Journal of Cooperatives

Similar documents
= 500 4q. Some Applications of Differentiation Single Variable Case

Competitive Firms in the Long-Run

Chapter 10 THE PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM COMPETITIVE MODEL. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik ( December 29, 2008

Chapter 11 Online Appendix:

Economics 307: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory A Brief Mathematical Primer

Aggregate Supply and Demand

Econ Honors: Midterm 2 (Anthony Yuen) November 14, 2007

Notes on a Basic Business Problem MATH 104 and MATH 184 Mark Mac Lean (with assistance from Patrick Chan) 2011W

Assignment 2 (part 1) Deadline: September 30, 2004

Marginal Revenue, Marginal Cost, and Profit Maximization pp

Online Appendix A to chapter 16

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

EconS Oligopoly - Part 3

A Perfectly Competitive Market. A perfectly competitive market is one in which economic forces operate unimpeded.

Keynesian Theory (IS-LM Model): how GDP and interest rates are determined in Short Run with Sticky Prices.

Problem Set #2. Intermediate Macroeconomics 101 Due 20/8/12

Chapter 4 Topics. Behavior of the representative consumer Behavior of the representative firm Pearson Education, Inc.

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY Department of Civil and Environmental Engineering

Chapter 4. Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work- Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization. Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

Answer ALL questions from Section A and ONE question from Section B. Section A weighs 60% of the total mark and Section B 40% of the total mark.

Final Exam - Solutions

ECON 312/302: MICROECONOMICS II Lecture 6: W/C 7 th March 2016 FACTOR MARKETS 1 Dr Ebo Turkson. Chapter 15. Factor Markets Part 1

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

Chapter 21. The Monetary Policy and Aggregate Demand Curves

UVic Econ 103C with Peter Bell Review for Final Exam Final Lecture

ECO 2013: Macroeconomics Valencia Community College

Business Economics Managerial Decisions in Competitive Markets (Deriving the Supply Curve))

Week #7 - Maxima and Minima, Concavity, Applications Section 4.4

Econ 110: Introduction to Economic Theory. 10th Class 2/11/11

I. More Fundamental Concepts and Definitions from Mathematics

ECON 103C -- Final Exam Peter Bell, 2014

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Perloff (2014, 3e, GE), Section

CEMARE Research Paper 167. Fishery share systems and ITQ markets: who should pay for quota? A Hatcher CEMARE

Solutions to Extra Business Problems

Math: Deriving supply and demand curves

Perfect Competition Model: where does it apply in PICs

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 9 THE COSTS OF PRODUCTION

Faculty: Sunil Kumar

0 $50 $0 $5 $-5 $50 $35 1 $50 $50 $40 $10 $50 $15 2 $50 $100 $55 $45 $50 $35 3 $50 $150 $90 $60 $50 $55 4 $50 $200 $145 $55 $65

b) The first secret of happiness is consuming on the Budget line, that is the condition That is

GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 3 November 2012

ECONOMICS 207 SPRING 2008 LABORATORY EXERCISE 11

6. The Aggregate Demand and Supply Model

Foundational Preliminaries: Answers to Within-Chapter-Exercises

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Solutions to Assignment #2

1 Maximizing profits when marginal costs are increasing

Model Question Paper Economics - I (MSF1A3)

Final Term Papers. Fall 2009 ECO401. (Group is not responsible for any solved content) Subscribe to VU SMS Alert Service

Print last name: Solution Given name: Student number: Section number

Microeconomic Analysis

Open Math in Economics MA National Convention 2017 For each question, E) NOTA indicates that none of the above answers is correct.

Final Term Papers. Fall 2009 (Session 03a) ECO401. (Group is not responsible for any solved content) Subscribe to VU SMS Alert Service

2 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing

Chapter 1: Monopoly II

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 5

LINES AND SLOPES. Required concepts for the courses : Micro economic analysis, Managerial economy.

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM Welfare Analysis

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

Derivations: LR and SR Profit Maximization

A Model of Room Rentals in a Seasonal Hotel Illustrating Monopolistic Competition

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

Commerce and Economics

8a. Profit Maximization by a competitive firm: a. Cost and Revenue: Total, Average and Marginal

Intermediate microeconomics. Lecture 3: Production theory. Varian, chapters 19-24

Microeconomics 2nd Period Exam Solution Topics

Chapter 8 COST FUNCTIONS. Copyright 2005 by South-western, a division of Thomson learning. All rights reserved.

