The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model

Similar documents
Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing

In ation persistence, Price Indexation and Optimal Simple Interest Rate Rules

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model

Sacri ce ratio in a medium-scale New Keynesian model

Central bank credibility and the persistence of in ation and in ation expectations

Chasing the Gap: Speed Limits and Optimal Monetary Policy

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Inflation targets, endogenous mark-ups and the non-vertical Phillips curve.

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 19/ Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

Discussion of. Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model By Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe and Martin Uribe

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

In ation Premium and Oil Price Uncertainty

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

Monetary Policy, In ation, and the Business Cycle. Chapter 3. The Basic New Keynesian Model

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports

Optimal Monetary Policy

Journal of Central Banking Theory and Practice, 2017, 1, pp Received: 6 August 2016; accepted: 10 October 2016

The science of monetary policy

Monetary Policy, In ation, and the Business Cycle. Chapter 5. Monetary Policy Tradeo s: Discretion vs Commitment Jordi Galí y CREI and UPF August 2007

The Limits of Monetary Policy Under Imperfect Knowledge

Samba: Stochastic Analytical Model with a Bayesian Approach. DSGE Model Project for Brazil s economy

Is Lumpy Investment really Irrelevant for the Business Cycle?

Monetary Policy, In ation, and the Business Cycle. Chapter 3 The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí CREI and UPF August 2007

Disin ation e ects in a medium-scale New Keynesian model: money supply rule versus interest rate rule

Price Reset Hazard Functions and Macro Dynamics

News and Business Cycles in Open Economies

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility

1 A Simple Model of the Term Structure

The New Keynesian Approach to Monetary Policy Analysis: Lessons and New Directions

Financial Stability in Open Economies

Fiscal Consolidation in a Currency Union: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Welfare

The optimal in ation rate revisited

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FISCAL POLICY, WEALTH EFFECTS, AND MARKUPS. Tommaso Monacelli Roberto Perotti

Macroeconometric Modeling (Session B) 7 July / 15

Welfare-based optimal monetary policy with unemployment and sticky prices: A linear-quadratic framework

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

Uncertainty and the Dynamics of R&D*

Econ590 Topics in Macroeconomics. Lecture 1 : Business Cycle Models : The Current Consensus (Part C)

An Anatomy of the Phillips Curve

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Is There a Fiscal Free Lunch in a Liquidity Trap?

Monetary Policy: Rules versus discretion..

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics

Trend In ation, Wage Indexation, and Determinacy in the U.S.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ON QUALITY BIAS AND INFLATION TARGETS. Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe Martin Uribe

On the new Keynesian model

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy. NBS, April 27, / 44

Quantitative Easing at the Zero-Lower Bound

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

Complete nancial markets and consumption risk sharing

Is the US current account de cit sustainable? Disproving some fallacies about current accounts

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES NEW-KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS: AN AS-AD VIEW. Pierpaolo Benigno. Working Paper

Models of Wage-setting.. January 15, 2010

EUI WORKING PAPERS EUROPEAN UNIVERSITY INSTITUTE. Optimal Monetary Policy Rules, Asset Prices and Credit Frictions. Ester Faia and Tommaso Monacelli

The Zero Lower Bound

Keynesian Multipliers with Home Production

WORKING PAPER NO THE IMPLICATIONS OF INFLATION IN AN ESTIMATED NEW-KEYNESIAN MODEL

Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D

Chapters 1 & 2 - MACROECONOMICS, THE DATA

Reconciling the Effects of Monetary Policy Actions on Consumption within a Heterogeneous Agent Framework

ESSAYS ON PRICE-SETTING MODELS AND INFLATION DYNAMICS

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Exercises on chapter 4

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Quadratic Labor Adjustment Costs and the New-Keynesian Model. by Wolfgang Lechthaler and Dennis Snower

Coordinating Monetary and Financial Regulatory Policies

Optimal Monetary Policy under Sudden Stops

The implementation of monetary and fiscal rules in the EMU: a welfare-based analysis

Fiscal Policy in an Estimated DSGE Model of the Japanese Economy

Quantity Rationing of Credit and the Phillips Curve

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont)

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

Econ 210C: Macroeconomic Theory

Review Seminar. Section A

Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 5

Exploding Bubbles In a Macroeconomic Model. Narayana Kocherlakota

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Determinacy, Stock Market Dynamics and Monetary Policy Inertia Pfajfar, Damjan; Santoro, Emiliano

Outline for Behzad Diba s Discussion of. Buiter (2005), The Elusive Welfare Economics of Price Stability...

