THE IMPACT OF RAISING CHILDREN ON RETIREMENT SECURITY

Similar documents
NRRI UPDATE SHOWS HALF STILL FALLING SHORT

THE IMPACT OF INTEREST RATES ON THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX

HOW DO INHERITANCES AFFECT THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX?

THE IMPACT OF INTEREST RATES ON THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX

HOW MUCH DOES HOUSING AFFECT RETIREMENT SECURITY? AN NRRI UPDATE

NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX: HOW MUCH LONGER DO WE NEED TO WORK?

DO INDIVIDUALS KNOW WHEN THEY SHOULD BE SAVING FOR A SPOUSE?

401(k) PLANS AND RACE

WHY DID POVERTY DROP FOR THE ELDERLY?

HOUSEHOLDS AT RISK : A CLOSER LOOK AT THE BOTTOM THIRD

HOW IMPORTANT IS MEDICARE ELIGIBILITY IN THE TIMING OF RETIREMENT?

HOW IMPORTANT ARE INHERITANCES FOR BABY BOOMERS?

HOW DOES WOMEN WORKING AFFECT SOCIAL SECURITY REPLACEMENT RATES?

IS PENSION INEQUALITY GROWING?

HOW MUCH TO SAVE FOR A SECURE

EMPIRICAL REGULARITY SUGGESTS RETIREMENT RISKS

THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX: AFTER THE CRASH

DOG BITES MAN: AMERICANS ARE SHORTSIGHTED ABOUT THEIR FINANCES

USING PARTICIPANT DATA TO IMPROVE 401(k) ASSET ALLOCATION

AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY

DO YOUNG ADULTS WITH STUDENT DEBT SAVE LESS FOR RETIREMENT?

HOW LONG DO UNEMPLOYED OLDER WORKERS SEARCH FOR A JOB?

HOW HAVE WORKERS RESPONDED TO OREGON S AUTO-IRA?

AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY

Are Retirees Falling Short? Reconciling the Conflicting Evidence

JOB TENURE AND THE SPREAD OF 401(K)S

THE IMPACT OF AGING BABY BOOMERS ON LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2007 REPORT IN PERSPECTIVE

CAN EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT EXPLAIN THE RISE IN LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION AT OLDER AGES?

WHY ARE OLDER WORKERS AT GREATER RISK OF DISPLACEMENT?

HOW DOES 401(K) AUTO-ENROLLMENT RELATE TO THE EMPLOYER MATCH AND TOTAL COMPENSATION?

IS WORKING LONGER A GOOD PRESCRIPTION FOR ALL?

IMPACT OF PUBLIC SECTOR ASSUMED RETURNS ON INVESTMENT CHOICES

Do Households Increase Their Savings When the Kids Leave Home?

ARE PEOPLE CLAIMING SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS LATER?

THE IMPACT OF INFLATION ON SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS

MODERNIZING SOCIAL SECURITY: HELPING THE OLDEST OLD

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2006 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

PENSION WEALTH AND INCOME: 1992,

SHOULD YOU CARRY A MORTGAGE INTO RETIREMENT?

HOW HAS THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AFFECTED THE CONSUMPTION OF RETIREES?

PENSION COVERAGE AND RETIREMENT SECURITY

DOES SOCIOECONOMIC STATUS LEAD PEOPLE TO RETIRE TOO SOON?

DO STATE ECONOMICS OR INDIVIDUAL CHARACTERISTICS DETERMINE WHETHER OLDER MEN WORK?

MEDICARE COSTS AND RETIREMENT SECURITY

ARE RETIREES FALLING SHORT? RECONCILING THE CONFLICTING EVIDENCE. Alicia H. Munnell, Matthew S. Rutledge, and Anthony Webb

DO INCOME PROJECTIONS AFFECT RETIREMENT SAVING?

