Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

Similar documents
Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model

Chapter 3 Economic Growth and the Current Account

The Representative Household Model

Chapter 7 Externalities, Human Capital and Endogenous Growth

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

On the Time Inconsistency of International Borrowing in an Optimal Growth Model

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation.

Chapter 10 Money, Interest and Prices

Advanced Macro and Money (WS09/10) Problem Set 4

Lecture 3 Growth Model with Endogenous Savings: Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

National Debt and Economic Growth with Externalities and Congestions

Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation

Home Assignment 1 Financial Openness, the Current Account and Economic Welfare

Chapter 8 A Short Run Keynesian Model of Interdependent Economies

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Money in a Neoclassical Framework

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

1. Money in the utility function (start)

A Re-examination of Economic Growth, Tax Policy, and Distributive Politics

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Intergenerational transfers, tax policies and public debt

Final Exam Solutions

Macroeconomic Policy and Short Term Interdependence in the Global Economy

Macroeconomic Theory I Professor George Alogoskoufis Winter Semester Course Structure

Money in an RBC framework

Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory. Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2009

Economic Growth and the Current Account

Working Paper No. 241

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

Nominal Exchange Rates Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 8

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Spring Trade and Development. Instructions

1 Dynamic programming

Lecture 7: Optimal management of renewable resources

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

A REINTERPRETATION OF THE KEYNESIAN CONSUMPTION FUNCTION AND MULTIPLIER EFFECT

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Lecture Notes. Macroeconomics - ECON 510a, Fall 2010, Yale University. Fiscal Policy. Ramsey Taxation. Guillermo Ordoñez Yale University

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

1 No capital mobility

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

TAKE-HOME EXAM POINTS)

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

Topic 6. Introducing money

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Exercises on chapter 4

Nonlinear Tax Structures and Endogenous Growth

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

The Fisher Equation and Output Growth

Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System

Exercises in Growth Theory and Empirics

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 3 : The Ramsey Growth Model

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Overlapping Generations Model: Dynamic Efficiency and Social Security

Optimal Capital Income Taxation

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

Government expenditure, capital adjustment, and economic growth

Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand

Unemployment Persistence, Inflation and Monetary Policy in A Dynamic Stochastic Model of the Phillips Curve

Chapter 3 Domestic Money Markets, Interest Rates and the Price Level

Midterm 2 Review. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics Professor Sims University of Notre Dame, Spring 2018

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets

Growth Effects of the Allocation of Government Expenditure in an Endogenous Growth Model with Physical and Human Capital

Satya P. Das NIPFP) Open Economy Keynesian Macro: CGG (2001, 2002), Obstfeld-Rogoff Redux Model 1 / 18

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Transactions and Money Demand Walsh Chapter 3

Testing the predictions of the Solow model: What do the data say?

MONETARY AND FINANCIAL MACRO BUDGET CONSTRAINTS

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture

Advanced Macroeconomics

The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases

Topic 4. Introducing investment (and saving) decisions

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

Transcription:

George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth In the models we have presented so far there is no role for money. Yet money performs very important functions in an economy. Money is a unit of account, in terms of which prices are defined, a means of payments, which reduces transaction costs, and a liquid store of value (asset), which pays no interest. In this chapter we allow for the role of money in the various exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far. We first present a representative household model, in which real money balances enter the utility function of households, and then analyze a corresponding model of overlapping generations. 1 In models with money, one can draw the distinction between real variables, as the ones we have analyzed so far, and nominal variables, such as the price level, inflation and nominal output, nominal wages and nominal interest rates. All nominal variables are expressed in terms of money. By assuming that money enters the utility function of households, we derive a money demand function from microeconomic foundations, as a result of the solution of an inter-temporal optimization problem by households. Based on this particular approach to money demand, we show that the demand for real money balances is proportional to aggregate consumption, and depends negatively on the nominal interest rate. Since money is an asset that pays no interest, the nominal interest rate measures the opportunity cost of holding real money balances. The demand for nominal money balances is proportional to the price level, a property which implies the neutrality of money. The stock of nominal money balances does not affect any real variables in these models, but only the price level. We also analyze the determination of inflation, the nominal interest rate and other nominal variables, and the inter-temporal effects of the rate of growth of the money supply on the path of economic growth. In the representative household model, the growth path of all real variables, with the exception of the stock of real money balances, is independent of the rate of growth of the money supply, which affects inflation and nominal interest rates. The demand for real money balances, which depends This approach in the derivation of money demand is the so-called money in the utility function approach, and was first 1 introduced to macroeconomics by Patinkin (1956). This approach contrasts with an alternative approach, called cash in advance, which emphasizes the role of money as a means of payments that reduces transaction costs, eliminating the need for a double coincidence of wants between agents (Clower 1967). As shown by Feenstra (1986) both of these approaches are functionally equivalent. We postpone the examination of the cash in advance approach until Chapter 9, where we provide a fuller treatment of alternative partial and general equilibrium approaches to money demand and the money market.