COMMENTS ON MONETARY POLICY UNDER UNCERTAINTY IN MICRO-FOUNDED MACROECONOMETRIC MODELS, BY A. LEVIN, A. ONATSKI, J. WILLIAMS AND N.

Schäuble versus Tsipras: a New-Keynesian DSGE Model with Sovereign Default for the Eurozone Debt Crisis

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy

Fiscal Multiplier in a Credit-Constrained New Keynesian Economy

The Dual Nature of Public Goods and Congestion: The Role. of Fiscal Policy Revisited

Terms of Trade Shocks and Fiscal Policy in a Small Open Economy with Credit Constrained Consumers

Fiscal Consolidations in Currency Unions: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

Nominal Rigidities and Asset Pricing in New Keynesian Monetary Models

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models

Transcription:

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model Guido Ascari University of Pavia Nicola Branzoli University of Pavia October 27, 2006 Abstract This note shows that full price indexation is not optimal in the long-run in the New Keynesian model. Moreover, we show that more price stickiness may increase steady state welfare, if price indexation is partial. JEL classi cation: E3, E52. Keywords: Indexation, Optimal Monetary Policy Rules, New Keynesian model Corresponding author: Guido Ascari, Department of Economics and Quantitative Methods, University of Pavia, Via San Felice 5, 2700 Pavia, Italy. Tel: +39 382 5062 ; Fax: +39 382 304226; e-mail:gascari@eco.unipv.it.

Introduction Indexation of wages and prices was the subject of substantial literature in macro in the era of high in ation (see the seminal paper by Gray, 976) and it has subsequently been neglected. Quite recently, however, many authors start introducing various forms of indexation in the New Keynesian model, within the Calvo price staggering framework. However, they do it in a completely ad hoc manner. First, the nowadays most popular form of indexation embedded in these models is the so-called backward-looking indexation. The main reason is empirical in order to have a lagged term in the New Keynesian Phillips Curve to match the in ation persistence in the data. Second, indexation is most of the times assumed to be full, which avoids the problems arising with positive in ation in steady state (see Ascari, 2004). In the empirical estimates of these models, however, indexation is usually found to be only partial. This short note looks at the second issue, while leaving the rst one to further research. That is, we do not ask which is the best form of indexation in these models. Instead, we deal with the following question: given that we assume backward looking indexation (as most of the recent literature), is full indexation optimal in the long-run? In order to do that, we use the Christiano et al. (2005) (CEE henceforth) model, which is quite rich and empirically successful. Since indexation is usually not assumed to be state contingent, in this note we restrict our analysis to the steady state of the CEE model. We will then ask which are the values of price and wages indexation that maximize welfare in the deterministic steady state of the CEE model. 2 The Model The version of the CEE model we use is exactly the one described in Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004), p. 4-23. Its main features are: (i) Households: habit persistence in consumption, money in the utility function, each household comprises all the type of labors and owns capital stock, sticky wages a la Calvo; (ii) Firms: Cash-in-advance constraint on wage payments, monopolistic competition, price stickiness a la Calvo, standard Cobb-Douglas production function plus a xed cost to guarantee zero pro t in equilibrium, variable capacity utilization, adjustment costs in investment; (iii) Government expenditure is nanced through lump-sum taxes and seigniorage. We use the same functional forms, notation and calibration of Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004) (see Table therein). In this note we focus on indexation, which in the CEE model takes the popular form of backward-looking indexation. In other words, those prices (and wages) that can not change are automatically updated accordingly to the level of price (wage) in ation in the previous period. 3 Steady State Optimal Indexation Both CEE and Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004) assume that both wages and prices are fully indexed, that is indexation is 00%. In this note we ask the model what are the values of 2 [0; ] (i.e., degree of price indexation) and of ~ 2 [0; ] (i.e., degree of wage indexation) that maximize the steady state welfare of the representative household.