Sample for Second Midterm Exam Answer Key

Economics Honors Exam 2008 Solutions Question 1

Objectives AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

The Theory of the Firm

The Solow Model and Standard of Living

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 5

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

PROBLEM SET 3. Suppose that in a competitive industry with 100 identical firms the short run cost function of each firm is given by: C(q)=16+q 2

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

Cost Minimization and Cost Curves. Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 3.1a, 3.2a-b, 4.1

Question 1: Productivity, Output and Employment (30 Marks)

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

Modelling Economic Variables

Economics 386-A1. Practice Assignment 2. S Landon Fall 2003

Question 1: Productivity, Output and Employment (20 Marks)

Final Exam. Figure 1

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Leader: Shealyn Course: Econ 101 Instructor: Peter Orazem Date: April 17, 2012

Monetary Approach to Exchange Rates

Perverse General Equilibrium Effects of Price Controls

AP Econ Practice Test Unit 5

University of Toronto July 21, 2010 ECO 209Y L0101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2

Mikroekonomia B by Mikolaj Czajkowski. MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

Exam #2 Review Questions (Answers) ECNS 303 October 31, 2011

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Microeconomics, Questions 1-2

Consumer Budgets, Indifference Curves, and Utility Maximization 1 Instructional Primer 2

Transcription:

Journal of Cooperatives Volume 28 214 Pages 36 49 The Neoclassical Theory of Cooperatives: Mathematical Supplement Jeffrey S. Royer Contact: Jeffrey S. Royer, Professor, Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Nebraska Lincoln, jroyer@unl.edu Copyright and all rights therein are retained by author. Readers may make verbatim copies of this document for noncommercial purposes by any means, provided that this copyright notice appears on all such copies.

The Neoclassical Theory of Cooperatives: Mathematical Supplement Jeffrey S. Royer This supplement presents mathematical epressions of the models of the farm supply cooperative described in Part I and the marketing cooperative described in Part II. Price and output solutions are derived for firms that maimize profit, cooperatives that maimize member returns, and cooperatives that handle whatever quantity of products members choose to purchase or deliver. Those solutions are then compared to the solutions for the maimization of economic welfare to determine the conditions under which profitmaimizing firms and cooperatives are efficient in an allocative sense. Keywords: Cooperatives, farm supply cooperatives, marketing cooperatives, processing cooperatives, neoclassical theory, mathematical models, economic welfare Introduction Here mathematical models of a farm supply firm and a processing firm are presented to support the descriptive and graphical analyses included in Parts I and II. Price and output solutions are derived for the IOF (investor-owned firm) objective of maimizing profit and the cooperative objective of maimizing member returns. Solutions also are derived for cooperatives that handle whatever quantity of products members choose to purchase or deliver. Those solutions are then compared to the solutions for the maimization of economic welfare to determine the conditions under which profit-maimizing firms and cooperatives are efficient in an allocative sense. The material in this supplement should be appropriate for graduate students, advanced undergraduate students, and others with elementary skills in calculus. A Model of a Farm Supply Firm Assume that agricultural producers employ two inputs in the production of a single product according to the following production function: q= qy (, ) (1) Jeffrey S. Royer is professor, Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Nebraska Lincoln. The author appreciates helpful comments by Richard Seton in his review of an earlier version of this article.

Vol. 28 [214] No. 1 37 where q is the quantity of the product and and y represent the levels of the two inputs. 1 Producer profits can be represented as π = pqy (, ) r ry y (2) where p is the price producers receive for the product and r and r y are the prices they pay for inputs and y. 2 Producers maimize profits according to the following first-order conditions: π q = p r = (3) and π q = p ry = y y (4) where the terms p( q ) and p( q y) represent the marginal value products of and y. To maimize profits, producers will employ each input at the level where its marginal value product is equal to its price. Solving equations (3) and (4) simultaneously for and y and summing over all producers yields the input demand functions: and = r (, r, p) (5) y y= yr (, r, p). (6) y The demand for each input is a function of the prices of both inputs and the output. 3 Now consider a farm supply firm that specializes in the production of input. Its profit can be defined as Π= r ( ) ( ) c (7)

38 Journal of Cooperatives Figure 1. Price and output solutions for farm supply firms given a downward-sloping demand curve where r ( ) is a convenient form for representing the inverse input demand function r = r( r, y, p), which is determined by solving equation (5) for r in terms of. The term c ( ) represents the total cost of producing. If the input supplier is a profit-maimizing firm, its first-order condition is dπ d [ ] = r ( ) + r ( ) c ( ) =, (8) which implies that the input supplier will maimize profit by producing at the level where its marginal revenue from the sale of is equal to the marginal cost of producing, 4 represented by the quantity 1 in figure 1. Net consider a farm supply cooperative that maimizes member returns, including its own earnings, which are returned to members as patronage refunds. Assume all producers are members. Then the cooperative s objective function can be written

