Chapter 14 Exotic Options: I

Similar documents
Chapter 14. Exotic Options: I. Question Question Question Question The geometric averages for stocks will always be lower.

1. In this exercise, we can easily employ the equations (13.66) (13.70), (13.79) (13.80) and

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Homework Assignments

MATH 476/567 ACTUARIAL RISK THEORY FALL 2016 PROFESSOR WANG

B8.3 Week 2 summary 2018

Chapter 9 - Mechanics of Options Markets

Valuation of Options: Theory

Chapter 24 Interest Rate Models

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

Hull, Options, Futures & Other Derivatives Exotic Options

CHAPTER 10 OPTION PRICING - II. Derivatives and Risk Management By Rajiv Srivastava. Copyright Oxford University Press

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

LECTURE 12. Volatility is the question on the B/S which assumes constant SD throughout the exercise period - The time series of implied volatility

15 American. Option Pricing. Answers to Questions and Problems

Options Markets: Introduction

Derivative Instruments

Appendix: Basics of Options and Option Pricing Option Payoffs

Name: MULTIPLE CHOICE. 1 (5) a b c d e. 2 (5) a b c d e TRUE/FALSE 1 (2) TRUE FALSE. 3 (5) a b c d e 2 (2) TRUE FALSE.

FNCE 302, Investments H Guy Williams, 2008

B. Combinations. 1. Synthetic Call (Put-Call Parity). 2. Writing a Covered Call. 3. Straddle, Strangle. 4. Spreads (Bull, Bear, Butterfly).

non linear Payoffs Markus K. Brunnermeier

Econ 174 Financial Insurance Fall 2000 Allan Timmermann. Final Exam. Please answer all four questions. Each question carries 25% of the total grade.

CHAPTER 20 Spotting and Valuing Options

MATH 476/567 ACTUARIAL RISK THEORY FALL 2016 PROFESSOR WANG. Homework 3 Solution

Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13

CHAPTER 17 OPTIONS AND CORPORATE FINANCE

Put-Call Parity. Put-Call Parity. P = S + V p V c. P = S + max{e S, 0} max{s E, 0} P = S + E S = E P = S S + E = E P = E. S + V p V c = (1/(1+r) t )E

Final Exam. Please answer all four questions. Each question carries 25% of the total grade.

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Spring 2018 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Fixed Income and Risk Management

Solutions of Exercises on Black Scholes model and pricing financial derivatives MQF: ACTU. 468 S you can also use d 2 = d 1 σ T

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher)

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING

Actuarial Models : Financial Economics

Cash Flows on Options strike or exercise price

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

A&J Flashcards for Exam MFE/3F Spring Alvin Soh

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO. Faculty of Mathematics and Natural Sciences

MFE/3F Questions Answer Key

Option Pricing. Simple Arbitrage Relations. Payoffs to Call and Put Options. Black-Scholes Model. Put-Call Parity. Implied Volatility

MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS

Option Properties Liuren Wu

Two Types of Options

JEM034 Corporate Finance Winter Semester 2017/2018

The Black-Scholes Model

MFE/3F Questions Answer Key

OPTIONS & GREEKS. Study notes. An option results in the right (but not the obligation) to buy or sell an asset, at a predetermined

REAL OPTIONS ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

TRUE/FALSE 1 (2) TRUE FALSE 2 (2) TRUE FALSE. MULTIPLE CHOICE 1 (5) a b c d e 3 (2) TRUE FALSE 4 (2) TRUE FALSE. 2 (5) a b c d e 5 (2) TRUE FALSE

Lattice Model of System Evolution. Outline

Errata and updates for ASM Exam MFE/3F (Ninth Edition) sorted by page.

Barrier Option Valuation with Binomial Model

Notes: This is a closed book and closed notes exam. The maximal score on this exam is 100 points. Time: 75 minutes

Valuing Put Options with Put-Call Parity S + P C = [X/(1+r f ) t ] + [D P /(1+r f ) t ] CFA Examination DERIVATIVES OPTIONS Page 1 of 6

Rho and Delta. Paul Hollingsworth January 29, Introduction 1. 2 Zero coupon bond 1. 3 FX forward 2. 5 Rho (ρ) 4. 7 Time bucketing 6

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 2 Solutions

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

MULTIPLE CHOICE. 1 (5) a b c d e. 2 (5) a b c d e TRUE/FALSE 1 (2) TRUE FALSE. 3 (5) a b c d e 2 (2) TRUE FALSE. 4 (5) a b c d e 3 (2) TRUE FALSE

Forwards, Futures, Options and Swaps

IAPM June 2012 Second Semester Solutions

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

UNIVERSITY OF AGDER EXAM. Faculty of Economicsand Social Sciences. Exam code: Exam name: Date: Time: Number of pages: Number of problems: Enclosure:

Errata, Mahler Study Aids for Exam 3/M, Spring 2010 HCM, 1/26/13 Page 1

Chapter 18 Volatility Smiles

Financial Markets & Risk

FX Options. Outline. Part I. Chapter 1: basic FX options, standard terminology, mechanics

P-7. Table of Contents. Module 1: Introductory Derivatives

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

S 0 C (30, 0.5) + P (30, 0.5) e rt 30 = PV (dividends) PV (dividends) = = $0.944.

