation (), we can express the expected abandonment value at time T as: Expected Abandonment Value = e rt E(π T θ 0 ) V 0 (5)

Valuation of Exit Strategy under Decaying Abandonment Value 7 Equation (5) shows that the expected abandonment value is the excess value of an investment project with abandonment option over an investment project without abandonment option.. The Evaluation of a Project with Two Abandonment Opportunities at a Predetermined Node and Terminal We now consider that a firm can exercise the abandonment option not only at the terminal but also at a predetermined node t. This case is similar to warrants. Figure shows the time line of an investment project with two abandonment opportunities. 0 T t The firm makes its investment decision based on the current market condition. The firm has an opportunity to decide whether to exit the market. The firm has an opportunity to get either the operating profit or the abandonment value. Figure : Time Line of an Investment with Two Abandonment Opportunities. At time t, if the firm does not exercise the abandonment option, the firm will continue the operation and receive the present value of the expected payoff at time T. Alternatively, the firm may consider exiting the market if the present value of expected payoff at time T is lower than the abandonment value at time t. The payoff function at time t is: π t = { e r(t t ) E(π T θ t ), ifθ t θ (t ) Fe ρt, ifθ t < θ (t ) where θ (t ) is the firm s exit threshold. Equation (6) shows that the expected operating profit is an increasing function of θ t (the market condition at time t ). We can express the expected payoff at time t as (see Appendix for derivation) E(π t θ 0 ) = e r(t t ) E(π T θ t )prob[θ t θ (t ) θ 0 ] + Fe ρt prob[θ t < θ (t ) θ 0 ] = e r(t t) { (θ T v) prob[θ 4 T θ (T) θ t ] +Fe ρt prob[θ t < θ (t ) θ 0 ] + Fe ρt prob[θ T < θ (T) θ t ]} prob[θ t θ (t ) θ 0 ] = 4 (θ 0) e (μ+ σ )T r(t t ) (π) e (x ) a a e (x ) dx dx (6)

8 Ming-Long Wang and Chien-Chih Peng v (θ 0)e μt r(t t) (π) e (y ) b b c +e r(t t) [ v 4 Fe ρt ] (π) e c c e (y ) dy dy (z ) e (z ) dz dz +[Fe (ρ+r)t+rt Fe ρt ] (π) e (z ) dz + Fe ρt (7) where x i, y i, and z i follow standard normal distributions, and a i, b i, and c i are integral upper-boundaries. The definitions are as the following: x = lnθ t [lnθ 0 + (μ + 3 σ )t ], x σ t = lnθ 3 T [lnθ t + (μ + σ )(T t )] σ T t y = lnθ t [lnθ 0 + (μ + σ )t ], y σ t = lnθ T [lnθ t + (μ + σ )(T t )] σ T t z = lnθ t [lnθ 0 + (μ σ )t ], z σ t = lnθ T [lnθ t + (μ σ )(T t )] σ T t ln [ a = ln [ b = ln [ c = θ 0 θ (t ) ] + (μ + 3 σ )t σ t, a = θ 0 θ (t ) ] + (μ + σ )t σ t, b = θ 0 θ (t ) ] + (μ σ )t σ t, c = ln [ θ t θ (T) ] + (μ + 3 σ )(T t ) σ T t ln [ θ t θ (T) ] + (μ + σ )(T t ) σ T t ln [ θ t θ (T) ] + (μ σ )(T t ) σ T t Then, we discount the Equation (7) with the cost of capital to get the present value of expected operating profits. e rt E(π t θ 0 ) = θ 0 exp [ (μ r + σ ) T] 4σ t (T t ) vθ b 0 exp[(μ r)t] b σ t (T t ) (π) e (y ) a a (π) e (x ) exp( rt) + σ t (T t ) [v 4 Fe ρt ] (π) e c c e (y ) dy dy (z ) e (z ) dz dz e (x ) dx dx +[Fe (ρ+r)t Fe (ρ+r)t c ] (π) e (z ) dz + Fe (ρ+r)t (8) Comparing Equation (8) with Equation (4), we find that adding one abandonment opportunity increases the present value of the expected operating profit significantly by the excess of the present value of abandonment value.