negatively on the nominal interest rate, is the only real variable that is affected by the rate of growth of the money supply. This is because the rate of growth of the money supply affects nominal interest rates, and therefore the opportunity cost of holding real money balances. To put it differently, the rate of growth of the money supply imposes an inflation tax on the real money balances held by households. The independence of the growth path of all other real variables from the rate of growth of the money supply is known as the super neutrality of money. In overlapping generations models, the rate of growth of the money supply affects the growth path of all real variables, as it affects the aggregate savings rate, the accumulation of capital and the balanced growth path. The reason is that in overlapping generations models, holdings of real money balances differ among generations. Thus, when there is an increase in the rate of growth of the money supply, older generations, which hold higher real money balances, reduce their asset holdings and their consumption more than younger generations, since they pay a higher inflation tax. As a result, aggregate consumption falls, and aggregate savings rise. This leads to a higher accumulation of capital, which affects the growth path. 2 The differences in the effects of the rate of growth of the money supply between representative household and overlapping generations models arise for the same reason that government debt has no real effects in representative household models, while it has real effects in overlapping generations models. Ricardian equivalence and the super neutrality of money are closely linked, as the rate of growth of the money supply is essentially an inflation tax on real money balances. In overlapping generations models this inflation tax, and government debt, have different effects on current and future generations, and thus affect aggregate savings. In the representative household model, neither government debt nor the growth rate of the money supply redistributes the tax burden among generations. In overlapping generations models, both result in a redistribution of the tax burden among generations, and thus affect the aggregate savings of current generations. An increase in public debt redistributes taxes from current to future generations, causing an increase in the consumption by current generations, while an increase in the rate of growth of the money supply redistributes taxes from future to current generations, causing a reduction in the consumption of current generations. This redistribution among generations, and its effects on aggregate savings are thus the reason for the non existence of Ricardian equivalence and the super neutrality of money in overlapping generations models. 6.1 Private Consumption and Money Demand in the Ramsey Model We initially assume an economy in which all households are similar, and in which a representative household is defined. In this economy there is a fixed number of Η households. The number of members of each household is equal to L(t)/H, and is growing at a rate n, which is the rate of growth of population L(t). Labor supply is equal to L(t) and the efficiency of labor h(t) grows at an exogenous rate of technical progress g. The literature on money and economic growth originated with Tobin (1965). Sidrauski (1967) first used a 2 representative household model to demonstrate the super-neutrality of money, i.e that the rate of growth rate of the money supply does not affect the path of real variables on the adjustment path or the balanced growth. The literature has since expanded exponentially. Weil (1987, 1991) analyzed the role of money in a model of overlapping generations, and demonstrated that the super-neutrality of money does not apply in such models.!2

The utility function of households depends on consumption of goods and services, and holdings of real money balances, which yield liquidity services to households. 6.1.1 Money in the Utility Function of Households Household i, where i=1,2,...,h, selects a path of consumption and real money balances in order to maximize the following inter-temporal utility function. ( ) 1 ε L(t)! U i = e ρt ln γ c i (t) ε + (1 γ )m i (t) ε (6.1) t=0 H dt The maximization takes place under the instantaneous budget constraint,! a i(t) = ( r(t) n)a i (t) + w(t)h(t) τ (t) c i (t) ( r(t) + π(t) )m i (t) (6.2) and the transversality condition, ( r(s) n)ds s=0! lim a i (t) = 0 (6.3) t e t ρ is the pure rate of time preference of households, 1/(1-ε) is the elasticity of substitution between consumption and real money balances (assumed positive), ci(t) denotes average consumption per person of household i at time t, mi(t) denotes average per person real money balances of household i at time t, ai(t) denotes average assets per person (non-human wealth) of household i at time t, w(t) denotes the real wage per efficiency unit of labor at time t, h(t) denotes labor efficiency per worker, and τ(t) denotes average per person taxes (minus transfers) at time t. r(t) is the real interest rate at time t, n is the population growth rate, equal to the growth rate of members per household, and π(t) is inflation, which is equal to expected inflation. Real money balances provide utility because of their liquidity services, i.e because they facilitate payments (the exchange of goods and services) and reduce transaction costs. The instantaneous utility function is assumed logarithmic in both its terms, something that restricts the inter temporal elasticity of substitution to unity. γ measures the share of goods consumption in the instantaneous utility of households. 6.1.2 Nominal and Real Interest Rates and the Opportunity Cost of Real Money Balances Unlike other assets held by households, such as capital or government bonds, the nominal yield of money is equal to zero, because money balances do not pay interest. Moreover, when there is inflation π(t), real (inflation adjusted) money balances lose value at a rate π(t). Therefore the opportunity cost of holding real money balances is equal to the sum of the real return of interest yielding assets, plus the expected inflation rate. This is defined as the nominal interest rate i(t), which is determined by,! i(t) = r(t) + π (t) (6.4)!3

