EICT Microsimulations for New Public Policy Initiatives for Mexico to tackle poverty

Similar documents
2 YEARS OF NOPOOR RESEARCH

Ageing and employment policies: Ireland

Income, pensions, spending and wealth

V. MAKING WORK PAY. The economic situation of persons with low skills

The Canadian Pension System

Unemployment: Benefits, 2010

Exiting Poverty: Does Sex Matter?

Labor Supply and Taxation in Europe

Assessing Developments and Prospects in the Australian Welfare State

Invalidity: Benefits a)

BC CAMPAIGN 2000 WHAT IS CHILD POVERTY? FACT SHEET #1 November 24, 2005

Ways to increase employment

THE SOCIOECONOMIC GRADIENT IN HEALTH: THE ROLE OF INTRA-HOUSEHOLD RESOURCE ALLOCATION AND DECISION-MAKER S GENDER

Chapter 2: Twenty years of economy and society: Italy between the 1992 crisis and the current difficult economic situation

Erratum to: Determinants of self-employment survival in Europe

Workforce participation of mature aged women

CHAPTER IV: LABOUR FORCE STATUS

The Distributional Impact of Public Services in Europe

Social Expenditure in Japan: Trends and Backgrounds

Exiting poverty : Does gender matter?

Do Conditional Cash Transfers (CCT) Really Improve Education and Health and Fight Poverty? The Evidence

The role of an EMU unemployment insurance scheme on income protection in case of unemployment

How to write research papers on Labor Economic Modelling

THE ABOLITION OF THE EARNINGS RULE

Statistical annex. Sources and definitions

DEMOGRAPHICS AND MACROECONOMICS

Invalidity: Benefits (I), 2002 a)

OECD HEALTH SYSTEM CHARACTERISTICS SURVEY 2012

BC CAMPAIGN FACT SHEETS

Joint Retirement Decision of Couples in Europe

17 January 2019 Japan Laurence Boone OECD Chief Economist

GREECE Overview of the system

Poverty, Inequality, and Discrimination. Wen-Jui Han New York University

Conceptualizing and Measuring Poverty. Julia B. Isaacs Urban Institute Senior Fellow and IRP Research Affiliate June 12, 2018

8-Jun-06 Personal Income Top Marginal Tax Rate,

Older workers: How does ill health affect work and income?

Is the Western Welfare State Still Sustainable?

March Canada s Retirement Income System

Income and Wealth Inequality A Lack of Equity

GREECE. 1. Overview of the system

Social Protection and Social Inclusion in Europe Key facts and figures

IV. FISCAL IMPLICATIONS OF AGEING: PROJECTIONS OF AGE-RELATED SPENDING

The EITC: What Have Economists Learned? Kartik Athreya, Dec 8 th, 2014

Income and Wealth Inequality in OECD Countries

Portability of pension rights and taxation of pension schemes in the EU

Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare Statistics and Information Department

Effective Anti-poverty Programs in the U.S

THE EFFECT OF DEMOGRAPHIC AND SOCIOECONOMIC FACTORS ON HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS* Luísa Farinha** Percentage

Extract from Divided We Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising

Lecture 10. Welfare State Expenditure ANDREEA STOIAN, PHD DEPARTMENT OF FINANCE AND CEFIMO

Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity in the OECD

EU Survey on Income and Living Conditions (EU-SILC)

Invalidity: Benefits a) (II), 2010

Social Policy Research Unit FINANCIAL INCENTIVES AND MOTHER S EMPLOYMENT: A COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE

Chartbook of International Labor Comparisons: The Americas, Asia/Pacific, Europe

Poverty, Inequality and the Welfare State

Redistribution and Tax Expenditures: The Earned Income Tax Credit

HOUSING BENEFITS IN THE CHILD BENEFIT PACKAGE IN 22 COUNTRIES

A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD, 2017

Can Universal Basic Income solve future Income Security Challenges?

The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, 13 th September 2018.

SELECTED MAJOR SOCIAL SECURITY PENSION REFORMS IN EUROPE, Source: ISSA Databases

10% 10% 15% 15% Caseload: WE. 15% Caseload: SS 10% 10% 15%

Married Women s Labor Force Participation and The Role of Human Capital Evidence from the United States

AUSTRIA To qualify, workers must have worked at least one out of the last two years.

