Does sovereign debt weaken economic growth? A Panel VAR analysis.

Similar documents
The other half of the public debt economic growth relationship: a note on Reinhart and Rogoff

A Graphical Analysis of Causality in the Reinhart-Rogoff Dataset

Optimal fiscal policy

Debt Financing and Real Output Growth: Is There a Threshold Effect?

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

The Bilateral J-Curve: Sweden versus her 17 Major Trading Partners

Sovereign debt crisis and economic growth: new evidence for the euro area

Empirical appendix of Public Expenditure Distribution, Voting, and Growth

The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic Activity the Case of the EU- 15

INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC STUDIES

Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation?

Reassessing the fiscal multiplier

From structural breaks to regime switching: the nonlinearity in the process of income inequality

The 90% Public Debt Threshold: The Rise & Fall of a Stylised Fact. By: Balazs Egert

Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries. Abstract

A prolonged period of low real interest rates? 1

Supplemental Technical Critique of Reinhart and Rogoff, Growth in a Time of Debt

Government spending in a model where debt effects output gap

Conditional convergence: how long is the long-run? Paul Ormerod. Volterra Consulting. April Abstract

University of Macedonia Department of Economics. Discussion Paper Series. Inflation, inflation uncertainty and growth: are they related?

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU

The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock

THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON EMERGING ECONOMIES. A TVP-VAR APPROACH

Testing for a Debt-Threshold Effect on Output Growth

Sovereign Debt and Economic Growth in the European Monetary Union

IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY

The Modigliani Puzzle Revisited: A Note

Workshop on resilience

PUBLIC DEBT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

External debt statistics of the euro area

International Income Smoothing and Foreign Asset Holdings.

The Velocity of Money and Nominal Interest Rates: Evidence from Developed and Latin-American Countries

School of Economics and Management

Unemployment and Labour Force Participation in Italy

Cyclical Convergence and Divergence in the Euro Area

Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to 0.4% in the third quarter of 2016

San Francisco Retiree Health Care Trust Fund Education Materials on Public Equity

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

Modelling and predicting labor force productivity

Household Balance Sheets and Debt an International Country Study

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Economics 134 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Spring 2018 Professor Christina Romer LECTURE 24

Effectiveness and Transmission of the ECB s Balance Sheet Policies

Web Appendix. Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? Olivier Coibion

Testing the Stability of Demand for Money in Tonga

DETERMINANT FACTORS OF FDI IN DEVELOPED AND DEVELOPING COUNTRIES IN THE E.U.

EFFECT OF GENERAL UNCERTAINTY ON EARLY AND LATE VENTURE- CAPITAL INVESTMENTS: A CROSS-COUNTRY STUDY. Rajeev K. Goel* Illinois State University

Budgetary Decomposition and Yield Spreads

Long-run Stability of Demand for Money in China with Consideration of Bilateral Currency Substitution

The Debt-to-GDP Threshold Effect On Output: A Country- Specific Analysis

Nonlinear Dependence between Stock and Real Estate Markets in China

Impact of US financial crisis on different countries: based on the method of functional analysis of variance

Fiscal policy in Europe: What is the appropriate stance?

Jesús Crespo-Cuaresma Vienna University of Economics and Business. Octavio Fernández-Amador Johannes Kepler University Linz

The relationship amongst public debt and economic growth in developing country case of Tunisia

Investigating the Intertemporal Risk-Return Relation in International. Stock Markets with the Component GARCH Model

Sovereign Bond Yield Spreads: An International Analysis Giuseppe Corvasce

ARE LEISURE AND WORK PRODUCTIVITY CORRELATED? A MACROECONOMIC INVESTIGATION

Does High Public Debt Consistently Stifle Economic Growth? A Critique of Reinhart and Rogoff

CARRY TRADE: THE GAINS OF DIVERSIFICATION

When Credit Bites Back: Leverage, Business Cycles, and Crises

Austerity, Inequality, and Private Debt Overhang

Constraints on Exchange Rate Flexibility in Transition Economies: a Meta-Regression Analysis of Exchange Rate Pass-Through

Fiscal Reaction Functions of Different Euro Area Countries

This DataWatch provides current information on health spending

Does the Confidence Fairy Exist?

