Corporate Law s Distributive Design

Similar documents
Selectica v. Versata: Delaware Chancery Court Upholds Poison Pill Shareholder Rights Plan with 4.99% Triggering Threshold Designed to Protect NOLs

The Rise of Nanny Corporations

The Shareholder Rights By-Law: Giving Shareholders a Decisive Voice

Does a Taxpayer Have the Burden of Showing Intent to Divert Corporate Funds as Return of Capital?

- 1 - BEFORE THE NATIONAL BUSINESS CONDUCT COMMITTEE NASD REGULATION, INC. DECISION. District No. 9

PUBLISHED UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE FOURTH CIRCUIT. No

Daniel JH Greenwood - Are Shareholders Entitled to the Residual? Hofstra University College of Law 2/8/06

The Right To Reimbursement Of Defense Costs?

Delaware Court Applies Revlon To Hybrid Merger And Provides Guidance

BEFORE THE STATE OF ALASKA OFFICE OF ADMINISTRATIVE HEARINGS ON REFERRAL FROM THE DIRECTOR OF THE DIVISION OF INSURANCE

Delaware Supreme Court Upholds Validity of "NOL" Rights Plan

Corporate Officer Liability and the Applicable Standard of Review Under Delaware Law and Agency Law By Kevin McCarthy

Corporate Litigation: Enforceability of Board-Adopted Forum Selection Bylaws

EXPERT GUIDE Mergers & Acquisitions May 2014

IN THE COMMONWEALTH COURT OF PENNSYLVANIA. Appellant :

Panter v. Marshall Field & (and) Company: A Tender Offer Field's Could Refuse

Rosann Delso v. Trustees of Ret Plan Hourly Em

Case3:09-cv MMC Document22 Filed09/08/09 Page1 of 8

CLM 2016 New York Conference December 1, 2016 New York, New York

United States Court of Appeals

THE PRESSURE TO TENDER: AN ANALYSIS AND A PROPOSED REMEDY

Numerous Proposed 2009 Amendments to the Delaware General Corporation Law Reflect Heightened Focus on Governance Issues

Moran And The Poison Pill: A Target'S Savior?

United States Court of Appeals

Do Antitakeover Defenses Decrease Shareholder Wealth? The Ex Post/Ex Ante Valuation Problem

Jeffrey Kaufman v. Barbara T. Alexander

IN THE SUPREME COURT OF THE STATE OF DELAWARE

ARMED SERVICES BOARD OF CONTRACT APPEALS

The Fiduciary Duties of Directors of the Companies Facing M&As in Delaware and Japan *

NYCLA COMMITTEE ON PROFESSIONAL ETHICS. OPINION No Date Issued: October 7, Topic

United States Court of Appeals For the First Circuit

The Case Against Board Veto in Corporate Takeovers

What amounts to good faith conduct or repudiation on construction projects?

NOT TO BE PUBLISHED IN THE OFFICIAL REPORTS IN THE COURT OF APPEAL OF THE STATE OF CALIFORNIA SECOND APPELLATE DISTRICT DIVISION TWO

AFFIRMATION IN SUPPORT -against- : : ABEX CORPORATION, et al., : : Defendants. : : X

Insurer v. Insurer: The Bases of an Insurer s Right to Recover Payment From Another Insurer*

UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS TENTH CIRCUIT ORDER AND JUDGMENT * Before O'BRIEN, TYMKOVICH, and GORSUCH, Circuit Judges.

Chapter 11. Elliott Management Corp. ( Elliott ), as a provider of investment

Follow this and additional works at: Part of the Corporation and Enterprise Law Commons

Priority of Withholding Taxes (In re Freedomland, Inc.)

DELAWARE CORPORATE LAW BULLETIN

Redemptions Not Essentially Equivalent to Dividends

The M&A Lawyer January 2018 Volume 22 Issue 1. K 2018 Thomson Reuters

IN THE IOWA DISTRICT COURT FOR POLK COUNTY

: : PLAINTIFF, : : : : : DEFENDANT : Plaintiffs are hedge funds that invested in the Rye Select Broad Market

O'Connor-Kohler v. State Farm Ins Co

A Comment on One More Time: New York s Structured Settlement Statutes, Rent Seeking and. the Pro-Plaintiff Bias Draft date: 3/23/04

Judge Sonia Sotomayor s Tax Opinions

Bulletin Litigation/Mergers & Acquisitions

IN THE COURT OF APPEALS OF THE STATE OF NEW MEXICO

IN THE SUPERIOR COURT OF THE VIRGIN ISLANDS DIVISION OF ST. CROIX

A Notable Footnote In High Court Merit Management Decision

IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT. No D.C. Docket No. 0:15-cv RNS

IN THE COMMONWEALTH COURT OF PENNSYLVANIA

CHANCES ARE... A FORTUITY CASE STUDY A POLICYHOLDER S PERSPECTIVE

IN THE FACE OF AN UNSOLICITED BID

Dalton v. United States

THE BASICS OF CASH COLLATERAL AND DIP FINANCING by Kevin M. Lippman and Jonathan L. Howell

Pay, Play, or Sue: A Review of the Ninth Circuit s Opinion in Golden Gate Restaurant Association v. City and County of San Francisco, et al.

