"Estimating the equilibrium exchange rate in Moldova"

Similar documents
Equilibrium exchange rate in Ukraine:

Relationship between Oil Price, Exchange Rates and Stock Market: An Empirical study of Indian stock market

REAL EXCHANGE RATES AND BILATERAL TRADE BALANCES: SOME EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE OF MALAYSIA

Impact of FDI and Net Trade on GDP of India Using Cointegration approach

The Fiscal Policy and the Stability of the nominal Sector: The Romanian Case (revisited version)

Outward FDI and Total Factor Productivity: Evidence from Germany

Asian Economic and Financial Review EMPIRICAL TESTING OF EXCHANGE RATE AND INTEREST RATE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS IN CHINA

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

In Search of a Dramatic Equilibrium: Was the Armenian Dram Overvalued?

What Are Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates?

Topic 10: Asset Valuation Effects

Exchange Rate Policy in Ukraine - Assessment and Recommendations -

Macroeconomic situation, bank lending and SME finance in Moldova

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

On the Determinants of Exchange Rate Misalignments

The Bilateral J-Curve: Sweden versus her 17 Major Trading Partners

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation

Impact of Devaluation on Trade Balance in Pakistan

6 The Open Economy. This chapter:

Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note*

THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON EMERGING ECONOMIES. A TVP-VAR APPROACH

esia/perkembangan/

Boston, USA, August 5-11, 2012

Volume 29, Issue 2. Measuring the external risk in the United Kingdom. Estela Sáenz University of Zaragoza

The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock

THE EFFECTIVENESS OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANNEL OF MONETARY POLICY TRANSMISSION MECHANISM IN SRI LANKA

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus)

AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF THE PUBLIC DEBT RELEVANCE TO THE ECONOMIC GROWTH OF THE USA

A causal relationship between foreign direct investment, economic growth and export for Central and Eastern Europe Zuzana Gallová 1

Testing the Stability of Demand for Money in Tonga

Recent developments in the euro area suggest. What caused current account imbalances in euro area periphery countries?

J-Curve, Oil Price, House Price and US-Canada Imbalance

THE TWIN DEFICIT HYPOTHESIS: THE CASE OF BULGARIA

Objectives of the lecture

The Real Business Cycle Model

The equilibrium real exchange rate: pros and cons of different approaches with application to Latvia

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

A Threshold Multivariate Model to Explain Fiscal Multipliers with Government Debt

Does Exchange Rate Volatility Influence the Balancing Item in Japan? An Empirical Note. Tuck Cheong Tang

A joint Initiative of Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität and Ifo Institute for Economic Research

Interactions between United States (VIX) and United Kingdom (VFTSE) Market Volatility: A Time Series Study

Sustainability of Current Account Deficits in Turkey: Markov Switching Approach

Understanding the behavioral equilibrium exchange rate model via its application to the valuation of Chinese renminbi

GLOBAL IMBALANCES FROM A STOCK PERSPECTIVE

ESTIMATING MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION OF BANGLADESH

Current Account Determinants for Oil- Exporting Countries

An Estimated Fiscal Taylor Rule for the Postwar United States. by Christopher Phillip Reicher

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

Exchange Rates and Inflation in EMU Countries: Preliminary Empirical Evidence 1

The Credit Cycle and the Business Cycle in the Economy of Turkey

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Access to External Finance by Industrial Companies under two scenarios: Westward vs. Eastward Integration

A Small Estimated Model (SEM) for New Zealand

THE CREDIT CYCLE and the BUSINESS CYCLE in the ECONOMY of TURKEY

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

An Investigation of Effective Factors on Export in Iran

Foreign direct investment and profit outflows: a causality analysis for the Brazilian economy. Abstract

The long-run relationship between the stock market and main macroeconomic variables in Poland

The effects of the real exchange rate on the trade balance: Is there a J-curve for Vietnam? A VAR approach.

Anexos. Pruebas de estacionariedad. Null Hypothesis: TES has a unit root Exogenous: Constant Lag Length: 0 (Automatic - based on SIC, maxlag=9)

Properties of the estimated five-factor model

NEW CONSENSUS MACROECONOMICS AND KEYNESIAN CRITIQUE. Philip Arestis Cambridge Centre for Economic and Public Policy University of Cambridge

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle

EC4100: Macroeconomic Policies in the Short Run

How can saving deposit rate and Hang Seng Index affect housing prices : an empirical study in Hong Kong market

Factor Affecting Yields for Treasury Bills In Pakistan?