We expected to nd full indexation (i.e.,,~ = ) to be optimal in steady state, since, as in Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004), steady state in ation is calibrated to be equal to US average in ation (4.2%). Figure shows welfare as a function of and ~; immediately revealing two main results: (i) no indexation gives the worst outcome; (ii) wage indexation is much more important than price indexation for welfare. Indeed, price indexation does not a ect welfare very much, for a given level of wage indexation (~); while the welfare surface is quite sensitive with respect to changes in ~, given : Moreover a quick look at Figure seems to con rm the expectation of the optimality of full indexation. However a more careful inspection of the actual numbers shows that this is, rather surprisingly, not the case. Result The maximum welfare level is attained at ~ = and = 0:88; that is, full wage indexation, but only partial price indexation. Figure 2 uncovers this main result. Indeed, steady state welfare is ever increasing in the wage indexation parameter, ~; but for a given ~; it is rst increasing and then decreasing in the price indexation parameter, : It follows that for any ~; full price indexation is never optimal. Moreover, even more surprisingly Result 2 For any level of ~; the value of = 0:88 maximizes steady state welfare. As shown in Figure, given ~ =, the change in steady state welfare from = 0:88 to = is admittedly quite small: from -56.706 to -56.743. In order to explain the intuition of the non optimality of full price indexation, we can follow the line of argument in King and Wolman (996). King and Wolman (996) focus their attention on the average mark-up in the economy. Generally speaking, we can think the average mark-up as a measure of the monopolistic distortion in the whole economy, i.e., a lower average mark-up should be associated with a higher welfare level. Moreover, recall that, like all the New Keynesian models, monopolistic competition implies that also in a exible price economy, the average mark-up is above one because of the monopolistic distortion. The average mark-up can be expressed as P t Pt = MC t ~P t ~P t MC t where MC t = nominal marginal costs, P t = aggregate price level and ~ P t = the optimal reset price. The average mark-up is hence given by two factors: ) the price adjustment gap, de ned as the ratio of the general price level to the price charged by resetting rms; 2) the marginal mark-up, de ned as the mark-up of the resetting rms. Recall that we are analyzing the steady state and that in ation is positive (i.e., 4.2%). In a full indexation environment all the prices and wages will be the same in a steady state. So there is no "price adjustment gap" and the average mark-up is equal to the marginal mark-up, in turn simply given by the Lerner coe cient. Whenever there is However, this change is bigger than the changes induced by changing the kind of monetary policy in the Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004) Table 2. This fact led us to investigate if there can be bigger welfare gain in changing the indexation parameters, rather than changing the Taylor rule parameters (see Ascari and Branzoli, 2006).! () 2

partial price indexation instead this is no longer true, and the steady state exhibits price dispersion. In this environment P t is lower than ~ P t and a price adjustment gap emerges. Indeed with partial indexation, positive in ation mechanically erodes the relative price set by rms in past periods. This is very simply implied by the steady state version of the equation that de nes the general price level P t = Z 0 P i;t 2 h di = =) = 4 ( )( ) + ( ) ( ) t P t + ( ) ~ P t i! 3 ~P t 5 P t =) ss P =) ~! t = ( )( ) P t (2) P Note that, other things equal, lower price indexation increases ~ t P t ; since rms will try to shield themselves from the erosion of relative prices. Thus the price adjustment gap increases, in turn decreasing the average mark-up in (), and increasing welfare. Here it is therefore the positive e ect of partial indexation: the lower ; the lower the price adjustment gap and the lower the average mark-up in the economy. The second e ect instead concerns the marginal mark-up, which is also a ected by partial indexation. Firms know that positive in ation erodes both their mark-up (since nominal marginal costs will increase with in ation) and their relative prices. This latter erosion would both increases their demand (which they have to satisfy by assumption) and decreases their per-unit pro ts. They thus react, by resetting a higher price when ~P they can, so that the lower the indexation parameter, the higher the ratio t MC t. Here is the negative e ect of a lower indexation on the average mark-up in the economy: the lower ; the higher the marginal mark-up and the higher the average mark-up in the economy: These are the two con icting forces acting in steady state. As displayed in Figure 3, for low levels of ; the second e ect dominates such that the average mark-up decreases with ; and therefore welfare is increasing with indexation. However, at a certain point ( = 0:88); the two e ects exactly compensate and then the rst e ect takes over, such that the average mark-up is now increasing, while welfare is instead decreasing with : Following the same argument, the second e ect instead always dominates with regard to wage indexation, given our calibration. To conclude, with positive trend in ation, partial price indexation can minimally correct the monopolistic distortion in the steady state, thereby increasing welfare. 3. Price indexation and price stickiness It would be interesting to look at the properties of the steady state de ned by the optimal combination of the two indexation parameters, particularly exploring the comparative statics with respect to some parameters. The most obvious one is the Calvo parameter of the price setting mechanism, because price indexation is only partial. The parameter is the probability of not being able to reset the price, and thus ( ) is the fraction of rms setting prices optimally each quarter. is set to 0.75 in Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004). 3