EMPLOYERS (LACK OF) RESPONSE TO THE RETIREMENT INCOME CHALLENGE

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2014 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

ESTIMATING PENSION COVERAGE USING DIFFERENT DATA SETS

WHY DON T LOWER-INCOME INDIVIDUALS HAVE PENSIONS?

TRENDS AND ISSUES. Do People Save Enough for Retirement?

HOW RETIREMENT PROVISIONS AFFECT TENURE OF STATE AND LOCAL WORKERS

PUBLIC SECTOR WORKERS AND JOB SECURITY

Retirements At Risk: The Outlook for the United States

TRENDS IN RETIREMENT SECURITY BY RACE/ETHNICITY

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2018 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

IS ADVERSE SELECTION IN THE ANNUITY MARKET A BIG PROBLEM?

REDUCING DEFAULT RATES OF REVERSE MORTGAGES

MAKING YOUR NEST EGG LAST A LIFETIME

WILL MILLENNIALS BE READY FOR RETIREMENT?

The Role of Tax Incentives in Retirement Preparation

Is Debt Good or Bad for a Comfortable Retirement? Exploring the Relationship between Consumer Debt and Retirement Preparedness

SOCIAL SECURITY AND TOTAL REPLACEMENT RATES IN DISABILITY AND RETIREMENT. Mashfiqur R. Khan, Matthew S. Rutledge, and Geoffrey T.

A Look at the End-of-Life Financial Situation in America, p. 2

HOW MUCH DO OLDER WORKERS VALUE EMPLOYEE HEALTH INSURANCE?

THE IMPACT OF LEAKAGES ON 401(K)/IRA ASSETS

THE STATE OF PRIVATE PENSIONS: CURRENT 5500 DATA

THE STRUCTURE OF 401(k) FEES

WORKERS RESPONSE TO THE MARKET CRASH: SAVE MORE, WORK MORE?

STATE AND LOCAL PENSION COSTS: PRE- CRISIS, POST-CRISIS, AND POST-REFORM

center for retirement research

401(k) PLANS ARE STILL COMING UP SHORT

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2011 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

ARE EARLY CLAIMERS MAKING A MISTAKE? Alicia H. Munnell, Geoffrey T. Sanzenbacher, Anthony Webb, and Christopher M. Gillis. CRR WP July 2016

DO PUBLIC PENSIONS HELP RECRUIT AND RETAIN HIGH-QUALITY WORKERS?

WHY DO WOMEN CLAIM SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS SO EARLY?

WILL THE FINANCIAL FRAGILITY OF RETIREES INCREASE?

JUST THE FACTS On Retirement Issues JANUARY 2005, NUMBER 14

FIGURE 1: NATIONAL SAVING HAS PLUMMETED OVER PAST QUARTER CENTURY

DO PEOPLE PLAN TO TAP THEIR HOME EQUITY IN RETIREMENT?

GEOFFREY T. SANZENBACHER

HOW SENSITIVE IS PUBLIC PENSION FUNDING TO INVESTMENT RETURNS?

PENSION PARTICIPATION, WEALTH, AND INCOME: Alicia H. Munnell, Wenliang Hou, Anthony Webb, and Yinji Li. CRR WP July 2016

THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND STATE/LOCAL DEFINED BENEFIT PLANS

THE IMPACT OF PUBLIC PENSIONS ON STATE AND LOCAL BUDGETS

GUARDIANSHIP AND THE REPRESENTATIVE PAYEE PROGRAM. Anek Belbase and Geoffrey T. Sanzenbacher. CRR WP August 2017

JUST THE FACTS On Retirement Issues APRIL 2005, NUMBER 17

center for retirement research

PLANNING FOR RETIREMENT: THE ROLE OF 401(K)S IN RETIREMENT INCOME

What Replacement Rate Do Households Actually Experience in Retirement?

