Generalized Dynamic Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering the Market Volatility Shocks

Similar documents
Factor Analysis for Volatility - Part II

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference

Chapter 6 Forecasting Volatility using Stochastic Volatility Model

Discussion Paper No. DP 07/05

Macro Risks and the Term Structure

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2017, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Market Microstructure Invariants

Problem Set 4 Answers

Estimation of Volatility of Cross Sectional Data: a Kalman filter approach

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Estimation of dynamic term structure models

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2012, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Noureddine Kouaissah, Sergio Ortobelli, Tomas Tichy University of Bergamo, Italy and VŠB-Technical University of Ostrava, Czech Republic

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

Is the Potential for International Diversification Disappearing? A Dynamic Copula Approach

Financial Risk Forecasting Chapter 3 Multivariate volatility models

Does a Big Bazooka Matter? Central Bank Balance-Sheet Policies and Exchange Rates

ARCH and GARCH models

Dynamic Effects of Credit Shocks in a Data-Rich Environment

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Empirical Test of Affine Stochastic Discount Factor Model of Currency Pricing. Abstract

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors

slides chapter 6 Interest Rate Shocks

Financial Econometrics Notes. Kevin Sheppard University of Oxford

Occasional Paper. Risk Measurement Illiquidity Distortions. Jiaqi Chen and Michael L. Tindall

GRANULARITY ADJUSTMENT FOR DYNAMIC MULTIPLE FACTOR MODELS : SYSTEMATIC VS UNSYSTEMATIC RISKS

Lecture 6: Non Normal Distributions

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns

Reading the Tea Leaves: Model Uncertainty, Robust Foreca. Forecasts, and the Autocorrelation of Analysts Forecast Errors

MFE Macroeconomics Week 3 Exercise

What Can Rational Investors Do About Excessive Volatility and Sentiment Fluctuations?

Oil Price Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy

Applied Macro Finance

Final Exam Suggested Solutions

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

Uncertainty and Economic Activity: A Global Perspective

Volatility Models and Their Applications

Discussion of Trend Inflation in Advanced Economies

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

A Statistical Analysis to Predict Financial Distress

Modelling the Sharpe ratio for investment strategies

Empirical Analysis of the US Swap Curve Gough, O., Juneja, J.A., Nowman, K.B. and Van Dellen, S.

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

Risk control of mean-reversion time in. statistical arbitrage

Informed Trading, Predictable Noise Trading Activities. and Market Manipulation

News Shocks and Asset Price Volatility in a DSGE Model

Dynamic Wrong-Way Risk in CVA Pricing

Stochastic Volatility (SV) Models

Statistical Models and Methods for Financial Markets

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Convex-Cardinality Problems Part II

Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment

Applied Dynamic Factor Modeling In Finance

Option-Implied Correlations, Factor Models, and Market Risk

Testing for Weak Form Efficiency of Stock Markets

Robust Longevity Risk Management

Modeling the extremes of temperature time series. Debbie J. Dupuis Department of Decision Sciences HEC Montréal

Modelling Joint Distribution of Returns. Dr. Sawsan Hilal space

14.461: Technological Change, Lectures 12 and 13 Input-Output Linkages: Implications for Productivity and Volatility

Choice Probabilities. Logit Choice Probabilities Derivation. Choice Probabilities. Basic Econometrics in Transportation.

Course information FN3142 Quantitative finance

Economics 2010c: Lecture 4 Precautionary Savings and Liquidity Constraints

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete

Can 123 Variables Say Something About Inflation in Malaysia?

Equilibrium Asset Pricing: With Non-Gaussian Factors and Exponential Utilities

Factor High-Frequency Based Volatility (HEAVY) Models

Lecture Note 9 of Bus 41914, Spring Multivariate Volatility Models ChicagoBooth

Monetary Economics Final Exam

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

Dynamic Sparsity Modelling

THE REACTION OF THE WIG STOCK MARKET INDEX TO CHANGES IN THE INTEREST RATES ON BANK DEPOSITS

Banca d Italia. Ministero dell Economia e delle Finanze. November Real time forecasts of in ation: the role of.

Conditional Heteroscedasticity

Survival of Hedge Funds : Frailty vs Contagion

Volume 37, Issue 2. Handling Endogeneity in Stochastic Frontier Analysis

How Much Insurance in Bewley Models?