Valuation of Exit Strategy under Decaying Abandonment Value 9. The Evaluation of a Project with n Abandonment Opportunities at any Time before Maturity We now extend our model by considering that a firm can exercise the abandonment option at any time before maturity. This case is similar to American put options. We divided the time to maturity into n periods. Each node represents the time that the firm can exercise the abandonment option. Figure shows the time line of an investment with n abandonment opportunities. 0 t T tn- The firm makes its investment decision based on the current market condition. The firm has an opportunity to decide whether to exit the market. The firm has an opportunity to decide whether to exit the market. The firm has an opportunity to get either the Figure : Time Line of an Investment with n Abandonment Opportunities To solve for expected payoff at a period, we can work backwards to estimate expected operating profit at the prior period. Since the abandonment value decreases through time, the decision criteria at each node can be different. We need to know the decision criteria at a determined node first so that we can derive the payoff function. The payoff function at terminal is Equation (3). The payoff function at each node before the terminal can be expressed as: π ti = { e r(t i+ t i ) E(π ti+ θ ti ), ifθ ti θ (t i ) Fe ρt i, ifθ ti < θ for i =,,., n (9) (t i ) The expected value of π ti can be expressed as: E(π ti θ ti ) = e r(t i+ t i ) E(π ti+ θ ti )prob[θ ti θ (t i ) θ ti ] + Fe ρt iprob[θ ti < θ (t i ) θ ti ] We use the recursive method to obtain the present value of future expected operating profit at time 0. e rt E(π t θ 0 ) = θ 0 exp [ (μ r + σ ) t n ] a a 4σ n t (t t ) (t n t n ) a n (π) n exp [ (x i) ] dx dx n n i=

30 Ming-Long Wang and Chien-Chih Peng vθ 0 exp [(μ r)t n ] b b b n σ n t (t t ) (t n t n ) (π) n exp [ (y i) ] dy dy n i= c exp ( rt n ) c + σ n t (t t ) (t n t n ) [v 4 Fe ρt n] c n (π) n exp [ (z i) ] dz dz n n i= c + [Fe (ρ+r)t n Fe (ρ+r)t n ] σ n t (t t ) (t n t n ) dz n c + [Fe (ρ+r)t n Fe (ρ+r)t n ] σ n t (t t ) (t n t n 3 ) dz n c c n c n (π) (n ) c n (π) (n ) n exp [ (z i) ] dz i= n exp [ (z i) ] dz +[Fe (ρ+r)t Fe (ρ+r)t c ] (π) e (z ) dz + Fe (ρ+r)t (0) where x i, y i, and z i follow standard normal distributions, and a i, b i, and c i are integral upper-boundaries. The definitions are as the following: x i = lnθ t i [lnθ ti + (μ + 3 σ ) (t i t i )], y i σ t i t i = lnθ t i [lnθ ti + (μ + σ ) (t i t i )] σ t i t i, z i = lnθ t i [lnθ ti + (μ σ ) (t i t i )] σ t i t i a i = c i = for i =,,, n ln [ θ i θ (t i ) ] + (μ + 3 σ ) (t i t i ) ln [ θ i θ, b i = (t i ) ] + (μ + σ ) (t i t i ), σ t i t i σ t i t i ln [ θ i θ (t i ) ] + (μ σ ) (t i t i ) σ t i t i for i =,,, n Comparing Equation (0) with (8), we find that adding more abandonment opportunities increases the present value of the expected operating profit significantly by the excess of the present value of abandonment value. i= 3 Numerical Solutions We apply the numerical method to derive some results to show how the number of abandonment opportunities, volatility of future market condition, variable cost, growth

Expected Abandonment Value Valuation of Exit Strategy under Decaying Abandonment Value 3 rate, depreciation rate, and facility value can affect the expected abandonment value and how exit thresholds can be varied at different abandonment nodes. Matlab programming is used to plot the simulation results. We select a base set of following parameters for our analysis: growth rate of market condition µ = 5%, cost of capital r = 0%, rate of depreciation ρ = 50%, variable cost per unit v = 5, facility value F = 0,000, volatility σ = 40%, and time to maturity T =. To simplify the analysis, we only consider projects with one, two, and three abandonment opportunities. Figure 3 shows the relationship between expected abandonment value and current market conditions under different number of abandonment opportunities. The figure shows that the more opportunities for firms to exit the market before maturity, the more valuable the abandonment option, and the higher the expected abandonment value. However, the increase in expected abandonment value decreases with the increase in abandonment opportunities. The expected abandonment value is negatively related with the current market condition. Figure 4 shows the relationship between expected abandonment value and volatility under different levels of market condition. The figure shows that the expected abandonment value is positively related with the volatility of market condition. The change in expected abandonment value given a change in volatility increases as current market conditions become better. 8000 7000 With One Opportunity With Two Opportunities With Three Opportunities 6000 5000 4000 3000 000 000 0 0 40 60 80 00 0 4 60 80 00 Current Market Condition Figure 3: Expected Abandonment Values under Different Number of Abandonment Opportunities.