The Effects of Fiscal Policy: Evidence from Italy

Macroeconomic Shocks and the Fiscal Stance within the EU: A Panel Regression Analysis

Exchange Rates and Inflation in EMU Countries: Preliminary Empirical Evidence 1

How Wealthy Are Europeans?

Gernot Müller (University of Bonn, CEPR, and Ifo)

Economic consequences of high public debt and lessons learned from past episodes

WHAT DOES THE HOUSE PRICE-TO-

/JordanStrategyForumJSF Jordan Strategy Forum. Amman, Jordan T: F:

FINANCIAL SYSTEMS, THE BRICS AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE. EEA-NYC February 27, 2015

8-Jun-06 Personal Income Top Marginal Tax Rate,

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow,

Burden of Taxation: International Comparisons

The relationship between the government debt and GDP growth: evidence of the Euro area countries

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

Insolvency forecasts. Economic Research August 2017

Consumption, Income and Wealth

EMPLOYMENT RATE IN EU-COUNTRIES 2000 Employed/Working age population (15-64 years)

Demographics and Secular Stagnation Hypothesis in Europe

The Effects of Oil Shocks on Turkish Macroeconomic Aggregates

Identifying Banking Crises

Okun s law revisited. Is there structural unemployment in developed countries?

Fiscal devaluation and Economic Activity in the EU

Internet Appendix to accompany Currency Momentum Strategies. by Lukas Menkhoff Lucio Sarno Maik Schmeling Andreas Schrimpf

A Threshold Multivariate Model to Explain Fiscal Multipliers with Government Debt

THE TAXES IMPACT ON THE ECONOMIC GROWTH: THE CASE OF EUROPEAN UNION

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

DOES MONEY GRANGER CAUSE INFLATION IN THE EURO AREA?*

Growth Rate of Domestic Credit and Output: Evidence of the Asymmetric Relationship between Japan and the United States

ON THE LONG-TERM MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SOCIAL SPENDING IN THE UNITED STATES (*) Alfredo Marvão Pereira The College of William and Mary

A Regime-Based Effect of Fiscal Policy

Transmission of Financial and Real Shocks in the Global Economy Using the GVAR

Uncertainty and the Transmission of Fiscal Policy

Learning Goal. To develop an understanding of the Millennium Development Goal targets

Financial Crisis What do we know?

Debt Sustainability. JURAJ SIPKO City University, VŠM, Bratislava

Transcription:

MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Does sovereign debt weaken economic growth? A Panel VAR analysis. Matthijs Lof and Tuomas Malinen University of Helsinki, HECER October 213 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/5239/ MPRA Paper No. 5239, posted 7. December 213 14:53 UTC

Does sovereign debt weaken economic growth? A Panel VAR analysis. Matthijs Lof Tuomas Malinen University of Helsinki, Helsinki Center of Economic Research, Arkadiankatu 7, FI-14 Helsinki, Finland October 213 Abstract We estimate a panel vector autoregressive model to analyze the highly disputed relationship between debt and growth. While several studies indicate that high levels of sovereign debt hamper the growth prospects of a country, our results question this. Using data on 2 developed countries, we find no evidence for a robust effect on debt to growth, even for higher levels of sovereign debt. We do find a significant negative reverse effect of growth to debt, which explains the negative correlation. JEL classification: H63, O43, C33 Keywords: Public debt, debt share, GDP growth Corresponding author. Tel.: +358-5-318-2261. Email adresses: matthijs.lof@helsinki.fi, tuomas.malinen@helsinki.fi. 1

1 Introduction Since the outbreak of the financial turmoil in 27 and the subsequent sovereign debt crisis in the euro area, the relationship between sovereign debt and economic growth has been at the heart of the economic policy debate. In an influential article, Reinhart and Rogoff (21) document a historically negative correlation between the level of sovereign debt and economic growth, and argue that countries face a dramatic decline to their growth potential when their debt-to-gdp ratio reaches 9 percent. Herndon et al. (213) uncover a number of computational errors in the results of Reinhart and Rogoff (21). Although an observed negative correlation between debt and growth remains, Herndon et al. (213) challenge the robustness of a 9 percent threshold. In addition, it is not clear that the correlation implies causation. Does high debt lead to low growth, or does low growth lead to high debt? In an attempt to decompose cause and effect, we estimate panel vector autoregressions (PVAR) that describe the dynamic relation between sovereign debt and economic growth, using data on debt and GDP for a panel of 2 developed countries ranging from the beginning of the 2th century. With both debt and GDP treated as endogenous, the PVAR allows us to estimate both the effect of debt on growth, as well as the reverse effect of growth on debt. We find that that the negative correlation between the variables is primarily driven by the impact of growth on debt rather than vice versa. We find that an increase in growth has a negative effect on debt, which makes sense given that government expenditure is in general counter-cyclical, while government revenue is pro-cyclical. When controlling for this negative effect, we find no evidence for a significant long-run reverse impact of debt on growth. Results also indicate that the dynamics of debt and growth are 2