Π+ π = r ( ) c( ) + p q(, y) r ( ) r y y = p q(, y) c( ) r y y Vol. 28 [214] No. 1 39 where here π represents the sum of the profits of the individual producers in equation (2). The corresponding first-order condition is (9) d q ( Π+ π ) = p c ( ) = d (1) where p( q ) once again represents the marginal value product of. Thus the cooperative maimizes member returns by producing at the level where the marginal value product of equals the marginal cost of producing. From equation (3), we know that producers will operate such that the marginal value product of is equal to the price paid for. Thus r ( ) ( ) = c (11) is equivalent to the first-order in equation (1). The cooperative will produce at the level where the marginal cost of producing the farm input is equal to its market price, shown as 3 in figure 1. In the case of a cooperative that produces whatever quantity of producers choose to purchase, 5 the receipt of patronage refunds provides producers an incentive to increase their purchases until the cooperative s average cost of producing is equal to the price of and the cooperative breaks even. Producers seek to maimize their profits: π = pqy (, ) ( r s) r y (12) where s represents the per-unit patronage refund and r s is the net price producers pay for the product. Their first-order conditions are y π q = p ( r s) = (13) and π q = p ry =. y y (14)

4 Journal of Cooperatives Solving equations (13) and (14) simultaneously for and y and summing over all producers yields the input demand functions: and = r ( sr,, p) (15) y y= yr ( sr,, p). (16) Solving equation (15) for r s in terms of, we obtain the input demand function for in its inverse form: y r s= R( r,, p). (17) y The per-unit patronage refund s is equal to the cooperative s net earnings divided by the quantity of the farm input it produces: r ( ) c ( ) s = = r( ) c ( ). (18) Substituting equation (18) for s in equation (17), we obtain the equilibrium condition for the cooperative: r ( ) ( ). s= c (19) Equilibrium occurs where the net price of the farm input equals the average cost of producing it. For any particular net price, the values of r and s are not unique. Therefore, it is convenient to assume that the cooperative sets the cash price for the farm input equal to its average cost so that r ( ) = c ( ) and s =. Substituting s = into equation (19), the equilibrium condition can be epressed in a simpler form without loss of meaning: r ( ) ( ). = c (2) Equilibrium occurs where the price of the input equals its average cost, represented by the quantity 4 in figure 1.

A Model of a Processing Firm 6 Vol. 28 [214] No. 1 41 Assume producers produce a single raw product that is sold to a processor. Producers seek to maimize their profits: π = r q f( q) (21) where r is the raw product price paid producers by the processor, q is the quantity of raw product produced, and f( q ) is the total cost of producing the raw product. Profit maimization occurs where the marginal cost of producing the raw product equals the raw product price: dπ = r f ( q) =. (22) dq Solving equation (22) for r and summing over all producers yields the raw product inverse supply function r = f ( q). For convenience and without loss of generality, we can assume that a unit of processed product is equal to a unit of raw product. Then the processor s profit function can be written Π= p( q) q k( q) r( q) q (23) where pq ( ) is the processed product price and kq ( ) represents total processing cost eclusive of the cost of the raw product. Here the raw product price is written as rq ( ) to reflect the processor s monopsony power in the raw product market. Substituting the raw product inverse supply function for rq ( ) in equation (23) and differentiating it with respect to quantity, the first-order condition for a profit-maimizing processor is dπ dq [ p q q p q ] k q [ f q q f q ] = ( ) + ( ) ( ) ( ) + ( ) =. (24) According to equation (24), a processor maimizes its profit by setting its marginal revenue in the processed product market equal to the sum of its marginal processing cost and the marginal factor cost of the raw product (MFC). The first two terms on the right, marginal revenue less the marginal processing cost, are equivalent the net marginal revenue product (NMRP). Thus the output of the

42 Journal of Cooperatives Figure 2. Price and output solutions for processing firms profit-maimizing processor is q 1 in figure 2, determined by the intersection of the NMRP and MFC curves. Now consider a cooperative processor that maimizes member returns, including its own earnings, which are returned to members as patronage refunds. Assume all producers are members. Then the cooperative s objective function can be written Π+ π = pq ( ) q kq ( ) f( q) (25) where here π represents the sum of the profits of the individual producers in equation (21). The corresponding first-order condition is d ( Π+ π ) = [ pq ( ) + q p ( q) ] k ( q) f ( q) =. (26) dq The cooperative maimizes member returns by setting its marginal revenue in the processed product market equal to the sum of its marginal processing cost and the marginal cost of producing the raw product. The first two terms on the right are once again equivalent to NMRP. In addition, the last term is equivalent to the raw