K = 1 = -1. = 0 C P = 0 0 K Asset Price (S) 0 K Asset Price (S) Out of $ In the $ - In the $ Out of the $

ECON4510 Finance Theory Lecture 10

Math 181 Lecture 15 Hedging and the Greeks (Chap. 14, Hull)

Economic Risk and Decision Analysis for Oil and Gas Industry CE School of Engineering and Technology Asian Institute of Technology

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

In general, the value of any asset is the present value of the expected cash flows on

The Greek Letters Based on Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright John C. Hull 2012

Derivative Securities

MFE/3F Study Manual Sample from Chapter 10

Exotic Options. Chapter 19. Types of Exotics. Packages. Non-Standard American Options. Forward Start Options

Introduction. Financial Economics Slides

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology

Chapter 5. Risk Handling Techniques: Diversification and Hedging. Risk Bearing Institutions. Additional Benefits. Chapter 5 Page 1

2 f. f t S 2. Delta measures the sensitivityof the portfolio value to changes in the price of the underlying

Lecture 4: Barrier Options

Derivatives Analysis & Valuation (Futures)

Exotic Derivatives & Structured Products. Zénó Farkas (MSCI)

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

SOA Exam MFE Solutions: May 2007

A Brief Review of Derivatives Pricing & Hedging

UCLA Anderson School of Management Daniel Andrei, Option Markets 232D, Fall MBA Midterm. November Date:

Lecture 7: Trading Strategies Involve Options ( ) 11.2 Strategies Involving A Single Option and A Stock

MATH4143: Scientific Computations for Finance Applications Final exam Time: 9:00 am - 12:00 noon, April 18, Student Name (print):

CHAPTER 27: OPTION PRICING THEORY

Chapter 17. Options and Corporate Finance. Key Concepts and Skills

B6302 Sample Placement Exam Academic Year

Lattice Model of System Evolution. Outline

Options (2) Class 20 Financial Management,

SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES EXAM IFM INVESTMENT AND FINANCIAL MARKETS EXAM IFM SAMPLE QUESTIONS AND SOLUTIONS DERIVATIVES

Transcription:

Chapter 14 Exotic Options: I Question 14.1. The geometric averages for stocks will always be lower. Question 14.2. The arithmetic average is 5 (three 5 s, one 4, and one 6) and the geometric average is (5 4 5 6 5) 1/5 = 4.9593. For the next sequence, the arithmetic average does not change (= 5); however the geometric average, (3 4 5 6 7) 1/5 = 4.7894 is much lower. As the standard deviation increases (holding arithmetic means constant), the geometric return decreases. As an example, suppose we have two observations, 1 + σ and 1 σ. The arithmetic mean will be 1; however the geometric mean will be (1 + σ)(1 σ) = 1 σ 2 < 1. Question 14.3. Using the forward tree specification, u = exp(.08/2 +.3/ 2) = 1.2868, d = exp(.08/2.3/ 2) =.84187, and risk neutral probability p = (e.08/2 d)/(u d) =.44716. The two possible prices in 6 months are 128.68 and 84.19; the three possible 1 year prices are 165.58, 108.33, and 70.87. a) Using the 6m and 12m prices, the possible arithmetic averages (in 1 year) are 147.13, 118.50, 96.26, and 77.53. The four possible geometric averages are 145.97, 118.07, 95.50, and 77.24. b) Since we are averaging the 6m and 12m prices, the average tree will be identical for the current node and the two 6m nodes; however, the 12m node will have the four nodes given in the previous answer. c) With K = 100 the up-up value is 47.1266 and the up-down value is 18.5026. There is no value in the bottom half of the tree. This gives an up value of e.04 (p47.1266 + (1 p) 18.5026) = 30.075 and an initial value of e.04 p30.075 = 12.921. d) Similarly, up value is e.04 (p45.9652 + (1 p) 18.0651) = 29.344 and an initial value of e.04 p29.344 = 12.607. Question 14.4. Using the forward tree specification, u = exp(.08/2 +.3/ 2) = 1.2868, d = exp(.08/2.3/ 2) =.84187, and risk neutral probability p = (e.08/2 d)/(u d) =.44716. The two possible prices in 6 months are 128.68 and 84.19; the three possible 1 year prices are 165.58, 108.33, and 70.87. 199