Program on Retirement Policy Number 1, February 2011

Falling Short: The Coming Retirement Crisis and What to Do About It

THE U.K. S AMBITIOUS NEW RETIREMENT SAVINGS INITIATIVE

HOW MUCH DO STATE ECONOMIC AND OTHER CHARACTERISTICS AFFECT LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION OF OLDER WORKERS?

CHILDREN AND HOUSEHOLD UTILITY: EVIDENCE FROM KIDS FLYING THE COOP. Norma B. Coe and Anthony Webb CRR WP

SOCIAL SECURITY AND TOTAL REPLACEMENT RATES IN DISABILITY AND RETIREMENT. Mashfiqur R. Khan, Matthew S. Rutledge, and Geoffrey T.

DO OLDER WORKERS FACE GREATER RISK OF DISPLACEMENT?

THE BEHAVIORAL AND CONSUMPTION EFFECTS OF SOCIAL SECURITY CHANGES. Wenliang Hou and Geoffrey T. Sanzenbacher. CRR WP September 2017

WHAT REPLACEMENT RATES DO HOUSEHOLDS ACTUALLY EXPERIENCE IN RETIREMENT? Alicia H. Munnell and Mauricio Soto*

Transcription:

September 2017, Number 17-16 RETIREMENT RESEARCH THE IMPACT OF RAISING CHILDREN ON RETIREMENT SECURITY By Alicia H. Munnell, Wenliang Hou, and Geoffrey T. Sanzenbacher* Introduction Children are expensive; they require food, clothing, childcare, and an education. So, one might think that households with children would end up less well prepared for retirement than those without. But raising children is temporary, and the lifecycle model used by economists suggests two ways that parents might not endanger their retirement. One option is for parents to keep household consumption steady over time, but sharply curtail spending on themselves when they have children at home. The other is to have households plan for higher consumption while the children are at home and lower consumption when the children leave and then in retirement. Either way households would accumulate enough wealth to maintain their standard of living in retirement. But households may not behave optimally; they may increase household spending when they have children and maintain spending at that elevated level even after the children leave home. In this case, households with children may be less prepared for retirement than those without. This brief uses the National Retirement Risk Index (NRRI) to assess the impact of having children on the retirement security of today s older working households. The NRRI is calculated by comparing households projected replacement rates retirement income as a percentage of pre-retirement income with target replacement rates that would allow them to maintain their standard of living. These calculations are based on the Federal Reserve s Survey of Consumer Finances, a triennial survey of a nationally representative sample of U.S. households. As of 2013, the NRRI showed that, even if households worked to age 65 and annuitized all their financial assets (including the receipts from reverse mortgages on their homes), more than half of households were at risk of falling short in retirement. The discussion proceeds as follows. The first section briefly describes the nuts and bolts of the NRRI. The second section discusses the potential impact of children on income, wealth, and retirement preparedness. The third section uses regression analysis to explore the actual impacts. The final section concludes that, in terms of retirement preparedness, having children leads to a moderate increase in the likelihood of being at risk for households in their 50s. However, the influence of children is considerably smaller than other factors, such as having an employer retirement plan. * Alicia H. Munnell is director of the at Boston College (CRR) and the Peter F. Drucker Professor of Management Sciences at Boston College s Carroll School of Management. Wenliang Hou is a senior research advisor at the CRR. Geoffrey T. Sanzenbacher is a research economist at the CRR. The CRR gratefully acknowledges Prudential Financial for its sponsorship of the National Retirement Risk Index.