remarkably similar across different subsamples and periods. Previous studies have also addressed the endogeneity problem in the relationship between debt and growth. For example, Baum et al. (213) and Checherita- Westphal and Rother (212) apply instrumental variables to identify the effect of debt on growth for euro area countries, while Minea and Parent (212) use endogenous threshold estimation methods. These studies find that at low debt levels, deficit spending can have a positive impact on growth, which disappears or turns negative for higher levels of debt. The estimated turning points in the debt-to- GDP ratio vary substantially, with estimates ranging between 6 and 115 percent. What these studies have in common is that they aim to find the short-run elasticity of growth with respect to debt in different debt thresholds. Although this is certainly an important question, we are more interested in the long-run effects of debt on growth. A dynamic model like a VAR is a suitable choice for estimating such long-run effects. After modeling debt and GDP as a bivariate dynamic process, we produce impulse-response plots that visualize the path of both debt and GDP for ten years after a shock hits either of these two variables. The shocks are identified recursively. 2 Data and methodology From the dataset of Reinhart and Rogoff (29) we obtain data on gross government debt. Data on real GDP per capita comes from the Maddison database of the Groningen Growth and Development Centre. Our dataset comprises annual data on 2 developed countries, over the period 1954-28. For a smaller subset of 1 countries, we are able to extend the length of the time-series, to the period 195-28. These countries are listed in Table 1. The table also marks those countries for which the average debt-to-gdp ratio over the period 1954-28 ex- 3

ceeds 5 percent and for which the maximum debt-to-gdp ratio over the period 1954-28 exceeds 9 percent. These subsets will be used in section 3 to compare the results for different subsamples classified by the degree of indebtedness. To analyze the dynamic relationship between debt and GDP, we compute impulse-response functions from an estimated Panel VAR (PVAR), in a similar manner as Lof et al. (213) assess the relationship between aid and GDP in developing countries. Using the growth rates (log-differences) of real GDP per capita ( Y) and the growth rate of total gross government debt per capita ( D) as our variables of interest, we estimate the following PVAR: y it = µ i + Ay it 1 + ε it, (1) in which y it = ( D it, Y it ), µ i is a 2 1 country-specific intercept term (fixed effect), A is a 2 2 coefficient matrix and ε it is a 2 1 residual term. The subscripts i and t denote country and year, respectively. The VAR includes only first-order lags, which is selected using the Bayesian Information Criterion (BIC). Before estimating the PVAR, we apply first-differencing, such that the fixed effect µ i drops out of the model. Afterwards, we estimate the differenced model by GMM, while applying lagged values as instruments. This is a standard procedure for estimating dynamic models with panel data, since the standard fixed-effects estimator is in general inconsistent for such models (Nickel 1981). The resulting estimate of A is used to compute the impulse-response functions. Confidence intervals for the impulse-response functions are computed by bootstrap simulation, see Lof et al. (213) for details. To identify the shocks, we impose a recursive structure, which makes the order of the variables relevant. We follow Caldara and Kamps (28), who note that because of the delay between political decision making and actual government spending, fiscal policy may have an instantaneous effect on GDP, while the 4