Part 3 Options Using the 6m and 12m prices, the possible arithmetic averages are (in 1 year) are 147.13, 118.50, 96.26, and 77.53. The four possible geometric averages are 145.97, 118.07, 95.50, and 77.24. These are in the order: u-u, u-d, d-u, and d-d. a) The four intrinsic values will be 165.58 147.13 = 18.45 (u-u), 0 (u-d), 108.33 96.26 = 12.07 (d-u), and zero (d-d). This will give an up value of e.04 p18.45 = 7.93, a down value of e.04 p12.07 = 5.19, and an initial value of e.04 (p7.93 + (1 p) 5.19) = 6.1602. b) The four intrinsic values will be 165.58 145.97 = 19.61 (u-u), zero (u-d), 108.33 95.50 = 12.83 (d-u), and zero (d-d). This will give an up value of e.04 p19.61 = 8.43 and a down value of e.04 p12.83 = 5.51 with an initial value of e.04 (p8.43 + (1 p) 5.51) = 6.55. Question 14.5. See Table One. Table One (Problem 14.5) Price Average Payoff RN Prob Arith Geo Arith Geo uuu 0.0954 151.1369 149.1442 51.1369 49.1442 uud 0.1134 133.3612 132.8796 33.3612 32.8796 udu 0.1134 118.8058 118.3887 18.8058 18.3887 udd 0.1348 106.2345 105.4781 6.2345 5.4781 duu 0.1134 106.8874 105.4781 6.8874 5.4781 dud 0.1348 94.3160 93.9754 0 0 ddu 0.1348 84.0221 83.7272 0 0 ddd 0.1602 75.1314 74.5965 0 0 Expected RN Payoff 12.4116 11.8580 Discounted 11.4574 10.9463 Question 14.6. a) A standard call is worth 4.1293. b) A knock in call will also be worth 4.1293 (you can verify this with the software). In order for the standard call to ever be in the money, it must pass through the barrier. They therefore give identical payoffs. c) Similar reasoning, implies the knock-out will be worthless since in order for S T > 45, the barrier must have been hit making knocking out the option. 200

Chapter 14 Exotic Options: I Question 14.7. See Table Two for the prices and ratio. The longer the time to expiration, the greater the dispersion of S T. For the standard call option, this unambiguously increases the value (by standard convexity arguments). For the knock-out, there is a trade-off. The higher the dispersion, the greater chance for large payoffs; however, there will also be a higher chance for the barrier to be hit. Table Two (Problem 14.7) T Standard Knock-Out Ratio 0.25 0.9744 0.7323 1.3306 0.5 2.1304 1.2482 1.7067 1 4.1293 1.8217 2.2667 2 7.4398 2.4505 3.0360 3 10.2365 2.8529 3.5881 4 12.6969 3.1559 4.0232 5 14.9010 3.4003 4.3823 100 39.9861 5.3112 7.5286 Question 14.8. See Table Three for the prices and ratio. The longer the time to expiration, the greater the dispersion of S T. For the standard put option, this increases the value unless the option expiration starts to become large (we lose time value of receiving the strike price). For the knock-out, there is an extra negative effect a higher expiration date has. With higher dispersion of S T, the greater chance for larger S T, the greater the chance of being knocked out; however, there will also be a higher chance for the barrier to be hit. Table Three (Problem 14.8) T Standard Knock-Out Ratio 0.25 5.0833 3.8661 1.3148 0.5 5.3659 3.4062 1.5753 1 5.6696 2.8626 1.9806 2 5.7862 2.2233 2.6025 3 5.6347 1.8109 3.1115 4 5.3736 1.5094 3.5601 5 5.0654 1.2761 3.9695 100 0.0012 0.0001 24.4951 Question 14.9. See Table Four on the next page for the values. This highlights the trade-off increasing the time to maturity has on the knock out call option. When time to maturity increases, the standard call has the interest on the strike as well as the higher dispersion of S T making it more valuable. For the knock out call, the likelihood of getting knocked out can offset this effect. 201