2 The Nuts & Bolts of the NRRI Calculating the NRRI involves three steps: 1) projecting a replacement rate retirement income as a share of pre-retirement income for each household; 2) constructing a target replacement rate that would allow each household to maintain its pre-retirement standard of living in retirement; and 3) comparing the projected and target replacement rates to find the percentage of households at risk. Retirement income at age 65, which is defined broadly to include all of the usual suspects plus housing, is derived by projecting the assets that households will hold at retirement, based on the stable relationship between wealth-to-income ratios and age evident in the 1983-2013 Surveys of Consumer Finances (SCFs). As shown in Figure 1, wealth-to-income lines from each survey rest virtually on top of one another, bracketed by 2007 values on the high side and 2013 values on the low side. Figure 1. Ratio of Wealth to Income by Age from the Survey of Consumer Finances, 1983-2013 6 5 4 3 2 1 1983 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 2013 0 20-22 26-28 32-34 38-40 44-46 50-52 56-58 62-64 Source: Authors calculations based on U.S. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) (1983-2013). A calculation of projected replacement rates also requires income prior to retirement. The items that comprise pre-retirement income include earnings, the return on 401(k) plans and other financial assets, and imputed rent from housing. In essence, with regard to wealth, income in retirement equals the annuitized value of all financial and housing assets; income before retirement is simply the return on those same assets. 1 Average lifetime income then serves as the denominator for each household s replacement rate. Determining the share of the population at risk requires comparing projected replacement rates with the appropriate target rates. Target replacement rates are estimated for different types of households assuming that households spread their income so as to have the same level of consumption in retirement as they had before they retired. Households whose projected replacement rates fall more than 10 percent below the target are deemed to be at risk of having insufficient income to maintain their pre-retirement standard of living. The NRRI is simply the percentage of all households that fall more than 10 percent short of their target. In 2013, the year of the most recent SCF, the overall share at risk was 52 percent ranging from 59 percent for households in their 30s to 45 percent for households in their 50s (see Figure 2). Figure 2. Percentage of NRRI Households At Risk by Age Group, 2013 100% 80% 60% 40% 52% 59% 52% 45% Sources of retirement income that are not derived from SCF-reported wealth are estimated directly. For defined benefit pension income, the projections are based on the amounts reported by survey respondents who have already retired. For Social Security, benefits are calculated directly based on estimated earnings histories for each member of the household. 20% 0% All 30-39 40-49 50-59 Ages Source: Munnell, Rutledge, and Webb (2014).

Issue in Brief Potential Impact of Children on Income, Wealth, & Retirement Children can affect a household s well-being in retirement both by their direct effects on income and wealth and by the pattern of consumption over the household s lifecycle. 2 Income and Wealth In addition to the mother s foregone earnings, families spend money on food, clothing, childcare, and education for their children. Studies by the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) show that the cost for a family of four is 140 percent of that of two adults (see Figure 4). Figure 4. Household Costs of Children 200% 3 Researchers agree that parents divert considerable resources to their children when the children are young. These resources involve time out of the labor force usually, for the mother and direct expenditures on children. Even today the labor force participation rate of women with children is substantially below that of childless women. Similarly, when women with children work, they earn lower wages (see Figure 3). 150% 100% 50% 100% 120% 140% 160% Figure 3. Workforce Status and Earnings for Women Ages 25-64 with and without Children, 2013 a. Percentage of Women Working for Pay 100% 0% 2 adults 2 adults, 1 child 2 adults, 2 children 2 adults, 3 children Source: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (2012). 75% 50% 25% 73% 61% The bottom line is that households with children would be expected at the end of their work-lives to have less income and lower wealth. However, neither of these outcomes is necessarily related to their retirement preparedness, measured by their ability to maintain their pre-retirement standard of living. 0% No children Has children Retirement Preparedness b. Women s Median Earnings $60,000 $44,400 $40,000 $35,000 $20,000 $0 No children Has children Source: Authors calculations from the 2013 SCF. Analyses of retirement preparedness are typically based on the lifecycle model in which households maximize the expected utility of consumption over their lifetime. This approach means saving when young and living off those savings when old. Some researchers assume that the marginal utility of consumption the enjoyment that people derive from each additional dollar of spending does not vary with the number of children, so the household would choose a savings plan that provides level consumption over the lifecycle. On the other hand, if the marginal utility of consumption is higher when children are present, then households will optimally plan for