Prudential Prop v. Boyle

Penny Wise and Pound Foolish? Issues for Excess Insurers in the Wake of Comerica and Qualcomm. By Patrick J. Boley

THE UTAH COURT OF APPEALS

NON-PRECEDENTIAL DECISION - SEE SUPERIOR COURT I.O.P

Testing the Limits of Lender Liability in Distressed-Loan Situations. July/August Debra K. Simpson Mark G. Douglas

IN THE COURT OF APPEALS STATE OF ARIZONA DIVISION ONE

United States Court of Appeals For the First Circuit

United States Bankruptcy Court Western District of Wisconsin

Stakes Are High For ERISA Fiduciaries

Case: 3:08-cv bbc Document #: 554 Filed: 07/02/12 Page 1 of 15

Defenders of the Corporate Bastion in Revlon Zone: Paramount Communications Inc. v. Time Inc.

Depreciation of Pipeline Easement Costs

Van Camp & Bennion v. United States 251 F.3d 862 (9th Cir. Wash. 2001).

NON-PRECEDENTIAL DECISION - SEE SUPERIOR COURT I.O.P

IN THE SUPREME COURT OF THE STATE OF OREGON

IN THE COURT OF COMMON PLEAS CUYAHOGA COUNTY, OHIO

The Gift Clause of Arizona s Constitution bars cities and other entities from. Ariz. Const.

Installment Sales--Purchaser's Assumption of Liability to Third Party

ARMED SERVICES BOARD OF CONTRACT APPEALS

ARMED SERVICES BOARD OF CONTRACT APPEALS

IN THE COURT OF APPEALS OF OHIO SIXTH APPELLATE DISTRICT LUCAS COUNTY. Court of Appeals No. L Trial Court No.

Case 3:10-cv Document 36 Filed in TXSD on 05/24/12 Page 1 of 2

Case 3:14-cv WWE Document 96 Filed 04/06/17 Page 1 of 6 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT DISTRICT OF CONNECTICUT

United States Court of Appeals For the Eighth Circuit

2017 CO 11. No. 16SC283, Youngquist v. Miner Workers Compensation Personal Jurisdiction Specific Jurisdiction.

Fiduciary Governance: Lessons from ERISA Litigation

2.02 Spin-Off Transactions

IN THE COURT OF APPEAL OF THE STATE OF CALIFORNIA FIRST APPELLATE DISTRICT DIVISION FIVE

Foreign Illegality: No Absolute Bar to Enforcement of Internal Revenue Service Summons

STATE OF MICHIGAN SIXTEENTH JUDICIAL CIRCUIT COURT. Case No AE OPINION AND ORDER

HARVARD JOHN M. OLIN CENTER FOR LAW, ECONOMICS, AND BUSINESS

BEFORE THE ALASKA OFFICE OF ADMINISTRATIVE HEARINGS ON REFERRAL BY THE COMMISSIONER OF REVENUE

The Misuse of Textualism: A Further Reply to Prof. Kahn

Nebraska Law Review. Stephen E. Kalish University of Nebraska College of Law. Volume 65 Issue 4 Article 9

Del. Confirms Continued Validity Of Advance Notice Bylaws

ARMED SERVICES BOARD OF CONTRACT APPEALS. Appeal of -- ) ) The Swanson Group, Inc. ) ASBCA No ) Under Contract No. N C-9509 )

Some Observations on Notice Requirements Under Claims-Made Forms and Other Policies with Strict Claim Reporting Requirements

Paper Entered: September 13, 2013 UNITED STATES PATENT AND TRADEMARK OFFICE BEFORE THE PATENT TRIAL AND APPEAL BOARD

UNITED STATES BANKRUPTCY COURT EASTERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA SACRAMENTO DIVISION

[Cite as Ceccarelli v. Levin, 127 Ohio St.3d 231, 2010-Ohio-5681.]

