LECTURE 14: THE INEQUALITY OF CAPITAL OWNERSHIP IN EUROPE AND THE USA

Similar documents
LECTURE 11: INCOME INEQUALITY IN EUROPE AND THE USA

LECTURE 3: MEASURING THE WEALTH OF NATIONS. Dr. Aidan Regan Website:

LECTURE 12: THE 1 PERCENT IN EUROPE AND THE USA

LECTURE 9: THE RETURN OF CAPITAL IN THE 21 ST CENTURY

Capital in the 21 st century

Inequality and Social Mobility. Econ 101

FIGURE I.1. Income inequality in the United States,

Inequality and growth Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics

Capital in the 21 st century

long run inequality History and Inequality University of Oslo

Thomas Piketty s Capital in the 21 st Century

Maurizio Franzini and Mario Planta

LECTURE 10: THE RETURN OF NEOLIBERAL CAPITALISM

Capital in the 21 st century. Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Visby, June

Capital in the 21 st century. Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Cologne, December 5 th 2013

CIE Economics A-level

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory. Costas Azariadis. Costas Azariadis. Lecture 3: Productivity and Labor

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates)

Global economic inequality: New evidence from the World Inequality Report

From Communism to Capitalism: Private Versus Public Property and Inequality in China and Russia

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

Wealth, Inequality & Taxation T. Piketty, IMF Supplementary slides

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2017 preliminary estimates)

Should the Rich Pay for Fiscal Adjustment? Income and Capital Tax Options

Wealth, inequality & assets: where is Europe heading?

2.5. Income inequality in France

Income and Wealth Inequality A Lack of Equity

Wealth and Welfare: Breaking the Generational Contract

Income and Wealth Concentration in Switzerland over the 20 th Century

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.ec] 1 Sep 2014

Table 4.1 Income Distribution in a Three-Person Society with A Constant Marginal Utility of Income

Capitalism, Inequality & Globalization. Public University of Navarre Pamplona, Spain May 21 st 2018 J. E. Stiglitz

Income and Wealth Inequality in OECD Countries

Wealth - why do we care and what do we know?

Capital, labour and the distribution of income. Mario Pianta Università di Urbino

TOP INCOMES IN THE UNITED STATES AND CANADA OVER THE TWENTIETH CENTURY

John Hills, Francesca Bastagli, Frank Cowell, Howard Glennerster, Eleni Karagiannaki and Abigail McKnight

the regional distribution of income

Sustainable development and EU integration of the Western Balkans

Source: Oxfam Issue Briefing, Having It All and Wanting More, January 2015

From Communism to Capitalism: Private vs. Public Property and Rising. Inequality in China and Russia

Income Inequality and Poverty (Chapter 20 in Mankiw & Taylor; reading Chapter 19 will also help)

Capitalism, Inequality & Globalization. J. E. Stiglitz Davidson College March 2018

Inequality and the super-rich

Consumption Inequality in Canada, Sam Norris and Krishna Pendakur

The intergenerational transmission of wealth

Gabriel Zucman. Inequality: Are we really 'all in this together'? #ElectionEconomics PAPER EA030

The Distribution of US Wealth, Capital Income and Returns since Emmanuel Saez (UC Berkeley) Gabriel Zucman (LSE and UC Berkeley)

(Translated to English. by Arthur Goldhammer) England, UK: Belknap Press of Howard University Press, 2014

Who is getting richer, who is getting poorer

SKEMA BUSINESS SCHOOL Global risk and the mounting wealth gap Michel Henry Bouchet

Poverty, inequality and policy since 1997

Inequality in Oregon

Reflections on capital taxation

Real Median Family Income is Falling. Family incomes have stagnated since the mid-1980s. Income in 2012 ($51,017) is lower than in 1989 ($51,681).

Redistribution from a lifetime perspective: historical and hypothetical reforms

INCOME INEQUALITY AND OTHER FORMS OF INEQUALITY. Sandip Sarkar & Balwant Singh Mehta. Institute for Human Development New Delhi

Capital is Back: Wealth-Income Ratios in Rich Countries Thomas Piketty & Gabriel Zucman Paris School of Economics October 2012

Lecture 3: Income & Wage Taxation Over Time & Across Countries (check on line for updated versions)

Rethinking Wealth Taxation

Inequality in China: Recent Trends. Terry Sicular (University of Western Ontario)

Income Inequality in Korea,

1 Income Inequality in the US

A Transition to Sustainable and Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz Tokyo March 14, 2017

About Capital in the 21 st Century

Inequality Dynamics in France, : Evidence from Distributional National Accounts (DINA)

Applying Generalized Pareto Curves to Inequality Analysis

Globalization, Inequality, and Tax Justice

WHAT WOULD THE NEIGHBOURS SAY?

