Macro Lecture 11: Late 1990 s and Productivity

Similar documents
U. S. Productivity Growth:

U. S. Productivity Growth:

Friday, November 30 Handout: Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Model The Dynamics Review

Macro Lecture 8: Aggregate Supply Curves

Macro Lecture 16: Quantitative Easing

6. The Aggregate Demand and Supply Model

Macro Lecture 14: Late 2000 s Revisited. Fannie Mae Eases Credit To Aid Mortgage Lending

Lesson 11 Aggregate demand and Aggregate Supply

download instant at

II. Determinants of Asset Demand. Figure 1

Introduction. Over the long run, real GDP grows about 3% per year on average.

Macro Lecture 14: Late 2000 s Revisited

Archimedean Upper Conservatory Economics, October 2016

Test 1 Econ322 Section 002 Chappell February 16, 2009

ECON Drexel University Summer 2008 Assignment 2. Due date: July 29, 2008

Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

CHAPTER 23 OUTPUT AND PRICES IN THE SHORT RUN

Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Lecture 12: Economic Fluctuations. Rob Godby University of Wyoming

Chapter 12 Appendix B

Introduction to Economic Fluctuations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

AGGREGATE DEMAND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

ECON 212: ELEMENTS OF ECONOMICS II Univ. Of Ghana, Legon Lecture 8: Aggregate Demand Aggregate Supply Dr. Priscilla T. Baffour

Questions and Answers

University of Toronto July 27, 2006 ECO 209Y - L5101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2 DO NOT WRITE IN THIS SPACE. Part I /30.

Boğaziçi University, Department of Economics Spring 2016 EC 102 PRINCIPLES of MACROECONOMICS FINAL , Saturday 10:00 TYPE A

Objectives AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996

Notes 6: Examples in Action - The 1990 Recession, the 1974 Recession and the Expansion of the Late 1990s

ECON 209 FINAL EXAM COURSE PACK FALL 2017

Chapter 9 Chapter 10

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Economics 102 Discussion Handout Week 14 Spring Aggregate Supply and Demand: Summary

Economics 102 Discussion Handout Week 14 Spring Aggregate Supply and Demand: Summary

Business Fluctuations: Aggregate Demand and Supply

Macro CH 29 sample questions

I. Basic Concepts of Input Markets

Money and the Economy CHAPTER

Macro Lecture 6: The Banking System and the Money Market

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

10. Oferta y demanda agregada

Objectives for Class 26: Fiscal Policy

So far in the short-run analysis we have ignored the wage and price (we assume they are fixed).

Wednesday, November 14 Lecture: The Banking System and the Federal Reserve Board

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

Chapter 19 Prices and Output in an Open Economy: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 6

7 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapter. Key Concepts

Economics 102 Summer 2014 Answers to Homework #5 Due June 21, 2017

1 Figure 1 (A) shows what the IS LM model looks like for the case in which the Fed holds the

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 5

Macroeonomics. 20 this chapter, Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply. look for the answers to these questions: Introduction. N.

ECON 212 ELEMENTS OF ECONOMICS II

At the height of the financial crisis in December 2008, the Federal Open Market

ECO 2013: Macroeconomics Valencia Community College

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Public Affairs 856 Trade, Competition, and Governance in a Global Economy Lecture 4 2/5/2018. Instructor: Prof. Menzie Chinn UW Madison Spring 2018

OVERVIEW. 1. This chapter presents a graphical approach to the determination of income. Two different graphical approaches are provided.

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

AP Macroeconomics. Scoring Guidelines

If a model were to predict that prices and money are inversely related, that prediction would be evidence against that model.

The Professional Forecasters

ECON 3010 Intermediate Macroeconomics Final Exam

KOÇ UNIVERSITY ECON 202 Macroeconomics Fall Problem Set VI C = (Y T) I = 380 G = 400 T = 0.20Y Y = C + I + G.

Amherst College Department of Economics Economics 111 Section 5 Fall 2015 Macro Handout 19: Inflation Targeting and International Finance

GRAPHS IN ECONOMICS. Appendix. Key Concepts. Graphing Data

This is IS-LM, chapter 21 from the book Finance, Banking, and Money (index.html) (v. 1.1).