Key strategic issues for the wider social development sector

Enhancing Gender Equality in the Japanese Labour Market

INSTITUTIONS AND GROWTH

Is Government the Problem or the Solution to U.S. Labor Market Challenges?

HEALTH LABOUR MARKET TRENDS IN OECD COUNTRIES

Women in the Labor Force: A Databook

25/11/2014. Health inequality: causes and responses: action on the social determinants of health. Why we need to tackle health inequalities

International Natural Gas Tariff Comparison for Residential and Industrial Customers June 2011

Labour Force Participation in the Euro Area: A Cohort Based Analysis

Effective Tax Rates on Employee Stock Options in the European Union and the USA

Social Determinants of Health: employment and working conditions

Social Situation Monitor - Glossary

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2016

Fertility Decline and Work-Life Balance: Empirical Evidence and Policy Implications

STATISTICS. Taxing Wages DIS P O NIB LE E N SPECIAL FEATURE: PART-TIME WORK AND TAXING WAGES

Second Quarter Trading Update 9 July 2010

Widow s, Widower s or Surviving Civil Partner s Contributory Pension. Frequently Asked Questions

SPAIN According to the Centre for Tax and Policy and Administration, the 2007 AW level is EUR

QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS ABOUT THE EARNED INCOME TAX CREDIT TAX YEAR 2010

Facts and Figures 2005

APPENDIX C SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS

INSTITUTO NACIONAL DE ESTADÍSTICA. Descriptive study of poverty in Spain Results based on the Living Conditions Survey 2004

1. ECONOMIC ACTIVITY

education (captured by the school leaving age), household income (measured on a ten-point

Prerequisites for Active Ageing

Can low-income countries afford social protection?

The Case for Fundamental Tax Reform: Overview of the Current Tax System

Estimating Rates of Return of Social Protection

Plum Superannuation Fund

Mind the Gap: Disentangling Credit and Liquidity in Risk Spreads *

Statistical Annex ANNEX

Indebted households in the euro area: a micro perspective using the EU-SILC

European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (EU-SILC)

Child Care Expenses Deduction for 2017

Swedish Fiscal Policy. Martin Flodén, Laura Hartman, Erik Höglin, Eva Oscarsson and Helena Svaleryd Meeting with IMF 3 June 2010

Transcription:

EICT Microsimulations for New Public Policy Initiatives for Mexico to tackle poverty Araceli Ortega Díaz Tecnológico de Monterrey Sabbatical Researcher at Universidad Autónoma de Madrid 12 June 2017

This paper estimates a Heckman correction equation to perform simulations of an earned income tax credit (EITC) program for single mothers, using an income and expenditure household survey to assess the poverty reduction. The results show that poverty decreases at least four percentage points more with this program than with the current cash transfer program PROSPERA, and at half cost. In addition an income tax credit program fosters women formal employment, increase government revenue and may promotes skills, concluding that this is a better strategy for tackling extreme poverty in a sustainable way, and at lower public cost.

Motivation This study main s motivation emerged from the fact that after 19 years of using cash transfers in Mexico, and not graduating people out of poverty it is necessary to move to programs that can effectively graduate them in a more sustainable and inclusive way. Developed countries like Canada, United States, Austria, Australia, Belgium, Finland, France, Finland, Germany, Greece, Italy, Netherlands, New Zealand and the UK have stablished programs with employments components that fight poverty more effectively than cash transfers due to their influence in generating sustainable income. One of these programs is the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC), implemented since 1975 in United States, the New Zeeland s Working for Families Tax Credit in 1984 and the UK s Working Tax Credit in 1999. (Eissa, Kleven, & Kreiner, 2008b)

Why suggesting EITC and not more Cash transfers? Graph 1. Mexican labor force by their employability status, millions of people People do work in México, but they do it informally, more tan 60% of our labor force is informal.

One barrier for women to enter labor force is the number of children. Graph 2. Single women who work as a proportion of the total single women, 14 year old or more, according to the number of children born alive to them. 0.72 0.67 0.62 0.57 0.52 0.47 0.42 1 child 2 child 3 child 4 child 5 or more chidren Source: Author s own elaboration using ENOE quarterly data. When the number of children increase from 2 to 3, 4 or 5 the female labor participation decreases.