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Income Inequality Matters, but Mobility Is Just as Important. Daniel R. Carroll and Anne Chen

WHAT DO HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS SUGGEST ABOUT THE TOP 1% INCOMES AND INEQUALITY IN OECD COUNTRIES? Nicolas Ruiz (OECD)

Italy and the political economy of decline

Budget 2015/16: Is the new South Africa sustainable? By Professor Matthew Lester 25 February 2015

Two Cheers for Piketty

Econ 133 Global Inequality and Growth. Inequality between labor and capital. Gabriel Zucman

Improving the Distribution of Wealth: Lecture in Memory of Anthony Atkinson. Joseph E. Stiglitz LSE February 16, 2018

Taxation of High Net Worth Individuals (HNWIs)

Wealth Extremes in the Late Nineteenth Century Ontario: Where Were the Rich People?

The Great Depression, golden age, and global financial crisis

Source: Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez. Chart by Catherine Mulbrandon of VisualizingEconomics.com.

Economics 448: Lecture 14 Measures of Inequality

Briefing Paper BP1/2015. New survey research on public attitudes to wealth taxes. Karen Rowlingson, Andy Lymer and Rajiv Prabhakar.

Executive Summary. Trends in Inequality: Globally and Nationally. How inequality constraints growth

Distribution of Wealth In Ireland

THREE WORLDS THEORY G L O B A L S T R A T I F I C A T I O N

Trump s Tax Scam: What can we expect from the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act and how can we resist it? by Peter Bohmer February 23, 2018

Income Inequality in France, : Evidence from Distributional National Accounts (DINA)

The 30 years between 1977 and 2007

Tim Hazledine University of Auckland

ECON 1100 Global Economics (Fall 2013) The Distribution Function of Government portions for Exam 3

Hi Danny! Thanks for speaking to

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GLOBAL INEQUALITY DYNAMICS: NEW FINDINGS FROM WID.WORLD

Capital Accumulation, Private Property, and Inequality in China,

Fiscal Fact. Reversal of the Trend: Income Inequality Now Lower than It Was under Clinton. Introduction. By William McBride

Inequality in developed countries - how good is a good state. Åsa Hansson Lunds universitet

The Links between Income Distribution and Poverty Reduction in Britain

Ending the Capital Gains Tax Preference would Improve Fairness, Raise Revenue and Simplify the Tax Code

Wealth inequality in the euro area

Wealth Distribution and Taxation. Frank Cowell: MSc Public Economics 2011/2

Econ 230B Graduate Public Economics. Models of the wealth distribution. Gabriel Zucman

Transcription:

LECTURE 14: THE INEQUALITY OF CAPITAL OWNERSHIP IN EUROPE AND THE USA Dr. Aidan Regan Email: aidan.regan@ucd.ie Website: www.aidanregan.com Teaching blog: www.capitalistdemocracy.wordpress.com Twitter: @aidan_regan #CapitalUCD

Introduction In this lecture we are returning to the question of wealth inequality (i.e. inequalities arising from capital ownership). Global wealth today is estimated at approximately $262 trillion. 44% of this is estimated to be owned by 0.7% of the world's population. Last week we concluded that the only reason why income inequality declined in the 20th century was because the income arising from capital ownership declined. It is therefore essential that we understand how this compression in the inequality of wealth came about.