4 higher consumption when the children are at home and lower consumption after the children have left home and during retirement. Level consumption means that a household with constant earnings would save at a constant rate over its lifetime. This saving and the interest on accumulated assets allow households to maintain their high level of consumption in retirement (see optimal path 1 in Figure 5). In contrast, the assumption that households vary their consumption across the lifespan shows relatively low consumption before the children are born, high consumption when the children are at home, and low consumption before retirement when the children are gone ( optimal path 2 ). 3 Figure 5. Various Consumption Paths Households with Children Could Take Percentage of gross income 100% 80% 60% 40% 20% Optimal path 2 Suboptimal path Optimal path 1 Retirement Social Security 0% 25 35 45 55 65 75 85 90 Age Source: Authors illustration. The NRRI targets are based on the assumption that households optimally follow a path of level consumption (optimal path 1). This assumption seems valid given that recent studies show that households do not increase their contributions to 401(k)s the main vehicle through which people accumulate wealth for retirement in a meaningful way when the children leave home. 4 However, the reality is that people may not behave optimally. They may start out as if they are going to keep consumption steady, then increase their spending from that high level when they have children and never cut back when the children leave home (the suboptimal path in Figure 5). These households will not meet their target wealth accumulation.? Actual Impact of Children on Income, Wealth, & the NRRI The data for this analysis come from the 2013 SCF. The equation is run with three separate dependent variables: income, wealth, and percentage at risk (NRRI). The main independent variable of interest is the number of children. 5 The control variables consist of whether the household has two earners, education level (less than high school, high school, some college, or college graduate), whether the household head is covered by a defined benefit (DB) or defined contribution (DC) plan, and whether the household is saving for children s educational expenses. 6 Thus, the equation is as follows: Income, wealth, or percentage at risk = f (# children, two-earner household, education group, DB or DC coverage, saving for education) Income and the household s NRRI status are well defined, but the options for measuring wealth are numerous. We defined wealth comprehensively to include financial wealth, assets in DC plans, net housing wealth, and the pro-rated value of DB and Social Security wealth. Figure 6, which is based on data directly from the SCF rather than estimates from the NRRI, shows that households with children generally have lower wealth Figure 6. Percentage Reduction in Household Income and Wealth Associated with Each Child by Age Group Income Wealth -4.5% -3.7% -4.2% -2.8% -2.8% Note: Solid bars are statistically significant. Source: Authors calculations. -0.4% -10% -5% 0% 30-39 40-49 50-59 Ages

Issue in Brief 5 Figure 7. Estimated Effect of Selected Factors on Retirement Risk, Households Ages 50-59 Number of children 1.9% Two earners 17.6% High school 2.3% Education Some college 3.5% College -2.5% Retirement plan DB DC -40.5% -10.4% Saving for children's education -14.3% Note: Solid bars are statistically significant. Source: Authors calculations. -60% -30% 0% 30% and income, with some differences by age. Each child reduces household income by about 4 percent for households in their 30s, but the percentage reduction declines to virtually zero for older households and is not statistically significant. This pattern is consistent with the notion that mothers of young children reduce their labor force effort for a time and then return. 7 In terms of wealth, each child is associated with roughly 3-4 percent less wealth. 8 Given that more children means less wealth, one would expect that, for households in their 50s, having children would make them more likely to be at risk. The regression results show that, by the time households are in their 50s, each child increases the share of households at risk by 2 percentage points. This finding means that the NRRI for households with two children should be 4 percentage points higher than for a household with no children. To put the size of this effect in context, it is helpful to compare it to the effects of the control variables (see Figure 7, with full results in Appendix Table A-1). Children have a considerably smaller impact on a household s retirement risk than several of the controls. Having an employer retirement plan is very important, particularly a DB plan, which reduces the likelihood of being at risk by about 40 percentage points. 9 Interestingly, being a two-earner couple also has a substantial impact in the opposite direction it increases the likelihood of being at risk by about 18 percentage points. This result may reflect, in part lower Social Security replacement rates for two-earner couples, but the topic deserves further exploration. Saving for a child s education which adds to a household s wealth reduces the likelihood of being at risk by 14 percentage points. However, any such saving is earmarked for the children s needs rather than for retirement, so it makes households look more prepared for retirement than they actually are. 10 Overall, then, the comparison of the regression results suggests that children moderately increase a household s prospects of being at risk. In other words, households with children are somewhat more likely to behave suboptimally by increasing their spending when the children are at home and keeping their spending higher even after the children are gone. One final question is the extent to which the impact of children on retirement risk varies by income group. The coefficients of the children s variable in Figure 8 indicate that the middle-income group Figure 8. Increase in Retirement Risk with Each Child by Income Group, Ages 50-59, 2013 3% 2% 1% 0% 1.8% 2.5% 1.7% Low Middle High Source: Authors calculations.