Market Condition Expected Abandonment Value 3 Ming-Long Wang and Chien-Chih Peng 4000 000 Theta 0 =75 Theta 0 =50 Theta 0 =5 0000 8000 6000 4000 000 0 0 0. 0. 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Volatility Figure 4: The Relationship between Volatility and Expected Abandonment Value under Different Market Conditions. Figure 5 shows how exit thresholds at each abandonment node vary under different levels of volatility. At any given abandonment node, the higher the volatility, the lower the exit threshold. At a low volatility level, the longer the time to maturity, the higher the exit threshold, and the exit threshold decreases as the terminal approaches. On the other hand, at a high volatility level, the longer the time to maturity, the lower the exit threshold, and the exit threshold increases as the terminal approaches. 80 70 60 Volatility=5% Volatility=50% Volatility=95% 50 40 30 0 0 00 0.33 0.67 Time Period Figure 5: The Effect of Volatility on Exit Threshold. Figure 6 shows the relationship between expected abandonment value and variable cost under different levels of market condition. The figure shows that the expected

Market Condition Expected Abandonment Value Valuation of Exit Strategy under Decaying Abandonment Value 33 abandonment value is positively related with the variable cost. The change in expected abandonment value given a change in variable cost increases as current market conditions become worse. 4500 4000 Theta 0 =75 Theta 0 =50 Theta 0 =5 3500 3000 500 000 500 000 0 5 0 5 0 5 30 Variable Cost per Unit Figure 6: The Relationship between Variable Cost and Expected Abandonment Value under Different Market Conditions. Figure 7 shows how exit thresholds at each abandonment node vary under different levels of variable cost. At any given abandonment node, the higher the variable cost, the higher the exit threshold. At a low variable cost level, the longer the time to maturity, the higher the exit threshold, and the exit threshold decreases as the terminal approaches. On the other hand, at a high variable cost level, the longer the time to maturity, the higher the exit threshold, and the exit threshold decreases at the beginning and becomes increasing in the middle to the terminal. 75 70 65 Variable Cost=5 Variable Cost=0 Variable Cost=0 Variable Cost=30 60 55 50 45 40 35 0.33 0.67 Time Period Figure 7: The Effect of Variable Cost on Exit Threshold.

Market Condition Expected Abandonment Value 34 Ming-Long Wang and Chien-Chih Peng Figure 8 shows the relationship between expected abandonment value and growth rate under different levels of market condition. The figure shows that the expected abandonment value is negatively related with the growth rate. The change in expected abandonment value given a change in growth rate increases as current market conditions become worse. 3500 3000 Theta 0 =75 Theta 0 =50 Theta 0 =5 500 000 500 000 500 0 0 0. 0. 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Growth Rate Figure 8: The Relationship between Growth Rate and Expected Abandonment Value under Different Market Conditions. Figure 9 shows how exit thresholds at each abandonment node vary under different levels of growth rate. At any given abandonment node, the higher the growth rate, the lower the exit threshold. At a low growth rate level, the longer the time to maturity, the higher the exit threshold, and the exit threshold decreases as the terminal approaches. On the other hand, at a high growth rate level, the longer the time to maturity, the lower the exit threshold, and the exit threshold increases as the terminal approaches. 70 60 Growth Rate=5% Growth Rate=50% Growth Rate=95% 50 40 30 0 0 00 90 0.33 0.67 Time Period Figure 9: The Effect of Growth Rate on Exit Threshold.