Does the Unemployment Invariance Hypothesis Hold for Canada?

Aviation Economics & Finance

IMPACT OF MACROECONOMIC VARIABLE ON STOCK MARKET RETURN AND ITS VOLATILITY

Global and National Macroeconometric Modelling: A Long-run Structural Approach Overview on Macroeconometric Modelling Yongcheol Shin Leeds University

Does the J-Curve Phenomenon Exist in The Indonesia s Bilateral Trade Balances With Major Trading Countries?

MACROECONOMIC VARIABLES AND STOCK MARKET: EVIDENCE FROM IRAN

Return on Assets and Financial Soundness Analysis: Case Study of Grain Industry Companies in Uzbekistan

Macroeconometrics - handout 5

Chapter 11 CAPITAL FLOWS AND THEIR IMPLICATIONS FOR CENTRAL BANK POLICIES IN TAIWAN. by Hsiao Yuan Yu 1

Topic 8: Financial Frictions and Shocks Part1: Asset holding developments

ECONOMIC MONITOR MOLDOVA Issue 7 January 2018

1. Tests based on ratios to GDP data

Relationship between Inflation and Unemployment in India: Vector Error Correction Model Approach

Exchange Rate Pass-through in India

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Equilibrium Level of the Real Exchange Rate and the Duration and Magnitude of the Misalignments for Turkey

Inflation Stabilization and Default Risk in a Currency Union. OKANO, Eiji Nagoya City University at Otaru University of Commerce on Aug.

The Main Determinants of Inflation in Sri Lanka A VAR based Analysis. H. P. G. S. Ratnasiri. Abstract

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model

ECONOMIC MONITOR MOLDOVA Issue 8 June 2018

Estimating the Relationship between the Current Account, the Capital Account and Investment for India

Empirical Analysis of Private Investments: The Case of Pakistan

The Kalman Filter Approach for Estimating the Natural Unemployment Rate in Romania

Effects of FDI on Capital Account and GDP: Empirical Evidence from India

EXPLORING RESILIENCE OF THE LEAST DEVELOPED COUNTRIES IN THE FACE OF THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL

The Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate: Evidence from Turkey

A new approach for measuring volatility of the exchange rate

IMPACT OF MONETARY POLICY AND BALANCE OF PAYMENT ON PRICE STABILIZATION IN NIGERIA

India: Effect of Income and Exchange rate Elasticities on Foreign Trade. Anshul Kumar Singh

GLOBAL IMBALANCES FROM A STOCK PERSPECTIVE

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Financing Energy Efficiency in Buildings in Ukraine

The relation between financial development and economic growth in Romania

Transcription:

German Economic Team Moldova Technical Note [TN/01/2010] "Estimating the equilibrium exchange rate in Moldova" Enzo Weber, Robert Kirchner Berlin/Chisinău, September 2010

About the German Economic Team Moldova ("GET Moldova") The German Economic Team Moldova ("GET Moldova"), which is active in Moldova since 2010, advises the Moldovan government and other state authorities such as the National Bank of Moldova on a wide range of economic policy issues and on financial sector development. Our analytical work is presented and discussed during regular meetings with high-level decision makers. GET Moldova is financed by the German Federal Foreign Office. German Economic Team Moldova ("GET Moldova") c/o BE Berlin Economics GmbH Schillerstr. 59 D-10627 Berlin Tel: +49 30 / 20 61 34 64 0 Fax: +49 30 / 20 61 34 64 9 info@get-moldau.de www.get-moldau.de 2010 German Economic Team Moldova All rights reserved.

"Estimating the equilibrium exchange rate in Moldova" Authors Enzo Weber enzo.weber@wiwi.uni-regensburg.de +49 941 / 943 1952 Robert Kirchner kirchner@berlin-economics.com +49 30 / 20 61 34 64 2 Contents 1. Introduction 2. External-Sustainability Approach (ES) 3. Balance-of-Payments Approach (BoP) 4. Conclusions References Annex