6 is affected more than the others. This finding is consistent with the notion that most of the retirement wealth for low-income households is Social Security, which is not directly affected by the number of children, and that the retirement wealth of higher income households may be overstated by educational saving, despite the attempt to control for such saving. Conclusion Children are expensive, but that does not mean that parents will end up less well prepared for retirement. For example, if households cover the costs of childrearing by spending less on themselves, they can remain on track for retirement. However, households may not behave in this optimal way, instead raising their total spending when they have children and then trying to maintain this higher spending path even after the children are gone. These households may be headed for trouble in retirement, because they have not saved enough to maintain the standard of living to which they have grown accustomed.

Issue in Brief 7 Endnotes 1 For the measures of retirement income and preretirement income, both mortgage debt and nonmortgage debt are subtracted from the appropriate income components. 2 See, for example, Browning (1992). 3 The optimal path 2 approach is used in Scholz and Seshadri (2008, 2007); and Scholz, Seshadri, and Khitatrakun (2006). The difference in the levels of consumption in retirement between the two optimal paths is due to the timing of saving. Level consumption (optimal path 1) produces more saving earlier in the life cycle with more time to earn interest than when saving is deferred until after the children are gone. (In terms of lifetime utility of consumption, the two paths are equivalent because a household that chooses to follow optimal path 2 receives higher utility from consumption when the children are at home, which makes up for the lower level of consumption the household experiences in retirement.) For this analysis, the important point is that under either type of optimal savings behavior children should not affect retirement preparedness. 4 Dushi et al. (2015) find that U.S. households increase their saving by only a very small amount when children leave. Klos and Rottke (2013) show roughly similar results for German households. Coe and Webb (2010) look at the flip side consumption rather than saving for U.S. households and find that parents increase spending on themselves after their children leave. 6 The variable for educational saving was constructed by combining responses to three separate SCF questions: 1) in the next 5-10 years, do you have any foreseeable major expenses for education?; 2) are the education expenses for your child?; and 3) are you currently saving for these expenses or have you previously saved for them? 7 U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (2014) shows that women with young children have less labor force activity than women with older children. 8 In a study of married households, Plotnick (2009) found a similar pattern: households with children tended to have slightly more income and about 5 percent more wealth than those without children. 9 One might have thought that compensating differentials would have led to a negative relationship between pension coverage and income. That is, the employer decides on a compensation package and then divides that package between wages and fringe benefits. In actuality, research has shown that good jobs pay both higher wages and fringe benefits, so simple correlations between wages and pension coverage are always positive (see Gustman, Mitchell, and Steinmeier 1994). 10 Souleles (2000) found that households that save for college tend to start well in advance of when their childrens college expenditures occur. 5 In terms of the explanatory variables, a key issue is how to measure children. We chose the number of children for two reasons. First, the OECD data suggest that the burden of the second child is the same as the burden of the first child. Second, estimates using a quadratic form for children yielded inconsistent results across income groups.