Case 1:16-cv WGY Document 14 Filed 09/06/16 Page 1 of 12 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT DISTRICT OF MASSACHUSETTS

Transcription:

University of Chicago Law School Chicago Unbound Coase-Sandor Working Paper Series in Law and Economics Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics 2009 Corporate Law s Distributive Design Anupam Chander Follow this and additional works at: https://chicagounbound.uchicago.edu/law_and_economics Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Anupam Chander, "Corporate Law s Distributive Design" ( John M. Olin Program in Law and Economics Working Paper No. 464, 2009). This Working Paper is brought to you for free and open access by the Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics at Chicago Unbound. It has been accepted for inclusion in Coase-Sandor Working Paper Series in Law and Economics by an authorized administrator of Chicago Unbound. For more information, please contact unbound@law.uchicago.edu.

Corporate Law s Distributive Design Anupam Chander June 2009 CHICAGO JOHN M. OLIN LAW & ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER NO. 464 (2D SERIES) THE LAW SCHOOL THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO School of Law University of California, Davis 400 Mrak Hall Drive Davis, CA 95616 530.752.0243 http://www.law.ucdavis.edu UC Davis Legal Studies Research Paper Series Research Paper No. 172 This paper can be downloaded without charge at: The Chicago Working Paper Series Index: http://www.law.uchicago.edu/lawecon/index.html and at the Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection.

FINAL_PDF.DOC 10/28/2008 9:26:10 PM Anupam Chander Corporate Law s Distributive Design Minorities, Shareholder and Otherwise 1 makes two novel claims: that corporate law places protection of minority shareholders at the heart of its endeavor; and that this minority-mindfulness should have even greater purchase in constitutional contexts. My retelling of the corporate law narrative coupled with my extension of that story to the constitutional domain puts pressure on scholars either to dispute my characterization of corporate law (or for that matter, constitutional law) or to deny the relevance of that characterization to the constitutional sphere. Alternatively and, I think, more promisingly, it allows scholars to seek to understand or resolve law s inconsistent attitudes towards minorities in different domains. I am glad to have the wisdom of Steven Bainbridge, Richard Delgado, and Kevin Johnson in thinking through my boundary-transgressing endeavor. Dean Johnson extends my thesis, arguing that immigrants, too, present the kind of vulnerable minorities who might deserve legal solicitude, but observing that the courts, through the plenary power doctrine, have disabled themselves from providing such protection. Delgado meanwhile presses for an explanation for the puzzle I identify: why does constitutional law neglect minorities while corporate law embraces them? He locates the divide in majoritarian selfinterest. Bainbridge, on the other hand, challenges my characterization of corporate law as being minority focused. Because his paper, unlike the others, disagrees with fundamental aspects of my argument, I will focus this reply to his claims, reserving the others for consideration in future work. Part I rebuts Bainbridge s case analysis, demonstrating that the cases show clear judicial succor for minority (by which I mean non-controlling) shareholders. Part II turns to broader theoretical differences. 1. Anupam Chander, Minorities, Shareholder and Otherwise, 113 YALE L.J. 119 (2003). 82

corporate law s distributive design cases Bainbridge identifies cases that he believes show that corporate law tolerates discrimination among shareholders (Unocal Corp. v. Mesa Petroleum Co., 2 Moran v. Household Int l., Inc., 3 and Zahn v. Transamerica Corp. 4 ); allows selfish ownership (Wilkes v. Springside Nursing Home, Inc. 5 ); has attenuated concern for fairness in public corporations (Sinclair Oil Corp. v. Levien 6 ); and permits non-sharing of control premia (e.g., Treadway Companies, Inc. v. Care Corp. 7 ). In this part, I review these cases to show that they in fact support my thesis. Take Moran, in which the Delaware Supreme Court upheld a poison pill against a minority shareholder attack. Bainbridge argues that the court s rebuff to Moran shows its willingness to tolerate discrimination against minority shareholders. But Household s board instituted the poison pill after it learned that Moran, chairman of Household s largest shareholder, had considered leading a leveraged buy-out of Household. The court upheld the defensive measure as a means to stave off coercive two tier tender offers 8 that might exploit the other shareholders. 9 When Unocal instituted a defense that excluded hostile acquirer and minority shareholder Mesa from a self-tender by Unocal, Mesa complained that the board was discriminating amongst different classes of shareholders. The court upheld the discrimination as a reasonable mechanism to prevent a two tier tender offer, in which the second tier would consist in junk bonds, stamped[ing] shareholders into tendering at the first tier, even if the price is inadequate. 10 Indeed, the court cited studies showing that shareholders often benefited from the defeat of hostile takeovers. 11 To the extent that Moran and Unocal demonstrate a court s willing to tolerate discrimination against a class of shareholders, it is simply a willingness of the court to deal skeptically with potentially controlling shareholders whom 2. 493 A.2d 946 (Del. 1985). 3. 500 A.2d 1346 (Del. 1985). 4. 162 F.2d 36 (3d Cir. 1947). 5. 353 N.E.2d 657 (Mass. 1976). 6. 280 A.2d 717 (Del. 1971). 7. 638 F.2d 357, 375 (2d Cir. 1980). 8. Moran v. Household Int l., Inc., 500 A.2d 1346, 1356 (Del. 1985). 9. Id. 10. Unocal Corp. v. Mesa Petroleum Co., 493 A.2d 946, 956 (Del. 1985). 11. Id. at 956 n.11. 83