Mankiw Chapter 10. Introduction to Economic Fluctuations. Introduction to Economic Fluctuations CHAPTER 10

INFLATION, JOBS, AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE*

Chapter 6 Firms: Labor Demand, Investment Demand, and Aggregate Supply

CHAPTER 15 Long-Run Macroeconomic Adjustments

Macroeconomics LESSON 6 ACTIVITY 41

Homework Assignment #6. Due Tuesday, 11/28/06. Multiple Choice Questions:

Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Macroeconomics 1 Lecture 11: ASAD model

The text was adapted by The Saylor Foundation under the CC BY-NC-SA without attribution as requested by the works original creator or licensee

CHAPTER 2 *(Core Chapter) THE LAW OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE

Shanghai Livingston American School Quarterly / Trimester Plan 2

Aggregate Supply and Demand

THE NAIRU AND ITS EVOLUTION

A. What is the value of the tax increase multiplier if the MPC is.80? B. Consumption changes by 400 and disposable income by 100. What is the MPC?

VII. Short-Run Economic Fluctuations

Test Review. Question 1. Answer 1. Question 2. Answer 2. Question 3. Econ 719 Test Review Test 1 Chapters 1,2,8,3,4,7,9. Nominal GDP.

Prices and Output in an Open Economy: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Macroeconomics LESSON 3 ACTIVITY 23

Macro Lecture 6: The Banking System and the Money Market

3.1 Introduction. 3.2 Growth over the Very Long Run. 3.1 Introduction. Part 2: The Long Run. An Overview of Long-Run Economic Growth

MACROECONOMICS. Major Components of GDP. Consumption. Real consumption as a share of GDP. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:

Questions and Answers

14.02 Quiz #2 SOLUTION. Spring Time Allowed: 90 minutes

Chapter 4. Determination of Income and Employment 4.1 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ITS COMPONENTS

Introduction to Economics. MACROECONOMICS Chapter 2 Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

KING S UNIVERSITY COLLEGE. Economics 1022B (570 & 574) Review Questions for Chapter 27

The Economy Today 14th Edition SOLUTIONS MANUAL Schiller Gebhardt

Problem Set #5 Due in hard copy at beginning of lecture on Monday, April 8, 2013

Answers to Problem Set 4. Homework 4 Economics 301

Disposable income (in billions)

AP Macroeconomics Unit 5 & 6 Review Session

MEC Aggregate Investment, I

Transcription:

Macro Lecture 11: Late 1990 s and Productivity Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Model: A Summary Figures 11.1-11.3 and Table 11.1 summarize the aggregate demand/aggregate supply model: π (%) π (%) LRAS AS π E AD Figure 11.1: Aggregate demand (AD) curve GDP P Figure 11.2: aggregate supply (AS) and long run aggregate supply (LRAS) curves π (%) AS AD Figure 11.3: Equilibrium Intersection of AD and AS curves AD curve downward sloping LRAS curve vertical AS curve upward sloping Shifts from Shifts from Expected Fiscal Autonomous Place mark for potential Supply policies: monetary policies: GDP (GDP P inflation rate ) shocks changes Government purchases and taxes An economy s potential GDP depends its resources and technology Table 11.1: Aggregate demand/aggregate supply model summary Intersects LRAS curve at the expected inflation rate Adaptive expectations: Expected inflation rates equals actual inflation rate in the recent past

2 Clinton Years: 1995-1998 Table 11.2 reports the data from the mid-1990 s. The adaptive expectation principle allows us to complete the expected inflation rate column. Adaptive Expectations: The expected inflation rate depends on the actual inflation rate in the recent past. More specifically, we assume that the expected inflation rate in a given year equals the actual inflation rate in the previous year. Unemp Real Actual Infl Expected Infl Govt Year Rate (%) GDP Rate (%) Rate (%) Purch 1994 2.1 1995 5.6 10,165 2.1 2.1 2,260 1996 5.4 10,550 1.8 2.1 2,280 1997 4.9 11,025 1.7 1.8 2,320 1998 4.5 11,515 1.1 1.7 2,370 Table 11.2: Clinton years macro data: 1995-1998 We begin by focusing on 1995 and 1996. First, note that a long run equilibrium existed in π (%) LRAS 1995 LRAS 1996 1995; the actual rate inflation rate and the 2.50 AS expected inflation rate were equal, they both 1995 equaled 2.1 percent. Since the aggregate supply (AS) curve intersects the long run aggregate 2.25 supply (LRAS) curve at the expected inflation rate, two aggregate supply curves intersect at 2.1 percent in 1995 as shown in figure 11.4. 2.00 1.75 1995 1996 In 1996, the actual inflation rate fell from 2.1 to 1.8 percent and GDP increased from 10,165 to 10,550. Since the aggregate supply (AS) curve is upward sloping, it had to shift down between 1.50 1995 and 1996. 10,000 10,250 10,500 How could this happen? The aggregate supply Figure 11.4: Clinton years 1995 and 1996 (AS) and long run supply (LRAS) curves intersect at the expected inflation rate. Adaptive expectation suggests that the expected inflation rate remained unchanged at 2.1 percent in 1996. Since the expected inflation rate remained unchanged, how could the aggregate supply (AS) curve shift down? This is a puzzle isn t it? As figure 11.4 illustrates, an increase in potential GDP provides the solution. Since the aggregate supply (AS) and long run aggregate supply (LRAS) curves intersect at the expected inflation rate, the long run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve had to shift right. Recall that the long run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve is a place mark for potential GDP. Since the long run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve shifted right, potential GDP had to grow. AS 1996 Question: What causes potential GDP to grow? Answer: Since an economy potential GDP depends on the resources and technology available to it, resources have grown and/or technology have advanced. To address the question table 11.3 reports population and GDP data from 1948 and 1989: Real GDP Year Population (billions of 2009 $) 1948 144,600,000 2,020 1989 246,800,000 8,475 Growth rate = 70% Growth rate = 325% Table 11.3: Population and real GDP growth data