Does Monetary Policy influence Stock Market in India? Or, are the claims exaggerated? Partha Ray

Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed

A Granular Interpretation to Inflation Variations

Risk-Adjusted Capital Allocation and Misallocation

What determines government spending multipliers?

A New Approach to Asset Integration: Methodology and Mystery. Robert P. Flood and Andrew K. Rose

Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data

List of tables List of boxes List of screenshots Preface to the third edition Acknowledgements

LOW FREQUENCY MOVEMENTS IN STOCK PRICES: A STATE SPACE DECOMPOSITION REVISED MAY 2001, FORTHCOMING REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

TOHOKU ECONOMICS RESEARCH GROUP

Variance clustering. Two motivations, volatility clustering, and implied volatility

Long and Short Run Correlation Risk in Stock Returns

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods

What the Cyclical Response of Advertising Reveals about Markups and other Macroeconomic Wedges

Transcription:

Generalized Dynamic Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering the Market Volatility Shocks Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Discussion by: Ross Askanazi March 27, 2015 Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the 27, Market 2015Volatility 1 / Shoc 28

Background This paper is concerned with a fundamental problem in modern time series econometrics: It s hard to estimate large covariance matrices. It s REALLY hard to estimate large time-varying covariance matrices. Key Problem: Dimensionality. Estimating a covariance matrix typically requires n 2 parameters. Estimating a full model of covariance dynamics typically requires n 4 parameters. Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the 27, Market 2015Volatility 2 / Shoc 28

Background Recent successful venture: Fan et al (2013) estimate a large covariance matrix Ω Y of a series Y t by decomposing with Ω xt low rank and Ω ηt sparse. Ω Y = Ω x + Ω η Problem: This decomposition is constructed from a static factor model for levels Y it = b i f t + η it (1) Ω x = bω f b This assumes that the common component of volatilities is precisely the volatility of the level-common component. Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the 27, Market 2015Volatility 3 / Shoc 28

This Paper s Contribution This paper uses the same low rank plus sparse decomposition in a stochastic volatility setting Ω Yt = Ω xt + Ω ηt (2) = bω ft b + Ω ηt Contribution: Uses the observation that the optimal Ω xt for a low rank plus sparse decomposition is not necessarily bω ft b. Approach: Begin with (2), then measure co-movement of the resulting Ω xt = bω ft b and Ω ηt. Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the 27, Market 2015Volatility 4 / Shoc 28

General method Let Y := Y it i 1 : n, t 1 : T be the data of interest. Fit Y it = b i f t + η it Obtain volatily proxies for market component and idiosyncratic component s it and w it Fit factor models to s it and w it separately, then to the panel of both. Difference between number of factors in combined panel and sum of factors in separate panels = number of factors in common. Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the 27, Market 2015Volatility 5 / Shoc 28

Description of Full Method Begin with data Y := Y it i 1 : n, t 1 : T and dynamic factor model with q factors: Y it = X it + Z it = q b ik (L)u kt + Z it k=1 u kt are the market shocks, giving rise to the common component X it. Forni and Lippi (2011) and (2014) show that with mild additional assumptions, there exist a set of block-diagonal filters A n (L) and a full rank constant matrix H such that (I A n (L))Y t = Hu t + (I A n (L))Z t Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the 27, Market 2015Volatility 6 / Shoc 28

Residuals for volatility analysis The above lets us easily obtain residuals for the level-common component: e = {e it } = {(Hu t ) i i 1 : n, t 1 : T }. Since the remainder is idiosyncratic, residuals are obtained by fitting univariate AR regressions, yielding idiosyncratic residuals v it. To conduct volatility analysis, take s it = log(e 2 it ) and w it = log(v 2 it ) as volatility proxies. Assume these proxies are demeaned. We now conduct factor analysis on s it and w it. Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the 27, Market 2015Volatility 7 / Shoc 28

Technical Issue - Factor Structure of Common Volatility Suppose we find 1 factor in the filtered data for the levels (so that u t is scalar). Then s it = log(h 2 i u 2 t ) = 2log(H i ) + 2 log(u t ) After demeaning, we will find a single factor for s it, given by log(u t ). We should not need to estimate factor structure on the volatilities of the common component. We DO need to estimate factor structure on volatility of u ts in the case where there are many factors for the levels. Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the 27, Market 2015Volatility 8 / Shoc 28