Expected Abandonment Value Valuation of Exit Strategy under Decaying Abandonment Value 35 Figure 0 shows the relationship between expected abandonment value and depreciation rate under different levels of market condition. The figure shows that the expected abandonment value is negatively related with the depreciation rate. The change in expected abandonment value given a change in depreciation rate increases as current market conditions become worse. Figure shows how exit thresholds at each abandonment node vary under different levels of depreciation rate. At any given abandonment node, the higher the depreciation rate, the lower the exit threshold. At a low depreciation rate level, the longer the time to maturity, the lower the exit threshold, and the exit threshold increases as the terminal approaches. On the other hand, at a high depreciation rate level, the longer the time to maturity, the higher the exit threshold, and the exit threshold decreases as the terminal approaches. 5000 4500 4000 Theta 0 =75 Theta 0 =50 Theta 0 =5 3500 3000 500 000 500 000 0 0. 0. 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Depreciation Rate Figure 0: The Relationship between Depreciation Rate and Expected Abandonment Value under Different Market Conditions

Expected Abandonment Value Market Condition 36 Ming-Long Wang and Chien-Chih Peng 0 00 90 Depreciation Rate=5% Depreciation Rate=50% Depreciation Rate=95% 80 70 60 50 40 30 0 0.33 0.67 Time Period Figure : The Effect of Depreciation Rate on Exit Threshold. Figure shows the relationship between expected abandonment value and facility value under different levels of market condition. The figure shows that the expected abandonment value is positively related with the facility value. The change in expected abandonment value given a change in facility value increases as current market conditions become worse. 9000 8000 7000 Theta 0 =75 Theta 0 =50 Theta 0 =5 6000 5000 4000 3000 000 000 0. 0.4 0.6 0.8..4.6.8 Facility Value x 0 4 Figure : The Relationship between Facility Value and Expected Abandonment Value under Different Market Conditions. Figure 3 shows how exit thresholds at each abandonment node vary under different levels of facility value. At any given abandonment node, the higher the facility value, the higher the exit threshold. In all levels of facility value, the longer the maturity, the higher

Market Condition Valuation of Exit Strategy under Decaying Abandonment Value 37 the exit threshold, and the exit threshold decreases at the beginning and becomes increasing in the middle to the terminal. 0 00 Facility Value=3000 Facility Value=0000 Facility Value=7000 80 60 40 0 00 80 0.33 0.66 Time Period Figure 3: The Effect of Facility Value on Exit Threshold. 4 Conclusion We analyze the abandonment decision in a contingent claims model that considers future abandonment opportunities, economic depreciation, flexible strategic behavior, and investment under uncertainty. Results from the numerical method show that volatility of future market condition, variable cost, growth rate, depreciation rate, and facility value can affect the abandonment value of investment projects. We also provide the decision criteria under various scenarios. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS: The authors are grateful to the anonymous referees for their constructive suggestions that tremendously improved the quality of the manuscript. References [] A. A. Robichek and J. C. Van Horne, Abandonment Value and Capital Budgeting, Journal of Finance, (4), (967), 577-589. [] E. A. Dyl and W. H. Long, Abandonment Value and Capital Budgeting: Comment, Journal of Finance, 4(), (969), 88-95. [3] H. Smit and L. Trigeoris, Strategic Investment Real Options and Games, Princeton University Press, 004. [4] H. K. Baker and G. E. Powell, Understanding Financial Management a Practical Guide, Blackwell Publishing, 005. [5] M. J. Brennan and E. S. Schwartz, Evaluating Natural Resource Investments, Journal of Business, 58(), (985), 35-57.

38 Ming-Long Wang and Chien-Chih Peng [6] R. McDonald and D. Siegel, Investment and the Valuation of Firms When There Is an Option to Shut Down, International Economic Review, 6(), (985), 33-349. [7] A. K. Dixit, Entry and Exit Decision under Uncertainty, Journal of Political Economy, 97(3), (989), 60-638. [8] S. C. Myers and S. Majd, Abandonment Value and Project Life, Advances in Future and Options Research, 4(), (990), -. [9] A. K. Dixit and R. S. Pindyck, Investment under Uncertainty, Princeton University Press, 994. [0] E. Clark and P. Rousseau, Strategic Parameters for Capital Budgeting When Abandonment Value Is Stochastic, Applied Financial Economics, (), (00), 3-30. [] T. Pfeiffer and G. Schneider, Capital Budgeting, Information Timing, and the Value of Abandonment Options, Management Accounting Research, (4), (00), 38-50. [] K. P. Wong, The Effects of Abandonment Options on Investment Timing and Intensity, Bulletin of Economic Research, 64(3), (0), 305-38. [3] S. R. Grenadier, The Strategic Exercise of Options: Development Cascades and Overbuilding in Real Estate Markets, Journal of Finance, 5(5), (996), 653-679. [4] N. Kulatilaka and E. C. Perotti, Strategic Growth Option, Management Science, 44(8), (998), 0-03. [5] P. D. Childs and A. J. Triantis, Dynamic R&D Investment Policies, Management Science, 45(0), (999), 359-377.