One condition to work is skills. Table 1. Average years of schooling of single mothers a by size of locality according to contractual situation. Number of inhabitants Employment status Less than 2 500 2,500 to 14,999 15,000 to 99,999 100,000 and more Unemployed 4.0 4.7 6.6 9.6 Employed 6.0 7.8 8.2 10.6 Difference 2.1 3.1 1.7 1.0 a: Single mothers include unmarried, divorced and widow women without the presence of a male couple. Source: Own estimation with data ENIGH 2014 Employed single/alone women with children in different geographical areas have more years of years of schooling on average. Whether it is a requirement to work or it is and effect of working is out of the scope of this papers, but it is observed that working women has at least 1 years of schooling more.

In fact there are women in poverty conditions that work Table 2. Distribution of women by employment status and poverty Unemployed Employed Total Food poverty Non-poor 85.0 85.7 85.5 Poor 15.0 14.3 14.5 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 Capabilities poverty Non-poor 77.9 78.0 78.0 Poor 22.1 22.0 22.0 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 Patrimony poverty Non-poor 53.0 55.2 54.6 Poor 47.0 44.8 45.4 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 Source: Own elaboration with data from ENIGH 2014 Taking into account the widest definition f poverty (patrimony), it is observed that whether women are employed of unemployed there is still poverty, therefore any alternative program to cash transfers that offers employment should be

3. CASH TRANSFERS PROGRAM Table 3. PROSPERA Beneficiaries Population in 2012 Poor Beneficiaries Components Impacts No impact 115 million Mexicans 19.7% in food poverty (22.66 million people) 28% in capabilities poverty (32.2 million people) 52.3% in patrimony poverty (60.15 million people) 5.2 million Families (25 million people.) 1. Enrolment and attendance: Primary, Secondary and Upper secondary. Higher education from September 2014. 2. Basic Health Services 3. Nutrition Increase in school enrolment and attendance, but low performance. Increase in terminal efficiency Educational quality, employability and leave poverty Source: Authors 'own elaboration

Graph 4. PROSPERA budget (right) and Families supported (left) Source: Own elaboration using data from 2nd Government Report, 2013-2014.

Income / Consumption 4. Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) Graph 5: Effect of EITC and CCT on budget constrain Phase out w(1-t) Flat region w C Phase in w(1+t) B A Hours worked/ Leisure 0 Before EICT After CCT After EICT

5. Simulation Methodology The methodology of (Eissa et al., 2008b) is followed to estimate an equation that identifies women with characteristics that are likely to be incorporated in the Mexican labour force, these characteristics are related to schooling level, experience, age, geographical area and number of children. To predict the labour income of those that do not work a wage equation in logs using Heckman (1979) selection equation is estimated. Estimating this equation corrects the bias caused by the decision of participating in the labour force. Based on Heckman, the first stage consists in estimating a Probit model of labor participation: Prob S i = 1 Z i = Φ Z i γ S equals one for those who work, and Z is a vector of socioeconomic variables that determine whether the person would work or not. In the second stage consist in estimating the amount of wage. E Y i X i, Z i, S i = 1 = X i β + ρλ Z i γ, con λ Z i γ = ϕ Z iγ Φ(Z i γ) For those who do not work we assume a distribution of the error with zero mean and variance equal to the variance of the error of people that work.

The simulation consists in four consecutive stages First. Once the person works, the taxable income and the amount of tax that each person should pay is calculated because the EITC is based on the wage and the rest of the taxable income. Table 4 shows the two official definitions of taxable income by two Mexican government institutions: the Treasury (SHCP) and the National Council of Evaluation of the Social Policy (CONEVAL), the latter is the institution in charge of calculating the official poverty measures, and for that duty, it has to calculate an official income measure of the households. Therefore, the net income of households I calculated according to CONEVAL, and the tax rates calculated using the SHCP official laws. Net income Gross income Investments income CONEVAL Interests from fixed terms Monetary income plus the non investments, interests from loans, Monetay income plus the non monetary income, minus the gifts interests from saving accounts monetary income. given by the household. and yields from bonds and warrants. SHCP Labor income from professional activities and rentals, income from corporate activities and interests, (pp.96). Labor income, income from professional activities and rentals, income from corporate activities, interests and contributions to social security, (pp 95). Interest on fixed maturities, from savings accounts and loans, (pp. 97).