the yale law journal pocket part 118:82 2008 the board, acting with independence and with due care, believes are hostile to the interests of the firm s other shareholders. In Zahn, the court held that the corporation s directors puppet[s] to Transamerica s puppeteer 12 had failed in their duty to represent[] all the stockholders. 13 Corporate law does not offer succor to every shareholder who owns less than fifty percent of the corporation, especially when the minority shareholder seeking the court s protection intends to become the controlling shareholder through a hostile takeover (or receive greenmail to stop trying). Courts understand which shareholders truly need legal protection. 14 Given rational apathy, in a diffusely held corporation, a single large minority owner may wield disproportionate influence in the company. Corporate law is not colorblind; relations of domination and subordination matter; the identity of the parties is legally relevant. Bainbridge argues that Wilkes affirms the possibility of selfish ownership by majority shareholders. He makes two crucial omissions in this reference: (1) the rest of the sentence; and (2) the rest of the decision. The court required that any selfish ownership of majority shareholders must be balanced against their fiduciary obligation to the minority. 15 The court sided with minority Wilkes, holding that the majority could have followed an alternative course of action less harmful to the minority s interest. 16 Even though the bylaws allowed the directors to set the salaries, the court held that Wilkes had been unjustly removed from the payroll. Bainbridge for his part says that I neglected to mention parts of the holding in Sinclair Oil in which the court upholds the majority shareholder s actions. Indeed, Sinclair prevailed against the minority s claim of excessive dividends and missed business opportunities because the minority could not show any harm to the company (and thus its minority shareholders) arising out of the dividends or the firm s expansion policy. In dismissing this part of the minority s claim, the court observed that the minority received its proportionate share of the dividend. 17 No harm, no foul. This victory for the controlling shareholder does not undermine my argument. My claim is not that the minority shareholder always wins, and on all counts. Being a minority shareholder is not some sort of talisman that guarantees success at the bar. 12. Zahn v. Transamerica Corp., 162 F.2d 36, 46 (3d Cir. 1947). 13. Id. at 45. 14. Chander, supra note 1, at 175-77. 15. Wilkes v. Springside Nursing Home, Inc., 353 N.E.2d 657, 663 (Mass. 1976). 16. Id. 17. Sinclair Oil Corp. v. Levien, 280 A.2d 717, 721 (Del. 1971). 84

corporate law s distributive design Bainbridge highlights the sale of control cases, which generally permit the controlling shareholder to retain a premium upon the sale. 18 While Berle and others argued in favor of a sharing rule, 19 the law generally permits owners of controlling blocs [to] sell at a substantial premium, without any obligation to share the bounty with other shareholders. 20 But this does not disprove my thesis. Corporate law permits controlling shareholders to earn premia because such a position generally makes minority shareholders better off. An active market for corporate control fostered by control premia is one of the principal means of disciplining management. Bainbridge himself writes in his impressive treatise that a no sharing rule should facilitate replacement of inefficient incumbents. 21 Some find strong empirical support for the view that the value of the noncontrolling shareholders shares increases following a transfer of control. 22 If a sharing rule dampened the disciplinary force of the market for corporate control, minority shareholders might be worse off in the long run. Yet another feature of the case law protects minority shareholders during changes of control: if a minority shareholder complains, judges carefully scrutinize the transaction for evidence of looting or usurpation of corporate opportunities. theory To locate occasional cases that fail to protect minority shareholders is not to defeat my thesis. After all, no theory can satisfactorily explain all cases, and there will be differing views as to whether a loss for minority shareholders in one case may hold long-term benefit for minority shareholders overall. Judges might also get a particular decision wrong. My point is that the overarching explanation for judicial action in corporate law matters can generally be found in the simple goal of protecting minority shareholders. Corporate law is not minority-status blind. Consider the universe of persons who are the principal subjects of corporate law: directors, officers, controlling shareholders, and minority 18. One of Bainbridge s citations for the general rule is inapposite: the sale of stock at issue in Treadway did not transfer control. Treadway Companies, Inc. v. Care Corp., 638 F.2d 357, 377 (2d Cir. 1980). 19. JAMES D. COX & THOMAS LEE HAZEN, COX & HAZEN ON CORPORATIONS 12.01 n.2 (2d ed. Supp. 2002) (collecting law review articles on the subject). 20. FRANK EASTERBROOK & DANIEL R. FISCHEL, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF CORPORATE LAW 109 (1996). 21. STEPHEN M. BAINBRIDGE, CORPORATION LAW AND ECONOMICS 349 (2002). 22. COX & HAZEN, supra note 19, at 12.01. 85