1. Introduction The calculation of equilibrium exchange rates (EERs) plays a central role both in international economics and practical policy decisions. For fixed or managed exchange rate regimes, the importance of the EER concept is obvious, since it is needed to guide the determination of concrete numerical targets for the currency value. Notwithstanding, the EER notion is relevant for floating regimes, too. Are sharp movements in the external value of a currency an expression of changes in the respective underlying factors, or do they represent a misalignment? Such an analysis concerns the evaluation of the current level of the market exchange rate in regard of the perspectives for current account adjustments, imported inflation pressures or expected capital flows. Evidently, these topics are among the mostdiscussed points in open macroeconomics. Furthermore, EERs provide crucial information for the conduct of monetary policy. This discussion clarifies the considerable significance of empirical EER calculations for policy makers. Such calculations have been carried out by Weber, Kirchner and Giucci (2010), who employed several methods to quantify the EER of the Moldovan leu. However, due to its presentation format, this work did not include much reference to theory and methodological aspects of the estimations performed. This technical note fills this gap by concentrating on the methods behind our estimations. Having explained this in more detail, in the future other applied researchers are enabled to check the validity, perform similar calculations and update the results. The structure of the technical note is as follows: The following sections introduce and describe the different EER estimation procedures. The two main approaches can be roughly classified by their time horizon: While the External-Sustainability (ES) approach operates in a medium-term framework, the Balance-of-Payments (BoP) methodology offers a medium- to long-term perspective. Section 4 provides some discussion and concludes. 2. External-Sustainability Approach (ES) The ES approach focuses on capital flows, and here specifically on the external asset-liability position of a country. Even if in the short term, considerable disequilibria in the capital account are not uncommon, in the medium term a country s stock of external liabilities must settle down to a sustainable level. In particular, the current account balance must be compatible with stabilising the net foreign asset (NFA) position of an economy 1. The following steps need to be followed to arrive at an EER estimate using the ES concept: - First, a benchmark value for the NFA position must be chosen. For instance, this might be zero or the current value. - Second, it must be figured out which current account balance would stabilise the actual NFA position at the benchmark chosen in the medium run. - Third, the current account balance expected to prevail over the medium run must be calculated. 1 External sustainability requires that the intertemporal budget constraint of the economy is satisfied, i.e. the present value of future trade surpluses is sufficient to pay back the existing amount of outstanding external liabilities. See IMF (2006) for more on this. 1

- Fourth, an estimate for the necessary real exchange rate adjustment must be found, which would bring the current account to the NFA-stabilising level. The second step requires an equation that relates the NFA position to the current account. This equation is given by expressing the accumulation of NFA as the sum of net financial flows and changes in the valuation of outstanding assets: (1) NFA t = CAt + CGt + Rt. Here, CA t denotes the current account, CG t capital gains, and R t the residual, e.g. transfers or errors. We concentrate in the following on the link between NFA and the current account, and abstract from the remaining terms. Writing ratios to GDP in lower-case letters leads to the current account ca that stabilises the NFA position at nfa: g + π ( 1+ g)(1 + π) (2) = nfa. ca where g denotes the growth rate of real GDP and π is the inflation rate. Furthermore, the respective trade balance tb (goods, services, transfers) that is consistent with (2) is given by g r =, 1 + g (3) tb nfa where r is the real rate of return of external assets and liabilities, which are assumed to be equal. The third step can be assessed by taking the actual as the expected current account or by adopting some smoothing filter like a weighted arithmetic mean of the last observations. Alternatively, adjustments can be made to exclude the effect of the current state of the business cycle or other potential biases. In Weber et al. (2010), we proceeded without such an adjustment, since a preliminary examination does not reveal typical business cycle patterns in Moldovan GDP. However, seasonal effects were eliminated by the Census-X12 procedure. Concerning the fourth step, the question is by how much the exchange rate must change in order to achieve a given change in the current account. Evidently, the answer requires an estimate of the current account elasticity with respect to the exchange rate. In open macroeconomics, such a relationship is typically addressed within a J-Curve framework. We start with import and export functions, which typically have the real exchange rate and the income of the recipient country as their arguments. It follows that the current account, the difference between exports and imports, depends on domestic and foreign income and the real exchange rate. In Weber et al. (2010), we measure foreign income by the real GDPs of Moldova s major trading partners, i.e. alternatively of the European Union 2 and Russia. Furthermore, we use the 2 We use here the Euro area in our estimations, i.e. European Monetary Union (EMU). 2