Factors of Volatilities As with the levels, we have the decompositions q s s it = χ s;it + ξ s;it = d s;ik (L)ε s;kt + ξ s;it w it = χ w;it + ξ w;it = k=1 q w k=1 d w;ik (L)ε w;kt + ξ w;it Now by construction, ε s;kt and ξ s;it are independent, as with ε w;kt and ξ w;it. But ε s;kt and ε w;kt may not be, as with ξ s;it and ξ w;it, etc, etc. Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the 27, Market 2015Volatility 9 / Shoc 28

Factors of Volatilities Moving forward, we can decompose further: q s s it = d s;ik (L)(φ kt + ψ s;kt ) + (ζ s;it + ξs;it) k=1 q s w it = d w;ik (L)(φ kt + ψ w;kt ) + (ζ w;it + ξs;it) k=1 Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 10 / Shoc 28

Common and Idiosyncratic Volatility Shocks These decompositions give rise to 4 categories: Strongly common: The shocks common to both s and w. Weakly common: The shocks ψ s;kt and ψ w;kt. These are the common shocks of each block not driven by the strongly common shocks. Weakly idiosyncratic: ζ s;it and ζw; it. These are the shocks idiosyncratic to the common shocks of their own block, but not necessarily to the common shocks of the opposite block. Arguably the most nebulous of the four. Strongly idiosyncratic: ξs;it and ξ w;it. These shocks are independent of each other and independent of all market-driven shocks. Essentially iid white noise. Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 11 / Shoc 28

Weakly Idiosyncratic Shocks A useful way to think of the idiosyncratic shocks: We understand φ kt, ψ s;kt and ψ w;kt. Consider { s it = χ s η;it η it = + ξs η;it = Q k=1 d η;ik s (L)ε kt + ξη;it s w it = χ w η;it + ξw η;it = Q k=1 d η;ik w (L)ε kt + ξη;it w Then ξ η s are strongly idiosyncratic by construction, so we conclude: ζ s;it = χ s η;it χ s;it And similarly ζ w;it = χ w η;it χ w;it Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 12 / Shoc 28

A revealing example Suppose Q = q s = q w (as is found to be the case). Then there are no weakly common or weakly idiosyncratic components, just a strongly common shock and strongly idiosyncratic shocks. We may thus write log(e 2 it) = d s;i (L)φ kt + ξ s;it log(v 2 it) = d w;i (L)φ kt + ξ w;it Here φ kt, ξ s;it, and ξ w;it are mutually orthogonal at all leads and lags. This is often the case found in financial empirical work, and is the case found in the empirical section of this paper, but in general need not be. Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 13 / Shoc 28

The S&P100 Panel The above method is applied to a panel of 90 times series for which 3457 trading days are observed. Method successfully picks up periods of high market volatility by estimating market shocks u t. They find overall 1/3 of total variance of returns is driven by variation in level-common shocks. Moreover, u t has a correlation of.95 with average daily returns, consistent with interpretation that common shocks are market return shocks. Factor structure: They find Q = q s = q w = 1. Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 14 / Shoc 28

Minor Aside The authors worked hard to construct the decompositions into strongly common, weakly common, weakly idiosyncratic, and strongly idiosyncratic shocks. Are there datasets for which this analysis is more fruitful? Large collections of macroeconomic indicators in a DSGE model unlikely to have single factor volatility. Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 15 / Shoc 28

Analyzing Volatility Shocks There are two volatilities to consider: Volatility of the returns factor s it and volatility of the returns idiosyncratic component w it. Market volatility shocks accounts for 2/3 of the volatility of the returns factor, and 1/10 of the volatility of the returns idiosyncratic component. Most of that 1/10 is observed during the 2008-2009 financial crisis, during which market-driven volatility shocks account for closer to 1/5 of the volatility of the level-idiosyncratic component. Outside of that time period, generally closer to 1/20. Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 16 / Shoc 28

Analyzing Volatility Shocks Combine the fact that the factor for volatility accounts for 2/3 of the variation of the returns factor, and 1/10 of the variation of the returns idiosyncratic component with the following: The common component explains an average 1/3 of the volatility of returns, the idiosyncratic component explaining the remaining 2/3. Doing some bad math... 2/3 (1/3) + 1/10 (2/3) =.29 This suggests that the extracted factor for volatility explains around 30% of the variation in returns. Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 17 / Shoc 28