This relationship is often called the Fisher equation. 3 6.1.3 The First Order Conditions for an Optimum Maximizing (6.1) under the constraint (6.2), by forming the relevant Hamiltonian, yields the following first order conditions, γ! (6.5) 1 c i (t) ε 1 = λ i (t) γ c i (t) ε + (1 γ )m i (t) ε ε 1 γ! 1 m i (t) ε 1 = λ i (t)( r(t) + π(t) ) (6.6) γ c i (t) ε + (1 γ )m i (t) ε ε! (t) = ( r(t) ρ)λi (t) (6.7) λ i The asset accumulation constraint (6.2) and the transversality condition (6.3) must also be satisfied. λi(t) is the current value multiplier of the relevant current value Hamiltonian, and its economic interpretation is that it measures the shadow value of savings (assets) of the household. From (6.5), λi(t), which is the shadow value of savings, is equal to the current marginal utility of consumption. At the optimum the marginal value of savings must be equal to the marginal utility of consumption, and the household must be indifferent at the margin between saving and consuming. From (6.6), the current marginal utility of real money balances is equal to the marginal utility of consumption, times the opportunity cost of holding real money balances. At the optimum the marginal value of holding real money balances must be equal to the opportunity cost of holding money, in terms of the marginal utility of consumption. Finally, from (6.7), the marginal utility of consumption falls at a rate which is equal to the difference between the real interest rate and the pure rate of time preference. This is another way of saying that the expected real return on savings, including capital gains on assets, is equal to the pure rate of time preference of the household. This can be seen by re-arranging (6.7) as,! r(t) + λ i (t) (6.7 ) λ i (t) = ρ 6.1.4 The Money Demand Function Dividing (6.5) by (6.6) and solving for real money balances, we can derive a function for the demand for real money balances by the representative household. 3 See Fisher (1896) or Fisher (1930) Chapter ΙΙ.!4

1 γ 1 ε! m i (t) = (r(t) + π (t)) (6.8) 1 γ ci (t) We can use (6.8) to deduce aggregate money demand. Multiplying both sides of (6.8) by L(t) we get, M (t) P(t) = γ (r(t) + π (t)) 1 γ 1 1 ε C(t) (6.9) where M(t) is the aggregate nominal money supply, P(t) is the price level, and C(t) is aggregate real consumption of goods and services. (6.9) describes the aggregate money demand function in this model. Aggregate money demand is proportional to the price level and aggregate real consumption, and depends negatively on the nominal interest rate. Put differently, the elasticity of aggregate money demand with respect to the price level and aggregate private consumption is equal to one, while the elasticity of aggregate money demand with respect to the nominal interest rate is equal to -1/(1-ε). (6.9) is characterized by homogeneity of degree one with respect to the price level, because households demand money for its purchasing power. Doubling the money supply, for given aggregate real consumption and nominal interest rates, would cause a doubling of the price level. This property leads to the neutrality of money. Expressing real money balances per efficiency unit of labor, one gets, γ m(t) = (r(t) + π (t)) 1 γ 1 1 ε c(t) (6.10) where c=c/hl και m=(m/p)/hl. h is the efficiency of labor. 6.1.5 The Rate of Growth of the Money Supply and Inflation We can use (6.9) or (6.10) to determine the price level and inflation, under the assumption that the aggregate nominal money supply and its rate of growth µ are determined by the government (or the central bank). From (6.9) and (6.4), it follows that, M (t) P(t)C(t) = m(t) c(t) = γ (r(t) + π (t)) 1 γ 1 1 ε = γ 1 γ i(t) 1 1 ε (6.11) For given aggregate real consumption and nominal interest rates, the level of the nominal money supply determines the level of prices.!5