the yale law journal pocket part 118:82 2008 shareholders. Corporate law imposes fiduciary duties on all of these persons with the exception of minority shareholders (unless they are also controlling shareholders). Bainbridge s colleagues have recently argued for the imposition of fiduciary duties on activist, minority shareholders, highlighting this lacuna. 23 Minorities suggests that this lacuna is not accidental but that the duties themselves can be understood as flowing towards minority shareholders. Bainbridge denies the existence of significant extra-contractual protections for minorities. 24 But how then does Bainbridge explain fiduciary duties, which, along with limited liability, form the core of corporate law? What are these other than extra-contractual duties placed on directors, officers, and controlling shareholders? There might be some out there who would eliminate fiduciary duties entirely, collapsing corporate law into limited liability and, maybe, securities regulation, but that is not our law today. To argue alternatively that fiduciary duties represent merely the contract that one would have found were it not for market failures and to conclude from this that fiduciary duties are thus not extra-contractual is simply to rewrite the meaning of contract and seems especially hard to justify in the setting of closed corporations with few principals. Bainbridge also contests my analogy, saying that the constitutional domain should properly be squared with the public corporation domain, not with the law of closed corporations, thus declaring closed corporation cases to be inapposite to my argument. He argues that closed corporations often involve consensus-based decisionmaking, rather than the authority-based decisionmaking prevalent in public corporations. But it is the lack of ready exit that motivates the heightened fairness concerns and judicial policing in closed corporation settings, not the supposed consensus-nature of the decisionmaking. No exit is true of the constitutional domain as well, and thus, I argue, should lead us to be similarly concerned with domination and fairness in constitutional quarters. Bainbridge s critique leads me to revisit a carelessly worded footnote defining affirmative action. 25 I do not believe that corporate law seeks to distribute disproportionately large gains to the minority; corporate law may devote its own resources disproportionately towards minority protection, but it 23. Iman Anabtawi & Lynn Stout, Fiduciary Duties for Activist Shareholders, 60 STAN. L. REV. 1255 (2008). 24. Stephen M. Bainbridge, There Is No Affirmative Action for Minorities, Shareholder and Otherwise, in Corporate Law, 118 Yale L.J. Pocket Part 71 (2008), http://thepocketpart.org/2008/10/28/bainbridge.html. 25. Chander, supra note 1, at 120 n.3. 86

corporate law s distributive design certainly does not require that minorities get a disproportionate share of the corporate spoils. conclusion My back and forth with Bainbridge suggests that there is room to wonder what corporate law is all about. It is best not to adopt uncritically any given orthodoxy, even when it is as appealing as the simple maximand of shareholder wealth. My thesis in Minorities might go further that shareholder wealth maximization is wrong as a descriptive matter; the telos of corporate law is shareholder wealth distribution. The business judgment rule immunizes so much foolishness 26 that it is hard to assert that courts play an active role in promoting wealth maximization. Rather it might be more reasonable to assert that judges simply police the distribution of the corporate gains (and make sure that management is not grossly negligent). Corporations have proven to be remarkably successful forms of enterprise because of or despite a legal framework attentive to the most vulnerable among those contributing capital. Ultimately, through Minorities, I hope to spur the thought that human organizational forms stand to learn much from each other. Anupam Chander is a Visiting Professor at the University of Chicago Law School and a Professor of Law at the University of California, Davis. Preferred Citation: Anupam Chander, Corporate Law s Distributive Design, 118 YALE L.J. POCKET PART 82 (2008), http://thepocketpart.org/2008/10/28/chanderresponse.html. 26. See, e.g., Brehm v. Eisner, 746 A.2d 244 (Del. 2000). 87