Level-Common and Volatility-Common Shocks Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 18 / Shoc 28

Analyzing Volatility Shocks The extracted factor for volatility explains little of the variation in idiosyncratic volatility. This is somewhat at odds to their original motivation. This returns us to the technical issue: Is the extracted factor for volatility to close to the volatility of the level-common component (u 2 t ) because the estimation procedure effectively used this series 90 times? (Recall the technical issue we raised). If the full panel of volatilities consisted of log(u 2 t ) once, then the 100 idiosyncratic volatilities, would we get a more accurate estimate? Or does this procedure just ruin the asymptotics without solving the above problem? Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 19 / Shoc 28

Issues And Extensions There are several key issues: Covariance estimation (as separate from volatility estimation). Forecasting ability - point versus density forecast. Volatility estimators - proxies instead of realized measures. Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 20 / Shoc 28

Covariance Estimation This paper assumes that all covariance in Y t is from joint loading off of factor - assume exactly diagonal idiosyncratic covariance t. How realistic is this? Let s consider a small exercise with 11 stocks (GE, AXP, Coca Cola, etc, etc). Fit a static factor model to them (scree plot suggests 1 factor) via principal components. Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 21 / Shoc 28

Covariance Estimation Construct a realized measure RMΩ Yt linear factor model in hand from high-frequency data. With the Y it = b i f t + η it we can construct a high-frequency factor as ˆf HF t = b Y HF t From this we can construct an estimate of brmω ft b, and a corresponding estimate of idiosyncratic covariance. What does idiosyncratic correlation look like? Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 22 / Shoc 28

Idiosyncratic Correlation Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 23 / Shoc 28

Idiosyncratic Correlation Idiosyncratic correlation is mean zero (which we expect from factor model identification assumptions). But with static factor loadings and a 1-factor model (so that Ω ft is scalar), if you assume Ω ηt diagonal t, you arrive at a constant correlation model. This is very at odds with the data. Extending the model to capture structure of idiosyncratic correlation would be a great extension. We see that at least for some datasets we may be able to do this parametrically/easily. Semi-open question: What idiosyncratic correlation structures still leave the model identified? Is long-run-mean 0 necessary? Sufficient? Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 24 / Shoc 28

Density Forecasts Consider a general stochastic volatility model Y t F (Σ t ) Σ t G(Σ t 1 ) This yields a density forecast via: ˆP(Y t+1 F t ) = ˆF (Y t+1 Σ t+1 )Ĝ(Σ t+1 F t )dσ t+1 Most of the work on density forecasts in stochastic volatility settings has only focused on the performance of the total density forecast ˆP(Y t+1 F t ). Extending the approach in this paper lets us address accuracy of Ĝ(Σ t Σ t 1 ). Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 25 / Shoc 28

Forecasting: Model-free setup Problem: A model-free approach means only point forecasts. Can maintain model-free setup and estimate distribution of volatility shocks. Covariance densities require at least some structure (to maintain positive-definiteness). Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 26 / Shoc 28

Forecasting - Volatility proxies? The estimation procedure gives rise to impulse response functions which are useful for point forecasts of volatility. How robust is the forecast to the choice of volatility proxy? Patton (2010) shows that the answer unfortunately depends on your choice of loss function. Only particular classes of loss functions are assured to be robust to choice of volatility proxy. Readers familiar with Patton will not be surprised to hear that this class is precisely Bregman loss functions. Bregman loss functions are quite general so this is not devastating, but worth keeping in mind. Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 27 / Shoc 28

Conclusions Key observation: that common component of volatilities is not the volatility of the common component. This is an exciting and important observation that paves the way for accurate volatility estimation. Empirical result that large numbers of common and idiosyncratic volatilities load off of a single factor is crucial for future tractable modeling. This paper is an extremely successful first pass at the approach, so it comes with the caveat that all first passes have: a LOT of room for forward progress. The two big ones are: Restricts to volatility estimation, not covariance estimation. Leaves open the question of how to estimate the densities of extracted shocks. Paper by: Matteo Barigozzi and Marc Hallin Generalized (Discussion by: Dynamic Ross Askanazi) Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering March the27, Market 2015 Volatility 28 / Shoc 28