From (6.11) it follows that, µ π (t) C (t) C(t) = 1 i (t) 1 ε i(t) (6.12) Thus, from (6.12), inflation is determined as, π (t) = µ C (t) C(t) + 1 i (t) 1 ε i(t) (6.13) For a given rate of growth in private consumption and fixed nominal interest rates, the inflation rate π(t) is determined by the rate of growth of the money supply. 6.1.6 The Euler Equation for Consumption In what follows, we shall assume that the elasticity of substitution between consumption of goods and services and real money balances is equal to unity, i.e that ε=0. In this case, (6.5) reduces to,! λ i (t) = γ (6.5 ) c i (t) From (6.5 ) and (6.7), it thus follows that,! (t) = ( r(t) ρ)ci (t) (6.14) c i (6.14) is the standard Euler equation for consumption in the Ramsey model, when the intertemporal elasticity of substitution is assumed equal to unity. The reason that real money balances, or the nominal interest rate, do not appear in (6.14) is the additional assumption that the elasticity of substitution between consumption and real money balances is also equal to unity (ε=0). This assumption implies additively separable preferences of the household over consumption and real money balances. With additively separable preferences the marginal utility of consumption in (6.5) does not depend on real money balances, or the determinants of their demand, such as the nominal interest rate. From (6.14), the evolution of aggregate consumption and consumption per efficiency unit of labor is determined by,! C (t) = ( r(t) ρ + n)c(t) (6.15)! c (t) = ( r(t) ρ g)c(t) (6.16) where g is the rate of exogenous technical progress.!6

From (6.15) and (6.16) the rate of growth of aggregate consumption or consumption per efficiency unit of labor only depends on real variables, not the money supply or its rate of growth. Assuming the elasticity of substitution between consumption and real money balances is equal to unity, i.e ε=0, also affects the money demand function (6.10), which now takes the form,! m(t) = 1 γ 1 (6.10 ) γ (r(t) + π(t)) c(t) With the unitary elasticity of substitution between consumption and real money balances, the demand for real money balances has a unitary elasticity with respect to the nominal interest rate. 6.2 Capital Accumulation in a Ramsey Model with Money We next turn to the determinants of capital accumulation, output and other real variables such as the real interest rate and real wages. We assume as in the previous models that output per efficiency unit of labor is determined by, y(t) = f (k(t)) (6.17) where f is a neoclassical production function, with all the usual properties. Once the capital stock per efficiency unit of labor is determined, output is determined through the production function (6.17). We have already assumed an exogenous rate of growth of population n and an exogenous rate of technical progress g. The depreciation rate of the capital stock will be assumed equal to δ, where, 1>δ>0. 6.2.1 The Real Interest Rate and the Real Wage In a competitive equilibrium, the real interest rate r(t) and the real wage per efficiency unit of labor w(t) will be determined by the marginal productivity conditions, r(t) = f (k(t)) δ (6.18) w(t) = f (k(t)) k(t) f (k(t)) (6.19) These marginal productivity conditions are derived from the assumption that firms maximize their profits. 6.2.2 The Inflation Tax and the Accumulation of Capital We shall assume that the assets of household i in equation (6.2) consist of capital, government bonds and money.!7

! George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 6 a i (t) = k i (t) + d i (t) + m i (t) (6.20) where ki, di and mi denote physical capital, real government bonds and real money balances held by the average member of household i. Replacing (6.20) in (6.2), after multiplying by L(t), we get an accumulation equation for total household assets in the economy. K (t) + D (t) + = r(t) K(t) + D(t) + M (t) P(t) M (t) P(t) + w(t)h(t)l(t) T (t) C(t) (r(t) + π(t)) M (t) P(t) The rate of growth of real money balances is given by µ-π(t). Thus, it will hold that, (6.21) M (t) P(t) = (µ π (t)) M (t) P(t) (6.22) Substituting (6.22) in (6.21), and solving for the accumulation of physical capital and real government bonds, we get, K (t) + D (t) = r(t)k(t) + w(t)h(t)l(t) + r(t)d(t) T (t) µ M (t) P(t) C(t) (6.23) The aggregate accumulation of capital and real government bonds by households depends on the difference between aggregate household disposable income from aggregate household consumption. The disposable income of households consists of their total asset and labor income, minus taxes T(t) and the inflation tax imposed by the government through the rate of growth of the money supply (seigniorage). Government revenue from the monopoly of issuing money, usually referred to as seigniorage, is equal to µ(m(t)/p(t)) and comprises a tax on real money balances held by households. (6.23) describes the budget constraint of households. The government budget constraint in an economy is which the government has the monopoly of money creation is described by, D (t) = C g (t) + r(t)d(t) T (t) µ M (t) P(t) (6.24) (6.24) suggests that the government accumulates government debt to the extent that primary government expenditure Cg, plus the interest expenditure on existing debt rd, exceeds total taxes (minus transfers) T, plus the inflation tax µ(m/p). Substituting the government budget constraint (6.24) in the household budget constraint (6.23), we end up with the well known equation for aggregate capital accumulation,!8