8 References Browning, Martin. 1992. Children and Household Economic Behavior. Journal of Economic Literature 30(3): 1434-1475. Coe, Norma B. and Anthony Webb. 2010. Children and Household Utility: Evidence from Kids Flying the Coop. Working Paper 2010-16. Chestnut Hill, MA: at Boston College. Dushi, Irena, Alicia H. Munnell, Geoffrey T. Sanzenbacher, and Anthony Webb. 2015. Do Households Increase Their Savings When the Kids Leave Home? Working Paper 2015-26. Chestnut Hill, MA: at Boston College. Gustman, Alan L., Olivia S. Mitchell, and Thomas L. Steinmeier. 1994. The Role of Pensions in the Labor Market. International and Labor Relations Review 47(3): 417-438. Scholz, John Karl and Ananth Seshadri. 2007. Children and Household Wealth. Research Paper No. WP 2007-158. Ann Arbor, MI: Michigan Retirement Research Center. Scholz, John Karl, Ananth Seshadri, and Surachai Khitatrakun. 2006. Are Americans Saving Optimally for Retirement? Journal of Political Economy 114(4): 607-643. Souleles, Nicholas S. 2000. College Tuition and Household Savings and Consumption. Journal of Public Economics 77(2): 185-207. U.S. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Survey of Consumer Finances, 1983-2013. Washington, DC. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2014. Women in the Labor Force: A Databook. Washington, DC. Klos, Alexander and Simon Rottke. 2013. Saving and Consumption When Children Move Out. Available at: https://www.econstor.eu/handle/10419/79786 Munnell, Alicia H., Matthew S. Rutledge, and Anthony Webb. 2014. Are Retirees Falling Short? Reconciling the Conflicting Evidence. Working Paper 2014-16. Chestnut Hill, MA: Center for Retirement Research at Boston College. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. 2012. Quality Review of the OECD Database on Household Incomes and Poverty and the OECD Earnings Database: Part I. Paris, France. Plotnick, Robert D. 2009. Childlessness and the Economic Well-being of Older Americans. The Journals of Gerontology Series B: Psychological Sciences and Social Sciences 64(6): 767-776. Scholz, John Karl and Ananth Seshadri. 2008. Are All Americans Saving Optimally for Retirement? Presented at the 10th Annual Joint Conference of the Retirement Research Consortium in Washington DC, August 7-8.

APPENDIX

10 Appendix Table A-1. Estimated Effect of Selected Factors on Retirement Risk, Households Ages 50-59 Number of children 1.9%*** (0.003) Two earners 17.6%*** Education (.012) High school 2.3% (0.020) Some college 3.5% (0.021) College -2.5% Retirement plan Coefficient (0.021) DB -40.5%*** (0.013) DC -10.4%*** (0.012) Saving for children s education -14.3%*** (0.017) Observations 6148 R-squared 0.19 Note: Statistically significant at the 1-percent level (***). Source: Authors calculations.

RETIREMENT RESEARCH About the Center The mission of the at Boston College is to produce first-class research and educational tools and forge a strong link between the academic community and decision-makers in the public and private sectors around an issue of critical importance to the nation s future. To achieve this mission, the Center sponsors a wide variety of research projects, transmits new findings to a broad audience, trains new scholars, and broadens access to valuable data sources. Since its inception in 1998, the Center has established a reputation as an authoritative source of information on all major aspects of the retirement income debate. Affiliated Institutions The Brookings Institution Syracuse University Urban Institute Contact Information Boston College Hovey House 140 Commonwealth Avenue Chestnut Hill, MA 02467-3808 Phone: (617) 552-1762 Fax: (617) 552-0191 E-mail: crr@bc.edu Website: http://crr.bc.edu 2017, by Trustees of Boston College,. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that the authors are identified and full credit, including copyright notice, is given to Trustees of Boston College,. The research reported herein was supported by Prudential Financial. The findings and conclusions expressed are solely those of the authors and do not represent the opinions or policy of Prudential Financial or the at Boston College.