Part 3 Options Table Four (Problem 14.9) Months Black-Scholes U & O Call Ratio 1 0.1727 0.1727 1.0003 2 0.5641 0.5479 1.0296 3 0.9744 0.8546 1.1401 4 1.3741 1.0384 1.3233 5 1.7593 1.1243 1.5649 6 2.1304 1.1468 1.8577 7 2.4886 1.1316 2.1991 8 2.8353 1.0954 2.5885 9 3.1718 1.0482 3.0260 10 3.4991 0.9962 3.5124 11 3.8180 0.9430 4.0488 12 4.1293 0.8906 4.6365 Question 14.10. When K = 0.9, the only scenarios where the up and out puts have a different payoff than the standard put is where the exchange rate rises to the barrier of 1 (or 1.05) before six months (i.e. x t > 1 for t<t) and then end below.9 (i.e. x T <.9). In this case, the up and out puts will pay nothing (they will have gotten knocked out) and the standard put will pay the intrinsic value.9 x T. Given the volatility assumption, these scenarios are virtually impossible and, for the small chance that they happen, the payoff in for the standard put would be small. When K = 1 the scenarios mentioned above are much more likely as x only has to rise above 1 (or 1.05) and then finish below 1. With higher time to expirations, the probabilities of such scenarios will become non negligible and we should expect the up and out to have lower values than the standards (when K =.9). Question 14.11. a) 9.61 b) In one year, the option will be worth more than $2 if S 1 > 31.723. c) 7.95 d) If we buy the compound call in part b) and sell the compound option in this question for x we will be receiving the standard call in one year for $2 regardless of S 1. Hence, our total cost is 7.95 x + 2e.08 = 9.61, which implies x =.18623. Without rounding errors it would be.18453. Question 14.12. a) 3.6956 b) In one year, the put option will be worth more than $2 if S 1 < 44.35. c) 2.2978 202

Chapter 14 Exotic Options: I d) If we buy the standard put from part a) as well as this compound option for x we will keep the standard put if S 1 < 44.35 and sell it for $2 otherwise. This identical to putting 2e.08 in the risk free bond and buying the compound option in part c). The total costs must be identical implying 3.6956 + x = 2.2978 + 2e.08, implying x =.448. Question 14.13. a) P (S,K 1,K 2,σ,r,T,δ) = K 1 e rt N ( d 2 ) Se δt N ( d 1 ) where d i are the same as equation (14.15). For foreign currency, δ = r E, S = x, and r = r $. b) A gap put will pay.8 x when x<1. With zero volatility, x = x 0 =.9 and this will mean we will be selling the foreign currency for.8 dollars. This is equivalent to a forward contract with delivery price K 1 =.8, f =.9e.03/2 +.8e.06/2 =.11024. (1) If volatility increases we will have the potential for upside if x can fall; this will be offset only for x rising up to K 2 = 1. If x T > 1, we get the discontinuous jump from losing.2 to having zero liability. This asymmetry should have the gap put becoming more valuable as volatility increases. Figure 1 confirms this. -0.06 Figure 1 (Problem 14.13) -0.07-0.08 Value of Gap Put -0.09-0.1-0.11-0.12 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 0.12 0.14 0.16 σ Question 14.14. Using σ = 30%, r = 8%, and δ = 0. See Figure Two on the next page. When we are close to maturity (e.g. T = 1/52) we see large variations in delta. The discontinuity at K 2 can require 203

Part 3 Options deltas greater than one. The value of the option can go from close to zero to close to $10 with little movement in the price (if S T is close to K 1 ). If T 0, delta will be close zero for S<100, enormous for S = 100, and close to one if S>100. This problem does not occur as T becomes larger. 1.6 Figure 2 (Problem 14.14) 1.4 1.2 Delta of Gap Call 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 T=1/52 T=1/4 T=1 0.2 0 90 92 94 96 98 100 102 104 106 108 110 S Question 14.15. Using σ = 30%, r = 8%, and δ = 0. See Figure Three. For three month and one year gap put 40 35 Figure 3 (Problem 14.15) T = 1/52 T = 1/4 T =1 30 25 Vega of Gap Put 20 15 10 5 0-5 -10 90 92 94 96 98 100 102 104 106 108 110 S 204