! K (t) = r(t)k(t) + w(t)h(t)l(t) C g (t) C(t) (6.25) Only primary government expenditure, and not the way it is financed, appears in the aggregate capital accumulation equation. Debt, taxes and seigniorage revenue do not affect the accumulation of capital. Expressing both sides of (6.25) per efficiency unit of labor, i.e dividing by h(t)l(t), we get,! k (t) = r(t)k(t) + w(t) c(t) c g (t) (n + g)k(t) = f (k(t)) c(t) c g (t) (n + g + δ )k(t) (6.26) The economy accumulates capital per efficiency unit of labor when total savings per efficiency unit of labor exceed the investment required to maintain a constant capital stock per efficiency unit of labor. 6.3 The Growth Path and the Rate of Growth of the Money Supply The evolution of real variables in the Ramsey model with money is thus determined by the Euler equation for consumption (6.16) and the capital accumulation equation (6.26). These two determine private consumption and the capital stock. All other real variables are functions of the capital stock (per efficiency unit of labor) and/or private consumption. Output is determined by the production function (6.17). The real interest rate and the real wage are determined by the marginal productivity conditions (6.18) and (6.19). The demand for real money balances is determined by the money demand function (6.10 ), while the nominal interest rate is determined by the Fisher equation (6.4), and inflation is determined by equation (6.13). As for the government, we shall make similar assumptions to the ones we made in Chapter 4. We shall assume that the government chooses a constant level of primary expenditure and government debt per efficiency unit of labor, and uses taxes to satisfy the government budget constraint. The government also chooses, through the central bank, a constant rate of growth of the money supply. All seigniorage revenue accrues to the government budget. With these assumptions, private consumption and the accumulation of capital are determined by the pair of differential equations,! c (t) = ( f (k(t) δ ρ g)c(t) (6.16 )! k (t) = f (k(t)) c(t) c _ g (n + g + δ )k(t) (6.26 ) where! is the government s target of primary government expenditure per efficiency unit of labor. c _ g As one can see from (6.16 ) and (6.26 ) neither the stock of money, nor the rate of growth of the money supply affect the evolution of private consumption (savings) or the accumulation of capital (investment). The determination of consumption and the capital stock takes place in the same way as in a model without money. The only government policy variable that appears to affect the economy is real primary government expenditure.!9

6.3.1 The Balanced Growth Path in the Ramsey Model with Money As in the Ramsey model without money, it is straightforward to prove that this economy possesses a unique balanced growth path and a unique saddle path leading to the balanced growth path. On the balanced growth path, all variables that have been defined per efficiency unit of labor will remain constant, and the same applies to interest rates (real and nominal) and inflation. From (6.16 ), on the balanced growth path, the real interest rate must be equal to the pure rate of time preference, plus the exogenous rate of technical progress. Therefore, steady state capital per efficiency unit of labor is determined by the condition, f (k*) = ρ + g δ (6.27) Steady state consumption per efficiency unit of labor is determined by the steady state version of (6.26 ) as, c* = f (k*) c _ g (n + g + δ )k * (6.28) Primary government expenditure has a one to one negative effect on private consumption, and does not affect the steady state capital stock or steady state output. Real output per efficiency unit of labor on the steady state is determined by the production function (6.17), as, y* = f (k*) (6.29) The real interest rate and the real wage per efficiency unit of labor are determined by,! r* = ρ + g (6.30)! w* = f (k*) k * f (k*) (6.31) (6.27), (6.28), (6.29), (6.30) and (6.31) determine the evolution of all real variables, with the exception of real money balances. Capital, output, the real wage and consumption per efficiency unit of labor are constant on the balanced growth path, as is the real interest rate. All per capita variables grow at the exogenous rate of technical progress g. In this model, neither the method of financing government expenditure, nor the money stock or the rate of growth of the money supply affect the balanced growth path. Thus, both Ricardian equivalence and the neutrality as well as the so called super neutrality of money hold in a representative household model. 6.3.2 The Super Neutrality of Money and Inflation!10