reverse effect can only occur after a lag. We therefore place debt before GDP. As a robustness check, however, we will also consider the VAR in the reverse recursive order. In this case, it turns out that the imposed order has no substantial effect on the estimated long-run impulse-responses. 3 Results Figure 1 depicts the impulse-response functions derived from the estimated VAR (Eq. 1). The figure shows the impact on debt (left column) and GDP (right column) for a period of ten years after a positive shock to either debt (top row) or GDP (bottom row). Both debt and GDP are measured in per capita terms and are transformed to growth rates by log-differencing. From the diagonal panels (top left and bottom right) it appears that shocks to both growth rates of debt and GDP are transitory: The effects of a shock die out within a couple of years, with shocks to GDP (bottom-right) being clearly less persistent than shocks to debt (top-left). The off-diagonal panels show the impact on debt, after a shock to GDP (bottomleft) and the reverse impact on growth, after a shock to debt (top-right), which is of our main interest. The top-right impulse response shows no evidence for any significant effect of debt on GDP growth. A positive shock to GDP growth does however have a significant negative effect on debt (bottom left), which persists for about three years, after which the effect dies out. Based on these figures, it seems the negative correlation between debt and GDP therefore results from the negative impact of GDP growth on debt, rather than the negative impact of debt on GDP growth. The same results apply when we look at the levels instead of differences. Figure 2 depicts the cumulative impulse response functions from the VAR. By cumulating the impact over time, these plots show the effect on the levels, rather than 5

on the differences of debt and GDP (both in logs). Although the plots look different from Figure 1, the interpretation is the same. The top-left panel shows that after a shock to debt, debt starts to accumulate for a couple of years, after which the level of debt stabilizes. This shock to debt has no significant impact on GDP (top-right). After a shock hits GDP, however, we can clearly see a negative impact on the level of debt (bottom-left). GDP itself stabilizes nearly immediately at the new level (bottom-right). In Figure 3, we display the cumulative impulse response functions from four alternative PVAR specifications. Compared to Figure 2, we display only the offdiagonal panels, showing the dynamic effects of debt on growth (top) and vice versa (bottom). First we consider the VAR with debt and GDP measured in aggregate terms, rather than per capita (Figure 3.A). Next, we replace the level of debt with the debt-to-gdp ratio (Figure 3.B). For Figure 3.C the recursive order is reversed, such that GDP is placed before debt. Finally, in Figure 3.D, we consider a subset of 1 countries (listed in Table 1), for which the VAR is estimated using a longer time-series that spans from 195 to 28. Overall, the results in Figure 3 seem highly similar to those presented in Figure 2. The long-run effect of debt on GDP is found to be insignificant for all four alternatives. Growth is found to have a negative effect on debt. The only exception is Figure 3.B, where a GDP shock seems to have no clear effect on the debt-to-gdp ratio. However, considering a structural shock that hits GDP but not the debt-to-gdp ratio is actually paradoxical, given that these variables are by construction so intertwined. A recursive VAR is therefore arguably not a suitable tool in this particular case. Finally, Figure 4 reproduces the off-diagonal panels of Figure 2, for four different subsamples (listed in Table 1). Figure 4.A is produced using only the data on 9 high-debt countries, for which the average debt-to-gdp ratio during the pe- 6

riod 1954-28 is higher than 5%. The remaining 11 countries are used for figure 4.B. Next we look at 7 countries for which the maximum debt-to-gdp ratio recorded during the period 1954-28 exceeds 9%, which is the threshold reported by Reinhart and Rogoff (21). The remaining 13 countries are used for figure 4.D. Like in the previous figures, we find no significant long-term impact of debt on GDP. Regarding the reverse impact of GDP on debt, we find either negative or insignificant effects. In general, the reported confidence bounds are wider than in the previous figures, presumably due to the smaller sample sizes. The overall picture from Figures 1-4 is clear: We find no significant long-run effect of sovereign debt on economic growth. This result is robust to alternative VAR specifications and to alternative samples. 4 Conclusion High levels of sovereign debt are surely a burden to a country, but does it hamper the macroeconomic performance in the longer run? According to our results, the effect of debt on growth is ambiguous, at best. We find no statistically significant long-run effect on debt to economic growth, for any elevated level of debt. GDP per capita growth, on the other hand, is found to have a statistically significant negative effect on sovereign debt. This implies that the negative correlation between sovereign debt and GDP growth is mainly driven by the negative effect of economic growth on sovereign debt. Our results are in line with Kimball and Wang (213), who claim in a recent blog post not to find "even a shred of evidence in the Reinhart and Rogoff data for a negative effect of government debt on growth". We have chosen a rather simple model for growth and debt, in which the variables are treated as a bivariate process that is rather homogeneous across countries. 7