Chapter 14 Exotic Options: I options, the option value increases with volatility (the value function is convex in S). When T = 1/52, if S>100 the option loses value with higher volatility due to the increased likelihood of a negative payoff (the value function is concave in S). Question 14.16. Under Black Scholes the standard 40-strike call on S will be BSCall (40, 40,.3,.08, 1, 0). (2) For the exchange option on S using 2/3 of a share of Q as the strike, we use a strike of (2/3) 60 = 40, a volatility of.3 2 +.5 2 2 (.5)(.3)(.5) =.43589, and an interest rate of.04: BSCall (40, 40,.43589,.04, T, 0). (3) For, all but very long time to maturities, the higher volatility will offset the lower interest and the exchange option will be worth more. With T = 1, we have the standard option is worth 6.28 and the exchange option is worth 7.58. Question 14.17. We use 1 year options. a) The price of falls from 2 to 1.22 as we increase the dividend yield of S from 0 to.1. b) The price rises from 2 to 2.86 as we increase the dividend yield of Q from 0 to.1. c) The price falls from 5.79 to 2 as we increase the correlation from.5 to.5. d) Standard arguments for δ. Asδ Q increases, the yield on the strike asset makes delaying our purchase of S more valuable (the same as why a higher r makes standard call options more valuable). As ρ increases the volatility of the difference goes down (in this case from 70% to 43%). Question 14.18. a) Var[ln (S/Q)] =.3 2 +.3 2 2 (.3)(.3) = 0 and the option is worthless (it will never be in the money as S T = Q T ). b) Var[ln (S/Q)] =.3 2 +.4 2 2 (.3)(.4) =.01 hence we use a 10% volatility in Black- Scholes. With T = 1 we have the exchange option equal to $1.60. 205

Part 3 Options c) If ln (S) and ln (Q) are jointly normal with ρ = 1 then they are linearly related. Hence ( ln (Q) = ln (40) 1 σ ) Q + σ Q ln (S). (4) σ S σ S In question a), ln (Q) = ln (S) = Q = S. For question b), ln (40) ln (Q) = + 4 3 3 ln (S) = Q =.2924S4/3. (5) If S rises (say S T = 50) then Q will be greater than S (say Q T = 53.861); the option will be in the money if S falls for Q will fall by a greater amount making the exchange option have value. Question 14.19. XYZ will have a natural hedge when x ($ price of Euro) and S ($ price of oil) move in together. For example, if x rises (the Euro appreciates implies good news for XYZ) and S rises ( bad news for XYZ) the two risks offset. Similarly if x falls and S falls. When the two move opposite, the company is either win-win (x and S ) or lose-lose (S and x ). An exchange option paying S x is therefore natural for XYZ. They will give up upside to hedge against downside. This is likely to be cheaper than treating the two risks separately due to ρ>0 implying the exchange option will have a lower (implied) volatility. Question 14.20. a) Since the options will be expiring at t 1, we have the payoff of a put if S T <Kand the payoff of a call if S T >K. This is equivalent to a K strike straddle. b) Using put-call parity at t 1, the value of the as-you-like-it option at t 1 will be: ( ) max C (S 1,K,T t 1 ),C(S 1,K,T t 1 ) + Ke r(t t1) Se δ(t t 1) (6) ( ) = C (S 1,K,T t 1 ) + max 0,Ke r(t t1) Se δ(t t 1) (7) ( ) = C (S 1,K,T t 1 ) + e δ(t t1) max 0,Ke (δ r)(t t1) S. (8) The first term is the value of a call with strike K and maturity T ; the second term is the payoff from holding e δ(t t 1) put options that expire at t 1 with strike Ke (δ r)(t t 1). Question 14.21. a) In 6 months, a 3 month at-the-money call option will be worth 6.9618 if S = 100, 3.4809 if S = 50, and 13.9237 if S = 200. Note it is always 6.9618% of the stock price. 206

Chapter 14 Exotic Options: I b) In six months (t 1 = 1/2), we will need.069618s T ; this can be done by buying.069618 shares of stock (since there are no dividends). c) We should pay $6.9618 for the forward start (the cost of the shares); this is the same as the current value of a 3m at-the-money option. d) Using similar arguments, a 3m 105% strike is always worth 4.7166% of the stock price. We should then pay $4.7166 for a forward start 105%-strike option. Question 14.22. a) $6.0831 b) The current price of a 1m 95-strike put is 1.2652. In fact, a 1m put with a strike equal to 95% of the stock price will always be equal to 1.2652% of the stock price. Therefore, the present value of twelve of these 1m 95% strike puts is 12 (1.2652) = 15.182. c) Technically, and perhaps non-intuitively, the rolling insurance strategy costs more because it is more expensive to replicate. Note that one strategy doesn t dominate another. If the price never falls less than 5% in month, all of the 12 one month options will be worthless; yet the price in 1 year could have fallen by more than 5%. Interest aside, the rollover options will give the holder 11 i=0 max (S i+1.95s i, 0); whereas, the simple insurance gives the holder max(s 12.95S 0, 0). The rollover strategy has the advantage of being able to provide payoffs (insurance) for each month regardless of the past. If the stock price rises in one month to (say) $120, the simple insurance option will be less effective whereas the rollover will provide a new insurance option with a strike of.95 (120) = 114. 207