Vol. 28 [214] No. 1 43 product supply curve according to equation (22). Thus the optimal level of output is q 3 in figure 2, determined by the intersection of the NMRP curve and the raw product supply curve S. In the case of a cooperative that processes whatever quantity of raw product producers choose to deliver, the receipt of patronage refunds provides producers an incentive to epand output until the cooperative s net average revenue product (NARP) is equal to the raw product price and the cooperative breaks even, as in the Helmberger and Hoos (1962) model. Producers seek to maimize their profits: π = ( r+ s) q f( q) (27) where s represents the per-unit patronage refund. The first-order condition is dπ = r+ s f ( q) =. (28) dq The per-unit patronage refund is equal to the cooperative s net earnings divided by the quantity of raw product processed: p( q) q k( q) r( q) q s = q = pq ( ) kq ( ) q rq ( ). (29) Substituting equation (29) for s in equation (28), we obtain the equilibrium condition: pq ( ) kq ( ) q f ( q) =. (3) Equilibrium occurs where the processed product price less the average processing cost equals the marginal cost of producing the raw product. The first two terms are equivalent to NARP. Thus the output of a cooperative that processes whatever quantity members choose to deliver is determined by the intersection of the NARP and raw product supply curves, represented by the quantity q 4 in figure 2. Maimization of Economic Welfare Resources used in the production of a good are allocated efficiently if they are employed in such a manner that the economic welfare associated with its produc-

44 Journal of Cooperatives tion and consumption is maimized. In the model of a farm supply firm, economic welfare consists of consumer surplus at the farm level: f = ( ) CS r d r (31) plus producer surplus at the supplier level: PS = r c ( ) d (32) s where and r are the quantity and price solutions for. Summing equations (31) and (32), economic welfare can be written Setting the first derivative to zero: [ ] W = r ( ) c ( ) d. (33) dw = r ( ) c ( ). = (34) d Economic welfare is maimized at the level where the farm input price equals the marginal cost of producing the input, a well-known result, which is represented by the quantity 3 in figure 1. The first-order and equilibrium conditions for the various farm supply firms are compared to the welfare-maimizing condition in table 1. The first-order condition for a profit-maimizing firm differs from the welfare-maimizing condition in that it contains r( ) + r ( ), or marginal revenue, in place of r ( ), the farm input price. If the firm faces a downward-sloping demand curve, r ( ). < As a result, the marginal revenue curve will lie beneath the demand curve, and the firm will restrict its output to less than the welfare-maimizing level. Only if r ( ) =, i.e., the firm is a price taker, will the firm s production meet the criterion for allocative efficiency. The first-order condition for a farm supply cooperative that maimizes member returns is identical to the welfare-maimizing condition. The cooperative

Vol. 28 [214] No. 1 45 Table 1. Comparison of the output solutions for farm supply firms to the welfare-maimizing condition Objective Condition Equation Maimization of economic welfare r ( ) = c ( ) (34) Maimization of profit r ( ) + r ( ) = c ( ) (8) Maimization of member returns (including patronage refunds) Production of quantity demanded by members r ( ) = c ( ) (11) r( ) = c ( ) (2) produces the optimal level of the farm input and uses resources efficiently. Eamination of equation (2) reveals that this generally is not the case for a cooperative that produces whatever quantity of the farm input members choose to purchase. The equilibrium condition contains c ( ), the average cost of producing the input, in place of c ( ), the marginal cost. If c ( ) > c ( ), the cooperative will overproduce relative to the welfare-maimizing quantity because the marginal cost of producing will eceed its value in producing the farm product q as reflected by its market price r ( ). The efficient level of will be produced only if c ( ) = c ( ), as at the minimum of the ATC curve in figure 1 or under a cost structure characterized by constant marginal costs. In the model of a processing firm, economic welfare consists of consumer surplus in the processed product market: q ( ) (35) CS= pqdq p q plus producer surplus at the processor level: q PS p = p q k ( q) dq r q (36) and producer surplus at the farm level:

46 Journal of Cooperatives Table 2. Comparison of the output solutions for processing firms to the welfare-maimizing condition Objective Condition Equation Maimization of economic welfare pq ( ) = k ( q) + f ( q) (39) Maimization of profit p( q) + q p ( q) = k ( q) + f ( q) + q f ( q) (24) Maimization of member returns (including patronage refunds) Production of quantity supplied by members p( q) + q p ( q) = k ( q) + f ( q) (26) pq ( ) = kq ( ) q+ f ( q) (3) q PS f r q f ( q) dq = (37) where q is the quantity solution and p and r are respectively the processed and raw product price solutions. Summing equations (35), (36), and (37), economic welfare can be written q Setting the derivative to zero: [ ] W = p( q) k ( q) f ( q) dq. (38) dw = pq ( ) k ( q ) f ( q ) =. (39) dq Economic welfare is maimized at the level where the processed product price equals the sum of the marginal processing cost and the marginal cost of producing the raw product, represented by the quantity q in figure 2. The first-order and equilibrium conditions for the various processing firms are compared to the corresponding welfare-maimizing condition in table 2. The first-order condition for a profit-maimizing firm differs from the welfare-

Vol. 28 [214] No. 1 47 maimizing condition in that it contains pq ( ) + q p ( q), or marginal revenue in the processed product market, in place of pq ( ), the processed product price, and it contains f ( q) + q f ( q), the marginal factor cost of the raw product, in place of f ( q), which is equivalent to the raw product price given equation (22). Thus a profit-maimizing firm will restrict output to a level less than the efficient level either if p ( q) <, i.e., the firm faces a downward-sloping processed product demand curve, or if f ( q) >, i.e., the firm faces an upward-sloping raw product supply curve. The firm will produce the efficient level of output only if p ( q) = and f ( q) =, i.e., the firm is a price taker in both the raw and processed product markets. The first-order condition for a cooperative that maimizes member returns differs from the welfare-maimizing condition only in that it contains pq ( ) + q p ( q) in place of pq ( ). Thus the cooperative will restrict output to less than the efficient level if p ( q) <. If p ( q) =, the two conditions are identical. The equilibrium condition for a cooperative that processes whatever quantity of raw product members choose to deliver differs from the welfare-maimizing condition in that it contains kq ( ) q, the average processing cost, in place of k ( q), the marginal processing cost. If k ( q) > kq ( ) q, the cooperative will overproduce q relative to the welfare-maimizing quantity because the sum of the marginal costs of producing and processing q will eceed its value to consumers as reflected by its price in the processed product market. The cooperative will produce the efficient level of output only if k ( q) = kq ( ) q, as at the minimum of the average processing cost curve or under a cost structure characterized by constant marginal costs. Notes 1. The purpose of assuming two inputs is to demonstrate that the demand for each input is a function of the price of the other input, as well as its own price and the price of the output. This model could easily be generalized to n inputs. 2. To keep the notation as simple as possible, we will not employ subscripts for individual agricultural producers. 3. For eample, consider the production function q = α β A y where α, β > and α + β < 1. Substituting this function into equation (2) for q, we can derive the following first-order conditions:

48 Journal of Cooperatives π α 1 β = pα A y r = and π α β 1 = pβ A y r y =. y Solving these conditions simultaneously for and y, the input demand function for is 1 1 β 1 α β β α β = Ap r r y From this, it is clear that the demand for is a function of both input prices and the output price. 4. Here and throughout, it is assumed that the second-order conditions for a maimum are satisfied. In this particular case, the first-order condition for a profit-maimizing input supplier can be rewritten d Π = MR MC = d where MR and MC respectively represent the firm s marginal revenue and marginal cost. Consequently, the second-order condition for profit maimization can be written. or 2 d Π dmr dmc 2 = < d d d dmr dmc <. d d For a maimum, the slope of the marginal revenue curve must be less than the slope of the marginal cost curve, i.e., marginal cost must be increasing at a faster rate than marginal revenue. 5. This assumption is equivalent to assuming the cooperative maimizes the quantity of it produces. Similarly, assuming a processing cooperative processes whatever quantity of raw product producers choose to deliver is equivalent to assuming it maimizes the quantity processed. 6. The models of a processing cooperative and the maimization of economic welfare are based on similar models presented in Royer (21). As in Part II, the processor model can be applied to a cooperative that simply markets the raw product by considering the processing costs as representing the costs of transporting or marketing the product.

References Vol. 28 [214] No. 1 49 Helmberger, P., and S. Hoos. 1962. Cooperative Enterprise and Organization Theory. Journal of Farm Economics 44:275 9. Royer, J.S. 21. Agricultural Marketing Cooperatives, Allocative Efficiency, and Corporate Taation. Journal of Cooperatives 16:1 13.