The super neutrality of money was first analyzed by Sidrauski (1967), who demonstrated that, in a representative household model, the growth rate of the money supply does not affect real variables on the balanced growth path. On the balanced growth path, the inflation rate is determined by the difference between the growth rate of the money supply from the long-term growth rate n+g. This can be seen from the inflation determination equation (6.13). Assuming a constant rate of growth of the money supply, the inflation rate on the balanced growth path equals, π* = µ (n + g) (6.32) where n+g is the steady state rate of growth of total private consumption (and output). Moving from (6.13) to (6.32) we have assumed that the nominal interest rate is constant on the balanced growth path. From the Fisher equation (6.5), the steady state nominal interest rate is indeed constant and equal to, i* = r *+π* = ρ + g + µ (n + g) = ρ n + µ (6.33) Finally, real money balances per efficiency unit of labor are also constant on the balanced growth path. They are determined from the money demand equation (6.10 ) and are given by, m* = 1 γ γ 1 i * c* = 1 γ γ 1 ρ n + µ c * (6.34) The higher the growth rate of the money supply, given the other structural parameters of the model, the higher the rate of inflation and the nominal interest rate, and the lower the stock of real money balances on the balanced growth path. A permanent increase in the growth rate of the money supply by 5 percentage points causes an increase in inflation by 5 percentage points, and an increase in nominal interest rates by 5 percentage points as well. It also causes a decrease in the demand for real money balances. In a representative household model, real money balances is the only real variable affected by the growth rate of the money supply on the balanced growth path. It also follows that the neutrality of money also holds in this model, as the level of the money supply only affects the price level, and no real variables. From the definition of real money balances per efficiency unit of labor, M (t)! (6.35) P(t) = m *h L 0 0 e(g+n)t where h0, L0 are the efficiency of labor and the labor force at time 0. Real money balances are also growing at a rate g+n on the balanced growth path. From (6.35), the only effect of a rise in the money stock is an equiproportionate rise in the price level. Thus, the neutrality of money also holds in this model.!11

6.4 Effects of Money Growth in an Overlapping Generations Model We now turn to the analysis of the impact of the growth rate of the money supply in the overlapping generations model of Blanchard and Weil. We assume that the economy consists of overlapping generations of households born at different times in the past. Each generation has an infinite time horizon. nl(t) households are born at each instant t, where L(t) is total population at time t, and n is the growth rate of the number of households and the overall population. Each household has one member and provides one unit of labor. Consequently, the growth rate of the labor force is also n. 6.4.1 The Blanchard Weil Model with Money The household born at time j chooses a path for consumption and real money balances in order to maximize the inter temporal utility function, U j = e ρs s= j ln( γ c( j,s) ε + (1 γ )m( j,s) ε ) 1 ε ds (6.36) under the instantaneous budget constraint, a ( j,s) = r(s)a( j,s) + w(s)h(s) τ (s) c( j,s) ( r(s) + π(s) )m( j,s) (6.37) and the transversality condition, lim e t t r(s)ds s= j a( j,t) = 0 (6.38) The variables and parameters are defined as in the case of the representative household model. ρ is the pure rate of time preference of households, 1/(1-ε) is the elasticity of substitution between consumption and real money balances (assumed positive), c(j,s) denotes the consumption of the household born at time j at time s, m(j,s) real money balances of the household born at time j at time s, a(j,s) denotes average assets of the household born at time j at time s, w(s) denotes the real wage per efficiency unit of labor at time t, h(s) denotes labor efficiency per worker, and τ(s) denotes average per household taxes (minus transfers) at time s. r(s) is the real interest rate at time s, n is the population growth rate, and π(t) is inflation, which is equal to expected inflation. γ is the share of consumption of goods and services on the instantaneous utility of households. From the first order conditions for a maximum, assuming ε=0, we can derive the aggregate money demand function, the equation describing the evolution of aggregate consumption, and the equation describing capital accumulation, as, M (t) P(t) = 1 γ γ 1 r(t) + π(t) C(t) (6.39)!12

! George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 6 C (t) = ( r(t) ρ + n)c(t) nργ K(t) + D(t) + M (t) P(t) (6.40)! K (t) = r(t)k(t) + w(t)h(t)l(t) C(t) C g (t) (6.41) Expressing (6.39), (6.40) and (6.41) per efficiency unit of labor, assuming also that the government has a constant target for primary government expenditure and public debt per efficiency unit of labor, as well as a constant target for the rate of growth of the money supply, we get,! m(t) = 1 γ 1 (6.42) γ r(t) + π(t) c(t)! c (t) = r(t) ρ g nρ(1 γ ) (6.43) r(t) + π(t) c(t) nργ k(t) + d_! k (t) = r(t)k(t) + w(t) c(t) c _ g (n + g)k(t) (6.44) In (6.43) we have used (6.42) to substitute for the stock of real money balances per efficiency unit of labor. Using (6.18) and (6.19) to replace for the real interest rate and the real wage per efficiency unit of labor, (6.43) and (6.44) can be written as, c (t) = f (k(t)) δ ρ g nρ(1 γ ) f (k(t)) δ + π(t) c(t) nργ k(t) + d_ (6.45) k (t) = f (k(t)) c(t) c _ g (n + g + δ )k(t) (6.46) 6.4.2 The Real Effects of the Rate of Growth of the Money Supply From (6.45) and (6.46), on the balanced growth path we shall have, c* = f (k*) δ ρ g nργ nρ(1 γ ) f (k*) δ + µ (n + g) k *+ d _ (6.47) c* = f (k*) c _ g (n + g + δ )k * (6.48) (6.47) and (6.48) determine real private consumption and real capital per efficiency unit of labor on the balanced growth path, as a function of parameters of technology, household preferences, the!13