The simulation consists in four consecutive stages The second step consists in calculating the annual amount of credit to be reimbursed to those female workers that accomplish the EITC requirements based on age, number of children and income. In the third stage, once net income and the income tax to be paid are calculated, the amount of tax credit is estimated and the beneficiaries of the program identified. There are two strong assumptions. First, that there exists labour demand for women who want to work. Second, it is assumed that the costs of participating in the labour force are zero, this is an strong assumption and is extensively discussed in (Eissa et al., 2008b). If women is selected to work, the household labour income is the sum of workers wage and the amount of EITC received.

Table 9. Heckman selection model Table 8. Women alone, widow, single and divorce Civil Status Member type Head Alone Total Divorced 1,970,777 240,199 2,210,976 Widow 989,435 176,080 1,165,515 Single 827,253 291,712 1,118,965 Total 3,787,465 707,991 4,495,456 Source: Own elaboration using ENIGH 2014 This paper focus on single mothers, this means women in working age that are single, widow or divorced and there is not a male partner in the household that provides income for them, and their low income made them eligible to be EICT beneficiaries. In the case of eligible women that do not work, the labour participation probability is used to select them, if it is higher than 0.5 the person is assumed to enter the labour forceprob S EITC = 1 0.5, and receive EITC. Variable Natural logarithm of annual wage per hour Indicator person working Schooling 0.109 0.003 (15.29)** -0.3 Experience -0.009-0.61 Experience squared 0-1.48 Indicator rural areas -0.265 0.146 (3.54)** -1.64 Age 0.2 (7.88)** Age squared -0.003 (9.19)** Annual labour income realized by other household members 0-0.77 Other income recipients -0.605 (4.84)** Widow -0.368 (2.86)** Separated or divorced -0.117-1.11 Children with disabilities 0.194-1.2 Children from 0 to 2 years -0.345-1.85 Children 3 to 5 years -0.105-0.74 Children from 6 to 12 years 0.005-0.06 Members with 65 years or more 0.058-0.37 Number of household members 0.271 (4.50)** Constant 2.01-2.597 (9.72)** (4.83)** Observations 2144 2144 t statistics in parentheses * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

6. Results Table 10. Results of simulation for employment Employment Status before EICT Persons Percentage Women not working 1,222,590 27.2% Women working 3,272,866 72.8% without payment** 888,111 27.1% with payment 2,384,755 72.9% Total 4,495,456 100% Employment Status after EICT Persons Percentage Women not working 737,362 16.4% Women working 3,758,094 83.6% without payment** 888,111 23.6% with payment 2,869,983 76.4% non- beneficiaries of EICT 79,052 2.8% beneficiaries of EICT 2,790,931 97.2% Total 4,495,456 100% Inserted to labour force 485,228 10.8% ** There is a variety of cases of women who declare working and received No payment this category should be studied further.

6. Results Finally, the net income of the family is calculated. This calculation is done for four simulations; 1) for the family non-receiving neither PROSPERA nor EITC, 2) receiving just PROSPERA, 3) receiving EITC and 4) receiving both. Table 11. Poverty measures with and without transfers Income Poverty Measure Net Income calculation Food Capabilities Patrimony Without CCT nor EITC 16.3% 23.9% 46.4% With Prospera 14.5% 22.0% 45.4% With EITC 10.7% 16.1% 32.3% With Prospera and EITC 9.0% 14.6% 31.3% Source: Author s own elaboration. The population of single mothers and women alone have a total poverty of 46.4%, PROSPERA would only decrease 1 percentage point their poverty, whereas EITC would decrease in 14.1 percentages points the poverty. And if both are combined poverty would decrease 15.1 percentage points.

6. Results EITC could be a better option for the government to tackle poverty than a then current cash transfer program Prospera, mainly for the following reasons: Cost less than Prospera Poverty reduction is faster and decrements are higher (14.1 percentages points). It is more sustainable as is people acquire more skills while working, as well as social benefits because they work in the formal sector. Workers contribute to tax and the pensions system, making it more sustainable. May create sense of pride by being productive and actively participating in the country s economy and diminishes stereotypes.