Valuation of Exit Strategy under Decaying Abandonment Value 39 Appendix This Appendix derives the expected value of operating profit. We assume market condition at time T, θ T, follows a lognormal distribution. The natural logarithm of θ T has a normal distribution with E(lnθ T ) = lnθ 0 + (μ σ ) T and Var(lnθ T ) = σ T. Then E(π T θ 0 ) = [ (θ T v) ] prob[θ 4 T θ (T) θ 0 ] + Fe ρt prob[θ T < θ (T) θ 0 ] = [ (θ T v) Fe ρt ] prob[θ 4 T θ (T) θ 0 ] + Fe ρt = 4 (θ T) [lnθ T E(lnθ T )] πtσ e σ T d(lnθ T ) v θ T + ( v 4 Fe ρt ) [lnθ T E(lnθ T )] πtσ e σ T d(lnθ T ) πtσ e [lnθ T E(lnθ T )] σ T d(lnθ T ) + Fe ρt Let (θ T ) = e lnθ T, θ T = e lnθ T and substitute E(lnθ T ) = lnθ 0 + (μ σ ) T into the equation E(π T θ 0 ) = 4 πtσ e v πtσ e + ( v 4 Fe ρt ) + Fe ρt = 4 (θ 0) e (μ σ )T+σ T v θ 0e (μ σ )T+ σt + ( v 4 Fe ρt ) {lnθ T [lnθ 0 +(μ σ )T]} 4σ Tlnθ T σ T d(lnθ T ) {lnθ T [lnθ 0 +(μ σ )T]} σ Tlnθ T πtσ e πtσ e πtσ e πtσ e σ T d(lnθ T ) {lnθ T [lnθ 0 +(μ σ )T]} σ T d(lnθ T ) {lnθ T [lnθ 0 +(μ σ )T+σ T]} {lnθ T [lnθ 0 +(μ σ )T+σ T]} {lnθ T [lnθ 0 +(μ σ )T]} σ T d(lnθ T ) σ T d(lnθ T ) σ T d(lnθ T ) + Fe ρt We change the original probability functions with new expectation value and standardize the new probability functions. In the standard normal distribution, prob(z Z a ) = prob(z Z a ).

40 Ming-Long Wang and Chien-Chih Peng where E(π T θ 0 ) = 4 (θ 0) e (μ σ )T+σ T Z π e dz v θ 0e (μ σ )T+ σt d Z π e dz + ( v d 3 4 Z Fe ρt ) π e dz + Fe ρt = 4 (θ 0) e (μ+ σ )T N(d ) v (θ 0)e μt N(d ) + ( v 4 Fe ρt ) N(d 3 ) + Fe ρt d = lnθ (T) + [lnθ 0 + (μ σ ) T + σ T] σ T d = lnθ (T) + [lnθ 0 + (μ σ ) T + σ T] σ T d 3 = lnθ (T) + [lnθ 0 + (μ σ ) T] σ T = d = = ln [ θ 0 θ (T) ] + (μ + 3 σ ) T σ T ln [ θ 0 θ (T) ] + (μ + σ ) T σ T ln [ θ 0 θ (T) ] + (μ σ ) T σ T We extend the restriction to that there is another abandonment opportunity before terminal. The solution must be derived from time T to time t. E(π t θ 0 ) = e r(t t ) E(π T θ t )prob[θ t θ (t ) θ 0 ] + Fe ρt prob[θ t < θ (t ) θ 0 ] = e r(t t) E(π T θ t )prob[θ t θ (t ) θ 0 ] + Fe ρt { prob[θ t θ (t ) θ 0 ]} = e r(t t) {[ (θ T v) Fe ρt ] prob[θ 4 T θ (T) θ t ]prob[θ t θ (t ) θ 0 ] + Fe ρt prob[θ t θ (t ) θ 0 ]} Fe ρt prob[θ t θ (t ) θ 0 ] + Fe ρt = e r(t t ) [lnθ 4 (θ T E(lnθ t t θ 0 )] [lnθ T E(lnθ T θ t )] ) lnθ (t ) πt σ e σ t d(lnθ t ) π(t t )σ e σ (T t ) d(lnθ T ) e r(t t ) v [lnθ (θ t E(lnθ t )] [lnθ T E(lnθ T )] T) lnθ (t ) πt σ e σ t d(lnθ t ) π(t t )σ e σ (T t ) d(lnθ T ) +e r(t t ) [ v 4 Fe ρt ] lnθ (t ) πt σ e [lnθ t E(lnθ t )] +[e r(t t ) Fe ρt Fe ρt ] σ t d(lnθ t ) lnθ (t ) πt σ e π(t t )σ e [lnθ t E(lnθ t )] [lnθ T E(lnθ T )] σ (T t ) d(lnθ T ) σ t d(lnθ t ) + Fe ρt = 4 e r(t t ) [lnθ t E(lnθ t θ 0 )] [lnθ T E(lnθ T θ t )] +4σ (T t )lnθ t πt σ e σ t d(lnθ t ) lnθ (t ) π(t t )σ e σ (T t ) d(lnθ T ) lnθ (t )