Although this method is useful for decomposing the correlation, it is not very informative about the economic channels through which debt and GDP affect each other. Moreover, due to the recursive structure, the VAR is not well equipped to estimate short-run effects. Directions for future research on the on the relationship between debt and growth should therefore include multiple variables to uncover these structural channels, which could also address possible omitted-variable biases. Regardless of these issues, the results of this paper make clear that when estimating the long-run effect of sovereign debt on growth, it is important to control for the reverse effect of growth on debt. Acknowledgements We gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Academy of Finland (Lof), and from the OP-Pohjola Group s Research Foundation (Malinen). References Baum A., Checherita-Westphal, C., Rother, P. (213). Debt and growth: new evidence for the euro area. Journal of International Money and Finance, 32, 89 821. Caldara, D., Kamps, C. (28). What are the effects of fiscal policy shocks? A VAR-based comparative analysis. European Central Bank working paper no 877. Checrita-Westphal C., Rother, P. (212). The impact of high government debt on economic growth and its channels: an empirical investigation for the euro area. European Economic Review, 56, 1392 145. Herndon, T., Ash, M., Pollin, R. (213). Does high public debt consistently sti- 8

fle economic growth?: A critique of Reinhart and Rogoff. Political Economy Research Institute. Kimball, M., Wang, Y. (213). After crunching the Reinhart and Rogoff s data, we ve concluded that high debt does not slow growth. Quartz blog, May 29, 213. http://qz.com/88781/after-crunching-reinhart-and-rogoffs-data-weveconcluded-that-high-debt-does-not-cause-low-growth/. Lof, M., Mekasha, T., Tarp, F. (213). Aid and Income. Another time series perspective. WIDER working paper no. 213/69. Minea, A., Parent, A. (212). Is high public debt always harmful to economic growth? Reinhart and Rogoff and some complex nonlinearities. CERDI working paper no 21218. Nickel, S. (1981). Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects. Econometrica, 49(6): 1417-1426. Reinhart C. M., Rogoff, K. S. (21). Growth in a time of debt. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 1, 573 578. Reinhart C. M., Rogoff, K. S. (29). This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. New Jersey: Princeton University Press. 9

Table 1: Country list Country 1954-28 195-28 av. debt >5% max. debt >9% Australia x x - - Austria x - - - Belgium x - x x Canada x x x - Denmark x x - - Finland x x - - France x - - - Germany x - - - Greece x - x x Ireland x - x x Italy x x x x Japan x - x x Netherlands x - x x New Zealand x x - - Norway x - - - Portugal x x - - Spain x - - - Sweden x x - - UK x x x x USA x x x - Notes: First column marks the countries for which time-series for 1954-28 are available (N=2, T=55). Second column marks the countries for which time-series for 195-28 are available (N=1, T=14). Third column marks the countries for which the average debt-to-gdp ratio during the period 1954-28 exceeds 5% (N=9). Fourth column marks the countries for which the maximum debt-to-gdp ratio during the period 1954-28 exceeds 9% (N=7). 1

1,5 D D,6 D Y 1,3,5 -,5 -,3,5 Y D 1,5 Y Y 1 -,5,5-1 -1,5 -,5 Figure 1: Impulse-response functions computed from estimated PVAR (Eq. 1), for 2 countries (See Table 1) over the period 1954-28. 95% confidence bounds are based on 1, bootstrap simulations. 8 D D,4 D Y 6,2 4 2 -,2 1,4 Y Y -2 1,2 1-4,8 Y D -6,6 Figure 2: Cumulative impulse-response functions. See Figure 1. 11

A B C D Figure 3: Cumulative impulse-response functions (See Figure 2) for alternative VAR specifications. (A) Debt and GDP measured in aggregate terms instead of per capita. (B) Debt measured as Debt-to-GDP ratio. (C) Recursive order reversed. (D) Sub-sample of 1 countries (See Table 1) with longer time-series (195-28). A B C D Figure 4: Cumulative impulse-response functions (See Figure 2) for different subsamples (See Table 1). (A) Av. Debt-to-GDP ratio>5% (N=9). (B) Av. Debt-to-GDP ratio<5% (N=11). (C) Max. Debt-to-GDP ratio>9% (N=7). (D) Max. Debt-to-GDP ratio<9% (N=13). 12