We expected welfare to be increasing with price exibility, that is, for a given (and ~), welfare would be decreasing with : Indeed = 0 means complete price exibility. This seems to be the case by looking at Figure 4 that plots welfare as and vary. The lower welfare level is by far given by the point ( =, = 0), as expected. However, welfare is, surprisingly enough, increasing in ; for certain values of : That is: in certain part of the surface in Figure 4, the higher price stickiness, the higher welfare. Generally, this holds for quite high values of ; as shown in Figure 5, and in particularly for = 0:88 (see Figure 6). Result 3 Given ~ = and = 0:88; steady state welfare is maximized for the maximum admissible level of price rigidity (i.e., = 0:993). 2 Indeed, given ~ = ; welfare is ever increasing in for values of > 0:76: Remarkably then, more price stickiness (i.e., higher values of ) can partially cure the monopolistic distortion, with substantial e ects on steady state welfare. 4 Conclusions This note shows that full price indexation is not optimal in the long-run in the New Keynesian model, because of monopolistic distortion. Note that the argument provided for the optimality of partial indexation is very di erent from the classical one in Gray (976). Indeed, we are simply analyzing the steady state of a microfounded model, without considering any stochastic supply or demand shocks, that were instead crucial for Gray (976) argument. Moreover, we show that more price stickiness may increase steady state welfare, if price indexation is partial. References Ascari, G. (2004). Staggered prices and trend in ation: Some nuisances. Review of Economic Dynamics 7, 642 667. Ascari, G. and N. Branzoli (2006). Optimal indexation and optimal operational monetary policy in the CEE model of the U.S. busineess cycle. mimeo, University of Pavia. Christiano, L. J., M. Eichenbaum, and C. L. Evans (2005). Nominal rigidities and the dynamic e ects of a shock to monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 3 (), 45. Gray, J. A. (976). Wage indexation: a macroeconomic approach. Journal of Monetary Economics 2, 22 235. King, R. G. and A. L. Wolman (996). In ation targeting in a st. louis model of the 2st century. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Quarterly Review, 83 07. Schmitt-Grohé, S. and M. Uribe (2004). Optimal operational monetary policy in the Christiano-Eichenbaum-Evans model of the U.S. business cycle. NBER wp No. 0724. 2 Given positive steady state in ation and partial indexation, there is a maximum value for ; such that the rst order condition for reset price is de ned (see Ascari, 2004). 4

Steady State Welfare 56.5 57 57.5 58 58.5 59 59.5 60 0.6 χ 0.4 0.2 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 χ tilde Figure Steady State Welfare 56.7 56.75 56.72 56.725 56.73 56.735 56.74 0.95 0.9 5 χ 0.75 0.7 0.65 0.9 0.92 0.94 0.96 0.98 χ tilde Figure 2 5

Average Mark up 0.6 0.65 0.7 0.75 5 0.9 0.95 ss welfare.200 56.7 56.75.2 56.72 56.725.2 56.73 56.735.999 χ (χ tilde = ) 56.74 0.6 0.65 0.7 0.75 5 0.9 0.95 χ (χ tilde = ) Figure 3 Steady State Welfare 56 58 60 62 64 66 68 0 0.2 0.4 α 0.6 0 0.2 0.4 χ 0.6 Figure 4 6

ss welfare Steady State Welfare 56.6 56.65 56.7 56.75 56.8 56.85 56.9 0.95 0.9 5 0.75 χ 0.7 0.65 2 4 α 6 8 0.9 Figure 5 56.62 56.63 56.64 56.65 56.66 56.67 56.68 56.69 56.7 56.7 56.72 0 0. 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.9 α (χ = 8) Figure 6 7