Valuation of Exit Strategy under Decaying Abandonment Value 4 e r(t t ) v lnθ (t ) +e r(t t ) [ v 4 Fe ρt ] lnθ (t ) (θ T) πt σ e πt σ e [lnθ t E(lnθ t )] σ t [lnθ t E(lnθ t )] +[e r(t t ) Fe ρt Fe ρt ] d(lnθ t ) lnθ (t ) σ t d(lnθ t ) lnθ (t ) π(t t )σ e πt σ e π(t t )σ e [lnθ t E(lnθ t )] [lnθ T E(lnθ T )] +σ (T t )lnθ t σ (T t ) d(lnθ T ) [lnθ T E(lnθ T )] σ (T t ) d(lnθ T ) σ t d(lnθ t ) + Fe ρt = 4 e r(t t )+(μ σ )(T t )+σ (T t ) [lnθ E(lnθ t t θ 0 )] a πt σ e σ t d(lnθ t )(θ t ) x lnθ (t ) π e σ dx v e r(t t )+(μ σ )(T t )+ σ (T t ) [lnθ t E(lnθ t )] b πt σ e σ t d(lnθ t )( θ t ) y lnθ (t ) π e σ dy c z c +e r(t t ) [ v 4 Fe ρt ] π e σ dz +[e r(t t ) c Fe ρt Fe ρt ] π e z σ dz π e z σ dz + Fe ρt = 4 (θ 0) e r(t t )+(μ σ )(T t )+σ (T t )+(μ σ )t +σ a t x a π e σ t d(x ) π e v (θ 0)e r(t t )+(μ σ )(T t )+ σ (T t )+(μ σ )t + b σ t y b π e σ t d(y ) π e +e r(t t ) [ v 4 Fe ρt ] ( c c c +[e r(t t ) Fe ρt Fe ρt ] π ) e π e z e z dz dz z σ dz + Fe ρt The expected operating profit function can be simplified to the following: E(π t θ 0 ) = 4 (θ 0) e (μ+ σ )T r(t t ) (π) e (x ) a v (θ 0)e μt r(t t) (π) e (y ) b b c +e r(t t) [ v 4 Fe ρt ] (π) e c c a e (y ) dy dy (z ) e (z ) dz dz +[Fe (ρ+r)t+rt Fe ρt ] (π) e (z ) dz + Fe ρt e (x ) dx dx where x = lnθ t [lnθ 0 + (μ + 3 σ )t ], x σ t = lnθ 3 T [lnθ t + (μ + σ )(T t )] σ T t y = lnθ t [lnθ 0 + (μ + σ )t ], y σ t = lnθ T [lnθ t + (μ + σ )(T t )] σ T t x σ dx y σ dy

4 Ming-Long Wang and Chien-Chih Peng z = lnθ t [lnθ 0 + (μ σ )t ] σ t ln [ a = ln [ b = ln [ c = θ 0 θ (t ) ] + (μ + 3 σ )t σ t, a = θ 0 θ (t ) ] + (μ + σ )t σ t, b = θ 0 θ (t ) ] + (μ σ )t σ t, c =, z = lnθ T [lnθ t + (μ σ )(T t )] σ T t ln [ θ t θ (T) ] + (μ + 3 σ )(T t ) σ T t ln [ θ t θ (T) ] + (μ + σ )(T t ) σ T t ln [ θ t θ (T) ] + (μ σ )(T t ) σ T t