respective bilateral real exchange rate (RER), Moldovan GDP and the ratio of exports to imports, all expressed in logs. Since all these variables are found to be non-stationary, the validity of the long-run current account relationship depends on the presence of cointegration. Using a Johansen (1995) Trace test, we find indeed one cointegrating relation on the 5% significance level among the four variables. In order to determine the current account RER elasticity, we set up a cointegrated vector autoregressive model (VAR) in vector error correction (VEC) form: (4) p yt = αβyt 1 + c + Γi yt i + i= 1 u t The VEC model represents both the long-run equilibrium between the endogenous variables in y t through the cointegrating vector β and the dynamic adjustment processes through the loadings vector α and the short-run dynamics given by the Γ i matrices 3. Within this system, we calculate the impulse response of the current account variable to a unit shock in the RER. That is, we suppose a hypothetical "+1"-shock in the exchange rate equation and trace the dynamic interactive effects in the system through time. The reaction of the current account can be seen in Figure 1. For both estimations (using Russia and EMU as trading partners, respectively), we arrive at very similar total elasticities that are equal to 0.61 and 0.55, respectively. Figure 1: Response of log (EX/IM) to One-Unit log (RER) Innovation Russia EMU 0.0-0.2 Elasticity.0 -.1 Elasticity -0.4 -.2-0.6 -.3 -.4-0.8 -.5-1.0 -.6-1.2 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 -.7 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 Time (measured in quarters) Source: Based on own estimations displayed in Table A.1 in the Annex In the last step, the elasticity is used to convert the required current account change, i.e. the difference between the NFA-stabilising and the actual current account balance, into the necessary adjustment of the REER. Thereby, we assume that this value applies equally to the nominal effective rate just as to the nominal bilateral rate, e.g. towards the US-dollar. 3 The estimation output is shown in Table A.1 in the Annex. 3

3. Balance-of-Payments Approach (BoP) The BoP approach 4 refers to the supply and demand for foreign exchange in the medium to long run. In general, the two major magnitudes under consideration are the current and the capital account. Therefore, the BoP broadens the scope of the ES method by considering equilibrium capital flows in addition to trade flows. The basic idea is that persistent capital account imbalances are compatible with a stable exchange rate in case equilibrium trade flows find their counterpart in sustainable net capital flows cf : (5) ca = cf For instance, emerging market economies are likely to receive on average positive net capital flows, attracted by higher returns on capital. Comparing ca with the actual (or some expected) current account yields the necessary change of the trade ratio. As in the ES approach, this can be converted into the required real exchange rate adjustment via the estimated elasticity. 4. Conclusions In this short technical note, we have reviewed the theory and methodology underlying the two EER estimation procedures that were used in Weber et al. (2010). First, the ES approach was introduced, concentrating on the compatibility of the current account balance with a stable NFA position. Second, the BoP concept additionally considered equilibrium capital flows that might balance persistent current account deficits. In Weber et al. (2010), the various procedures provided a range of relatively similar results for the Moldovan EER. However, substantial deviations cannot be excluded, underlining the need of carefully assessing the scope and plausibility of the estimates. Taking these caveats into account, the discussed approaches can nevertheless provide valuable guidance for policy decisions by systematically incorporating information on foreign debt and capital flows in the decision-making process. 4 This concept is closely related to the "macroeconomic balance" approach, see IMF (2006). For a more detailed description of the underlying theoretical concept, see Brook/Hargraves (2000). 4

References Brook, A.-M. / D. Hargreaves (2000): A macroeconomic balance measure of New Zealand's equilibrium exchange rate, Reserve Bank of New Zealand Discussion Paper Series DP2000/09. Frankel, J. (2005): On the Renminbi: The Choice between Adjustment under a Fixed Exchange Rate and Adjustment under a Flexible Rate, NBER Working Paper 11274. Goldstein, M. (2004): Adjusting China s Exchange Rate Policies, IIE Working Paper 04-1. Washington: Institute for International Economics. IMF (2006): Methodology for CGER Exchange Rate Assessments, IMF Research Department. Isard, P. / H. Faruqee (1998): Exchange Rate Assessment: Extensions of the Macroeconomic Balance Approach, Occasional Paper, No. 167, International Monetary Fund. Isard, P. / H. Faruqee / R. Kincaid / M. Fetherston (2001): Methodology for Current Account and Exchange Rate Assessment, Occasional Paper, No. 209, International Monetary Fund. Maeso-Fernandez F. / C. Osbat / B. Schnatz (2004): Towards the Estimation of Equilibrium Exchange Rate for CEE Acceding Countries: Methodological Issues and a Panel Cointegration Perspective, ECB Working Papers No. 353 Maslova, S. / M. Vogel (2008): EMEA FX: Finding new equilibria in a deleveraging world, Barclays Capital Client Research Note Weber, E. / R. Kirchner / R. Giucci (2010): The Moldovan Leu: Recent developments and assessment of the equilibrium exchange rate, German Economic Team Moldova, Policy Briefing 02/10 5