3 The U.S. population has grown thereby increasing potential GDP. But the growth of GDP outstripped the population growth indicating that American workers must have become more productive. We will now formally define what we mean by productivity: Productivity: The amount of goods and services produced in an hour by the average worker. We will now look at productivity growth more carefully. Productivity Growth: 1948-1989 Figure 11.5 plots productivity growth in the U.S. from 1948 to 1989. The overall trend was down. While the typical American worker produced more goods and services from year to year, the increase in production declined. This becomes even more apparent when we calculate average productivity growth rates for each decade. The average annual productivity growth rate is reported in table 11.4 and illustrated in figure 11.6: U. S. Productivity Growth: 1948 1989 8 6 4 2 0 2 1945 1955 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 Figure 11.5: U.S. productivity growth: 1948-1989 Average Annual Productivity Decade Growth (%) 1950 s 2.78 1960 s 2.77 1970 s 1.92 1980 s 1.47 Table 11.4: U.S. productivity data by decades Clearly, productivity growth had slowed although you might say that the decline is not large; the growth rate declined from 2.78 percent in the 1960 s to 1.47 percent in the 1980 s. 1950 s 1960 s 1970 s 1980 s At first glance, small differences in annual changes in growth rates do not appear important, but over time they can become significant. Figure 11.6: U.S. productivity growth by decades To appreciate this, suppose you earn $50,000 a year when you graduate. You can probably expect to work about 45 years. Table 11.5 compares what your salary would be when you retire if your annual increase is 2.78 percent compared to 1.47 percent: 2.78% annual 1.47% annual growth rate growth rate First year $50,000 $50,000 Second year $51,390 $50,735 Forty-five years later $171,700 $96,400 Table 11.5: Importance of growth rates In the second year the difference is small, less than $600. But after 45 years, the difference is nearly $80,000. Even though the difference between 2.78% and 1.47% appears to be small, it accumulates over time. A small annual difference becomes huge after forty-five years. Consequently, we should be concerned with the productivity decline experienced by the U.S. economy in these decades. (%) 3 2 1 2.78 2.77 1.92 1.47

4 We shall consider the determinants of productivity to try to understand why this has occurred: Natural resources Physical capital Human capital Labor reallocation Technology Physical Capital Physical capital refers to machines, tools, factories, etc. Obviously, the more machines, tools, factories, etc. an economy has, the more productive its workers will be. Industrialized nations have large amounts of physical capital, while developing nations have little. Consequently, workers in industrialized countries are more productive. As a worker is given more capital, he/she becomes more productive; that is, as capital per worker increases, productivity increases as illustrated by figure 11.7. Note that productivity increases at a decreasing rate, however. To understand why, consider a worker, George, who is cutting grass. If you give George a sickle, it takes him quite a while to cut a lawn. A hand mower would make George more productive, a power mower even more productive, and a lawn tractor yet more productive. As George moves from a sickle to hand mower, his productivity increases dramatically. As he moves from a hand mower to a power mower his productivity increases again, but by a smaller amount. As he moves from a hand mower to a lawn tractor, his productivity increases Productivity Capital per worker Figure 11.7: Diminishing marginal product of capital once more, but this time by an even smaller amount. This phenomenon is known as diminishing marginal productivity. When a worker uses more capital, his/her productivity increases. Each additional increment of capital leads to smaller increases in productivity, however. The productivity curve is increasing, but at a decreasing rate. Figure 11.8 compares two initial situations: capital per worker is low; capital per worker is high. Larger increments of new capital are required to achieve the same amount of productivity growth when capital per worker is initially high than when it is initially low. This occurs because productivity increases at a diminishing rate. Question: What do we call new capital? Answer: Investment. Accordingly, as workers have larger amount of capital, greater levels of investment are required to achieve a constant rate of productivity growth. Productivity Capital per worker Figure 11.8: Diminishing marginal product of capital