population growth rate and the rate of exogenous technical progress, as well as the parameters describing fiscal and monetary policy. The balanced growth path, and the relevant unique saddle path, are shown diagrammatically in Figure 6.1. The equilibrium path has the usual properties that characterize the model of Blanchard and Weil. The new element here is the impact of the growth rate of the money supply on private consumption. 4 A permanent increase in the growth rate of the money supply µ leads to a permanent increase in inflation and nominal interest rates. This in turn leads to a reduction in demand for real money balances. In this model, the decline in real money balances leads to a corresponding reduction in private consumption by current generations, thus increasing aggregate savings and causing the accumulation of physical capital. This analysis is in Figure 6.2. A permanent increase in the growth rate of the money supply, which leads to an increase in inflation, results in a heavier inflation tax for the current generations, who hold higher real money balances compared to future generations who do not hold real money balances. This causes a reduction in current consumption, an increase in total savings and the initiation of a process of accumulation of physical capital. The economy adjusts towards a new balanced growth path E, which implies higher capital, output and consumption per efficiency unit of labor, due to the substitution towards physical capital caused by higher inflation. In this model, the super neutrality of money does not apply, because the inflation tax impacts different generations differently, and the redistribution it causes in favor of future generations reduces current consumption and increases savings by current generations. Thus, as with Ricardian equivalence, the super neutrality of money does not apply in an overlapping generations model like the Blanchard and Weil model. 6.4.3 A Dynamic Simulation of the Effects of a Rise in the Rate of Growth of the Money Supply In order to examine the quantitative impact of the rate of growth of the money supply in the overlapping generations model of Blanchard Weil, we shall simulate the model for specific parameter values, assuming a Cobb Douglas production function of the form,! y(t) = Ak(t) α,! A > 0,! 0 < α < 1 (6.49) Consequently, the model we simulate consists of, (6.45), for the evolution of private consumption, (6.46), for the accumulation of capital, (6.49), for the production function, (6.42), for the money demand function, ( 6.18) and (6.19), for the real interest rate and real wages, (6.4), for the nominal interest rate and (6.13), for inflation. Where the marginal product of capital or labor appears, this is derived from the production function (6.49). In the simulations we use the usual parameter values, the same as in Chapters 3 and 4. A=1, a=0.333, ρ=0.02, n=0.01, g=0.02, δ=0.03. 4 See Weil (1987, 1991).!14

With regard to the parameters of fiscal policy it is assumed that,! c _ g = 0.5 and! d _ = 0.5 In Figure 6.3 we present the dynamic effects of a permanent change in the growth rate of the money supply from 5% to 10%. We assume that this change is accompanied by corresponding reductions in taxes, which are continuously equal to the increase in the inflation tax on real money balances. There is no impact on primary government expenditure or government debt. The change in the growth rate of the money supply by five percentage points, from 5% to 10%, reduces private consumption expenditure immediately, due to the reduction of the real money balances of current generations. This causes an increase in savings and initiates a process of capital accumulation that leads the economy towards a new balanced growth path, with a higher capital stock, higher output, higher private consumption and higher real wages per efficiency unit of labor. On the other hand, the real interest rate falls. Inflation rises by five percentage points, the same as the rise in the rate of growth of the money supply, and roughly the same happens to nominal interest rates. However, it is worth noting that the impact of a change in the growth rate of the money supply on the real economy is extremely small. A doubling of the growth rate of the money supply from 5% to 10%, leads to an increase in steady state real per capita income (and real wages) by only 0.09%, and a reduction in the real interest rate by only 0.01 percentage points (i.e from 4.25% to 4.24%). The overall savings rate in the balanced growth path rises from 27.66% to 27.71%, again a very slight increase. On the other hand, inflation rises by five percentage points, from 2% to 7%, and nominal interest rates slightly less, from 6.24% to 11.23%. The rise in the nominal interest rate is due to the rise in inflation plus the small fall in the real interest rate. We see therefore that, as with deviations from Ricardian equivalence, deviations from the superneutrality of money in models of overlapping generations are quantitatively limited. This is due to the fact that these differences depend on the product of two quantitatively small parameters: the rate of growth of population, which determines the rate of entry of new generations in the economy, and the pure rate of time preference of households, which determines the percentage of total household wealth that is consumed. With the assumptions we have made, for population growth rate of 1% per year and pure rate of time preference of 2%, their product is equal to just 0.2%. 6.5 Conclusions In this chapter we have analyzed the role of money in optimizing models of economic growth. Initially we analyzed the role of money in a representative household model, in which money enters the utility function of the representative household. We then analyzed a corresponding model of overlapping generations. In growth models with money, one can analyze the determination of both real and nominal variables, such as the price level, inflation and nominal interest rates and examine the dynamic impact of the rate of the rate of growth of the money supply.!15