Annex Table A.1 Empirical Results for VEC Model Estimation (EMU) Sample (adjusted): 2001Q1 2009Q3 Included observations: 35 after adjustments Standard errors in ( ) & t-statistics in [ ] Cointegrating Eq: CointEq1 LOG(EX(-1)/IM(-1)) 1.000000 LOG(RER_EUR(-1)) 1.896771 (0.57181) [ 3.31712] LOG(GDP_MOL(-1)) 3.325186 (0.68005) [ 4.88965] LOG(GDP_EMU(-1)) 8.242601 (1.15505) [ 7.13615] C -275.9966 Error Correction: D(LOG(EX/IM)) D(LOG(RER_E UR)) D(LOG(GDP_M OL)) D(LOG(GDP_E MU)) CointEq1-0.307789 0.307123-0.347970 0.008630 (0.18855) (0.09693) (0.07999) (0.01147) [-1.63243] [ 3.16853] [-4.34994] [ 0.75270] D(LOG(EX(-1)/IM(-1))) -0.238337-0.189908 0.154943-0.003206 (0.22002) (0.11311) (0.09335) (0.01338) [-1.08325] [-1.67897] [ 1.65985] [-0.23960] D(LOG(EX(-2)/IM(-2))) 0.139416 0.048910 0.026514-0.021263 (0.19118) (0.09828) (0.08111) (0.01163) [ 0.72925] [ 0.49765] [ 0.32689] [-1.82894] D(LOG(RER_EUR(-1))) 0.244465-1.185735 0.921527-0.055445 (0.48483) (0.24924) (0.20570) (0.02948) [ 0.50423] [-4.75732] [ 4.48001] [-1.88056] D(LOG(RER_EUR(-2))) 0.261532-0.892295 0.780280-0.055896 (0.47539) (0.24439) (0.20169) (0.02891) [ 0.55014] [-3.65110] [ 3.86867] [-1.93352] D(LOG(GDP_MOL(-1))) -0.181350-1.394656 1.183182-0.076212 (0.58890) (0.30275) (0.24985) (0.03581) [-0.30795] [-4.60669] [ 4.73554] [-2.12811] D(LOG(GDP_MOL(-2))) 1.074875-0.846357 0.882154-0.088238 6

(0.68123) (0.35021) (0.28903) (0.04143) [ 1.57784] [-2.41669] [ 3.05216] [-2.12995] D(LOG(GDP_EMU(-1))) -3.521300-4.215191 0.537341 0.391442 (2.98467) (1.53438) (1.26630) (0.18150) [-1.17979] [-2.74716] [ 0.42434] [ 2.15667] D(LOG(GDP_EMU(-2))) 2.093290 1.217781 5.206249-0.110392 (3.03367) (1.55957) (1.28709) (0.18448) [ 0.69002] [ 0.78084] [ 4.04497] [-0.59838] C -0.010847-0.015869-0.001571 0.000596 (0.01769) (0.00910) (0.00751) (0.00108) [-0.61305] [-1.74467] [-0.20929] [ 0.55433] R-squared 0.419356 0.579107 0.703614 0.554786 Adj. R-squared 0.210324 0.427586 0.596915 0.394508 Sum sq. resides 0.209126 0.055269 0.037644 0.000773 S.E. equation 0.091461 0.047019 0.038804 0.005562 F-statistic 2.006183 3.821947 6.594377 3.461414 Log likelihood 39.94006 63.22771 69.94865 137.9391 Akaike AIC -1.710860-3.041583-3.425637-7.310805 Schwarz SC -1.266475-2.597198-2.981252-6.866420 Mean dependent -0.011638-0.006675-0.001758 0.001768 S.D. dependent 0.102922 0.062146 0.061119 0.007148 Determinant resid covariance (dof adj.) 4.65E-13 Determinant resid covariance 1.21E-13 Log likelihood 321.8426 Akaike information criterion -15.87672 Schwarz criterion -13.92142 Source: Own estimations 7