Reminder Table 7.2. Inequality of capital ownership across time and space Share of different groups in total capital Low inequality (never observed; ideal society?) Medium inequality ( Scandinavia, 1970s-1980s) Mediumhigh inequality ( Europe 2010) High inequality ( U.S. 2010) Very high inequality ( Europe 1910) The top 10% "Upper class" 30% 50% 60% 70% 90% including: the top 1% ("dominant class") 10% 20% 25% 35% 50% ("well- including: the next 9% to-do class") 20% 30% 35% 35% 40% The middle 40% "Middle class" 45% 40% 35% 25% 5% The bottom 50% "Lower class" 25% 10% 5% 5% 5% Corresponding Gini coefficient (synthetic inequality index) 0.33 0.58 0.67 0.73 0.85 In societies with "medium" inequality of capital ownership (such as Scandinavian countries in the 1970s-1980s), the top 10% richest in wealth own about 50% of aggregate wealth, the bottom 50% poorest about 10%, and the middle 40% about 40%. The corresponding Gini coefficient is equal to 0.58. See technical appendix.

Capital ownership Table 7.2 shows that in all known societies the poorest half of the population own virtually nothing (generally 5% of wealth). The world of the 21 st century is no different to the world of the 19th century in this sense. The top decile have generally owned between 60-90% of wealth. The middle classes have generally owned between 5-35%. This emergence of a property owning middle class transformed wealth distribution in the 20th century. Let's take a look at these empirical trends in Europe and the USA overtime.

France 100% Figure 10.1. Wealth inequality in France, 1810-2010 90% Share of top decile or percentile in total wealth 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% Top 10% wealth share Top 1% wealth share 0% 1810 1830 1850 1870 1890 1910 1930 1950 1970 1990 2010 The top decile (the top 10% highest wealth holders) owns 80-90% of total wealth in 1810-1910, and 60-65% today. Sources and series: see piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c.

France What we observe in France is that the top decile owned between 80-90% of wealth from 1810-1910 and 60-65% today. This longitudinal data is available because of the introduction of an estate tax in 1791 on all forms of wealth; property, assets, bonds, land. Looking at these trends in capital ownership it is interesting to ask what would have happened had there been no war? France was a patrimonial society characterized by a hyper-concentration of wealth. The decline in the upper decile share of wealth in the 20th century went exclusively to the middle 40 percent of the population. The poorest 60 percent owned nothing in the 19th and the 21 st century. Much like the structure of wage inequality - this has not changed.

Britain 100% Figure 10.3. Wealth inequality in Britain, 1810-2010 Share of top decie or top percentile in total wealth 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% Top 10% wealth share Top 1% wealth share 0% 1810 1830 1850 1870 1890 1910 1930 1950 1970 1990 2010 The top decile owns 80-90% of total wealth in 1810-1910, and 70% today. Sources(and(series:(see(pike0y.pse.ens.fr/capital21c.((

Sweden 100% Figure 10.4. Wealth inequality in Sweden, 1810-2010 Share of top decie or percentile in total wealth 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% Top 10% wealth share Top 1% wealth share 0% 1810 1830 1850 1870 1890 1910 1930 1950 1970 1990 2010 The top 10% holds 80-90% of total wealth in 1810-1910, and 55-60% today. Sources and series: see piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c.

Britain and Sweden Figure 10.3 and figure 10.4 show that the same extreme concentration of capital ownership and wealth existed in Britain and Sweden. It was a European wide phenomenon. In Britain, the top decile owned 80-90 percent of total wealth in 1910 and 70 percent today. In 1910, Sweden was just as unequal. It was nothing like the egalitarian country it became during the 1970's. The essential difference today is that there is a property owning middle class - who own about one third of national wealth. The wealthiest 10 percent lost to the middle 40 percent during the period of strong growth in the 20th century. Nothing went to the poorest half of the population.

USA 100% Figure 10.5. Wealth inequality in the U.S., 1810-2010 Share of top decile or percentile in total wealth 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% Top 10% wealth chare Top 1% wealth share 0% 1810 1830 1850 1870 1890 1910 1930 1950 1970 1990 2010 The top 10% wealth holders own about 80% of total wealth in 1910, and 75% today. Sources and series: see piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c.

USA Figure 10.5 shows that in the USA the top 10 percent owned 80% of total wealth in 1910 and around 75 percent today. We are accustomed to the fact that the US is more unequal that Europe, and that public opinion in the US is more tolerant of inequalities - primarily because they are perceived as an outcome of entrepreneurial dynamism. But this was not always the case. A century ago the US prided itself on the fact that it was more egalitarian than Europe. From 1910-1930 the US pioneered a progressive income and wealth tax to limit growing inequalities, which were deemed incompatible with the democratic values of the 'free-world'. Perceptions and attitudes toward inequality, redistribution and national values have changed a great deal over the 20th century

Europe/USA 100% Figure 10.6. Wealth inequality: Europe and the U.S., 1810-2010 90% Share of top decile or percentile in total wealth 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% Top 10% wealth share: Europe Top 10% wealth share: U.S. Top 1% wealth share: Europe Top 1% wealth share: U.S. 0% 1810 1830 1850 1870 1890 1910 1930 1950 1970 1990 2010 Until the mid 20th century, wealth inequality was higher in Europe than in the United States. Sources and series: see piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c.