In the representative household model, the growth rate of the money supply has virtually no real effects, apart from reducing the demand for real money balances, since money does not pay interest. The balanced growth path of all other real variables is independent of the growth rate of the money supply, which only affects inflation, nominal interest rates and the demand for real money balances by households. This result is known as the super neutrality of money. In a model of overlapping generations, the growth rate of the money supply has real effects, as it has a different impact on the holdings of real money balances and on the level of consumption of different generations. When there is an increase of the growth rate of the money supply, older generations, which hold higher real money balances, pay a higher inflation tax than younger generations. Therefore, current aggregate consumption falls, and savings increase. This leads to a higher accumulation of capital and a transition to a balanced growth path with higher capital per efficiency unit of labor. However, it is worth noting that dynamic simulations suggest that these deviations from the super neutrality of money are quantitatively small for plausible parameter values. The differences in the effects of the growth rate of the money supply between the two categories of models are due to the same reasons that government debt has real effects in a model of overlapping generations, while it does not have real effects in a representative household model. In the representative household model, neither government debt nor the growth rate of the money supply cause a redistribution of the tax burden among generations. On the other hand, in an overlapping generations model, both government debt and the rate of growth of the money supply are associated with a redistribution of the tax burden among generations. An increase in government debt redistributes the tax burden from current to future generations, causing an increase in consumption by current generations and a fall in savings and the accumulation of capital. An increase in the rate of growth of the money supply redistributes the tax burden from future to current generations, causing a reduction of aggregate private consumption, and an increase in savings and the accumulation of capital.!16

Figure 6.1 Equilibrium and Dynamic Adjustment in the Blanchard Weil Model with Money c=0 c c * E k=0 k * -c g k!17

! George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 6 Figure 6.2 An Increase in the Rate of Growth of the Money Supply in the Blanchard Weil Model c=0 c c Ε c Ε E E' k=0 k Ε k Ε -c g k!18

Figure 6.3 A Dynamic Simulation of an Increase in the Rate of Growth of the Money Supply from 5% to 10%, in the Blanchard Weil Model!19

References Barro R.J. (1974), Are Government Bonds Net Wealth, Journal of Political Economy, 82, pp. 1095-1117. Blanchard O.J. (1985), Debts, Deficits and Finite Horizons, Journal of Political Economy, 93, pp. 223-247. Clower R.W. (1967), A Reconsideration of the Microfoundations of Monetary Theory, Western Economic Journal, 6, pp. 1-9. Diamond P. (1965), National Debt in a Neoclassical Growth Model, American Economic Review, 55, pp. 1126-1150. Feenstra R.C. (1986), Functional Equivalence between Liquidity Costs and the Utility of Money, Journal of Monetary Economics, 17, pp. 271-291. Fisher I. (1896) Appreciation and Interest, Publications of the American Economic Association, 11, pp. 1-98. Fisher I. (1930), The Theory of Interest, New York, Macmillan. Patinkin D. (1956), Money, Interest and Prices, (2nd Edition, 1965), New York, Haprer and Row. Ramsey F. (1928), A Mathematical Theory of Saving, Economic Journal, 38, pp. 543-559. Sidrauski M. (1967), Rational Choice and Patterns of Growth in a Monetary Economy, American Economic Review, 57, pp. 534-544. Tobin J. (1965) Money and Economic Growth, Econometrica, 33, pp. 671-684. Weil P. (1987), Permanent Budget Deficits and Inflation, Journal of Monetary Economics, 20, pp. 393-410. Weil P. (1989), Overlapping Families of Infinitely-Lived Agents, Journal of Public Economics, 38, pp. 183-198. Weil P. (1991), Is Money Net Wealth, International Economic Review, 32, pp. 37-53.!20