5 Let us focus on investment in the U.S. during the last sixty years. Table 11.6 reports on the average amount of investment per worker during the 1950 s, 1960 s, etc. Figure 11.9 illustrates the data with a bar chart. Annual Average of Real Investment per Decade Worker (2005 $) 1950 s 4,970 1960 s 6,870 1970 s 8,690 1980 s 8,870 1990 s 12,680 2000 s 17,050 Table 11.6: Investment per worker by decades Real investment per worker has increased during the last several decades (figure 11.9). It is possible, however, that the increase has not been enough to maintain a constant rate of productivity growth. Empirical studies suggest that this is probably not the case, however; that is, investment per worker has increased by so much that had nothing else occurred, productivity growth would had risen, rather than fallen. (2009 $) 20,000 16,000 12,000 1950 s 1960 s 1970 s 1980 s 1990 s Figure 11.9: U.S. investment per worker by decades Natural Resources Workers fortunate enough to live in economies rich in natural resources tend to have higher productivity. For example, American farmers in the American Midwest are perhaps the most productive farmers in the world. The soil and climate in the Midwest is largely responsible for the large amount of food that American farmers produce. Farmers in less endowed areas are not as productive. For example, farmers in New England are not as productive as their counterparts in the Midwest because New England weather and soil are not as good. We cannot attribute the decline in productivity growth in the U.S. to fewer natural resources, however. The U.S. has an abundance of natural resources. Human Capital Human capital refers to the education, skills, training, etc. that a worker accumulates over the years. As an economy s work force becomes more educated, more skilled, better trained, etc. its workers should become more productive. 8,000 4,000 2000 s On the one hand, there has been much concern about the U.S. educational system. Compared to children in some nations, Americans do not achieve the same level of performance. There is particular concern about mathematics in view of the fact that we live in an increasingly technological world. On the other hand, few doubt that the American higher education system is superb. College and graduate students from nearly all nations come to the U.S. to take advantage of the educational opportunities offered by American colleges and universities. Reallocating labor Moving labor from sectors with high productivity growth to sectors with low growth would reduce overall productivity growth. During the last few decades, labor has moved from the manufacturing sector to the service sector. Historically, service industries have experienced low rates of productivity growth. Consequently, moving labor to service industries would reduce overall productivity growth.

6 Technology Technology plays a large role in productivity. Technological advances explain much of our productivity increases. Communications provide a good example. Over the last century or so, we have progressed from handwritten letters, to typewritten letters, to word processing, to e-mail, etc. Improved communications has allowed us all to become more productive. Conclusion Empirical studies conclude that when we account for the effect of natural resources, physical capital, human capital, and the reallocation of labor we cannot explain the decline in productivity growth. That leaves us with one last source of growth: technology. It is difficult, if not impossible, to quantify technological change. Many argue that this has been perhaps the most important source of productivity growth. Consider American agriculture. In 1900, 40 percent of all American workers labored on farms. Today the figure is 3 percent. Despite the fact that fewer Americans work on farm, our farms produce much more food today than in 1900. Some believe that there has been a slowdown in technological innovations from the 1950 s to the 1980 s. With a fewer innovations, the productivity of American workers would not grow as rapidly. Note that there is no direct evidence here: there is no smoking gun. Some believe that technology must be the culprit because we cannot explain the slowdown in productivity in any other way. U. S. Productivity Growth: 1948 1989 If technology is the culprit, what could the government do to help promote innovations? There are a number of policies the government could adopt. For example, the government could finance more research and development; it could provide tax incentives for private firms to undertake research and development, etc. 8 6 4 2 0 2 1945 1955 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 The reasons for the U.S. Figure 11.10: U.S. productivity growth: 1948-1989 productivity slowdown from the 1950 s to the 1980 s, as illustrated in figure 11.10, are not fully understood. We can point to various factors, but there is no smoking gun. Furthermore, in view of the trend, most believed that the outlook for the 1990 s was dim.