Europe/USA Figure 10.6 compares capital ownership and wealth inequality in Europe and the USA. The huge decline in Europe during the 20th century created a perception that capital had been tamed The assumption was that inequality and a sharply divided class society had been relegated to the past. This has come to a halt and best observed in the English speaking world.

The Mechanism: R>G What explains the hyper-concentration of wealth up until WW1? For Piketty, the fundamental macro-social driving force was R>G. These were low-growth societies (G) in which the rate of return on capital (R) was markedly stronger. If G=1% and R=5% then fortunes grow faster than the economy. This is an ideal condition for an 'inheritance society'. Most wealth during the 18th and 19th century came from inheritance.

R>G 6% Figure 10.10. After tax rate of return vs. growth rate at the world level, from Antiquity until 2100 Annual rate of return or rate of growth 5% 4% 3% 2% 1% Pure rate of return to capital (after tax and capital losses) Growth rate of world output g 0% 0-1000 1000-1500 1500-1700 1700-1820 1820-1913 1913-1950 1950-2012 2012-2050 2050-2100 The rate of return to capital (after tax and capital losses) fell below the growth rate during the 20th century, and may again surpass it in the 21st century. Sources and series : see piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c

Taxes and growth Before WW1 taxes on capital, profits and property were very low. This changed after WW1. Since 1980 and with heightened international competition for capital investment, they have become very low again. Figure 10.10 and figure 10.11 show what will happen if capital taxation continues on its downward spiral (intensified capital tax competition) into the 21st century. R>G will return. What the data suggests is that the after-tax return to capital fell from 1913-1950 (higher capital taxes) and continued to decline from 1950-2010 (stronger economic growth). During the 20th century, and for the first time in history, the net return on capital was less than the growth rate. This benefitted the middle of society. This was the period during which the social state, committed to providing public services and social protection, was born. Democracy gave birth to 'social' rights not the capitalist market.

The role of politics Figures 10.10 on R>G relies on the assumption that thee will be no political intervention to stop rising inequalities. But the R>G inequality is dependent upon and shaped by public policies and institutions i.e. the social and political context within which markets operate, and which are impossible to predict. To reverse the R>G inequality, economic growth (G) would need to persistently exceed 2 percent over the coming decades and/or taxes on capital (R) would need to reduce the net return to below 3 percent. Left to its own devises the market will ensure that the inequality in capital ownership and wealth will grow indefinitely. The freer the capital-market the greater the inequality of wealth.

Impact of war We still need to explain we have not returned to 19th century levels? The most important reason was that war in the 20 th century brought an end to role of inheritance. A new generation did not have the luxury of inheriting fortunes that would enable them to live as their grandparents had. The rich lost a lot of their capital assets (not least in their foreign colonies). Governments defaulted on the sovereign debt owned to wealthy individuals. This meant that those at very top of the wealth distribution (the top percentile) were disproportionately affected.

Taxation Total private wealth has (measured in capital/income ratios) regained the level it attained on the eve of WW1. The reason why it is has not become as unequal is because governments now tax capital and its income at significant rates. Up until WW1 there was no tax on corporate profits. If capital grows at 5% and the average capital tax rate is 30% then the net after tax return to capital will be around 3.5%. Taxes on capital do not modify the accumulation of wealth. They affect the distribution of wealth.

Conclusion Wealth inequalities grew throughout the 19th century because of the inequality R>G and the absence of a democratic state. Wealth inequalities declined in the 20th century because of the shocks of two wars and the creation democratic social rights Piketty suggests wealth inequality will increase to 19th century levels again because of: The return of the inequality R>G (slower growth) Increased tax competition among nation-states in a global financial market (lower taxes). On this basis he considers a global wealth tax the only option to defend democracy against economic inequalities.