CLAS. Utility Functions Handout

Similar documents
Microeconomics Pre-sessional September Sotiris Georganas Economics Department City University London

Consumer Theory. June 30, 2013

Graphs Details Math Examples Using data Tax example. Decision. Intermediate Micro. Lecture 5. Chapter 5 of Varian

2) Indifference curve (IC) 1. Represents consumer preferences. 2. MRS (marginal rate of substitution) = MUx/MUy = (-)slope of the IC = (-) Δy/Δx

Chapter 3. A Consumer s Constrained Choice

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis October 16, 2008 Professor John Parman. Midterm 1

Chapter 3: Model of Consumer Behavior

MICROECONOMIC THEORY 1

Summer 2016 Microeconomics 2 ECON1201. Nicole Liu Z

Chapter Four. Utility Functions. Utility Functions. Utility Functions. Utility

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

Microeconomic Analysis ECON203

Overview Definitions Mathematical Properties Properties of Economic Functions Exam Tips. Midterm 1 Review. ECON 100A - Fall Vincent Leah-Martin

Preferences - A Reminder

We want to solve for the optimal bundle (a combination of goods) that a rational consumer will purchase.

Midterm #1 Exam Study Questions AK AK AK Selected problems

Review of Previous Lectures

Midterm 1 - Solutions

a. Show the budget set containing all of the commodity bundles that the following individuals can afford.

Homework 3 Solutions

3/1/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 4: Solving the Consumer s Problem. The Story So Far. Today s Aims. Solving the Consumer s Problem

Garrison Schlauch - CLAS. This handout covers every type of utility function you will see in Econ 10A.

Intro to Economic analysis

Utility Maximization and Choice

Johanna has 10 to spend, the price of an apple is 1 and the price of a banana is 2. What are her options?

3. Consumer Behavior

File: ch03, Chapter 3: Consumer Preferences and The Concept of Utility

Math: Deriving supply and demand curves

MICROECONOMICS I REVIEW QUESTIONS SOLUTIONS

To do today. Find where on the budget line we choose to be. Need indifference curves for this. Graph equilibrium.

EconS Constrained Consumer Choice

Chapter 5: Utility Maximization Problems

p 1 _ x 1 (p 1 _, p 2, I ) x 1 X 1 X 2

Homework 2 ECN205 Spring 2011 Wake Forest University Instructor: McFall

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences

Midterm 1 - Solutions

Faculty: Sunil Kumar

Chapter 4 UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE

MODULE No. : 9 : Ordinal Utility Approach

Simple Model Economy. Business Economics Theory of Consumer Behavior Thomas & Maurice, Chapter 5. Circular Flow Model. Modeling Household Decisions

Lecture 4: Consumer Choice

LONG RUN SHORT RUN COST MINIMIZATION. Labor is variable Capital is fixed Solve for: labor only

Introductory to Microeconomic Theory [08/29/12] Karen Tsai

Lecture 1: The market and consumer theory. Intermediate microeconomics Jonas Vlachos Stockholms universitet

CONSUMPTION THEORY - first part (Varian, chapters 2-7)

14.54 International Trade Lecture 3: Preferences and Demand

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK!

Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

No books, notes, or other aids are permitted. You may, however, use an approved calculator. Do not turn to next pages until told to do so by examiner.

Chapter 4. Our Consumption Choices. What can we buy with this money? UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE

ANSWER KEY 3 UTILITY FUNCTIONS, THE CONSUMER S PROBLEM, DEMAND CURVES. u(c,s) = 3c+2s

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

ECON 310 Fall 2005 Final Exam - Version A. Multiple Choice: (circle the letter of the best response; 3 points each) and x

Problem Set 5 Answers. A grocery shop is owned by Mr. Moore and has the following statement of revenues and costs:

Consumer Choice. Theory of Consumer Behavior. Households and Firms. Consumer Choice & Decisions

Microeconomic Theory, Econ 323 Mostashari, Fall 2008 Exam 1 Version MAKEUP- KEY 50 minutes 100 Points Total. Name

Preferences and Utility

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 1 with Solutions

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 2, Question 1

Lecture 3: Consumer Choice

Midterm 1 (A) U(x 1, x 2 ) = (x 1 ) 4 (x 2 ) 2

The supply function is Q S (P)=. 10 points

CPT Section C General Economics Unit 2 Ms. Anita Sharma

Lecture 4 - Utility Maximization

ECN 2001 MICROECONOMICS I SLUTSKY EQUATION Class Discussion 6 (Ch. 7) - Answer Key TRUE-FALSE

The Rational Consumer. The Objective of Consumers. Maximizing Utility. The Budget Set for Consumers. Slope =

Income and Substitution Effects in Consumer Goods Markest

We will make several assumptions about these preferences:

PAPER NO.1 : MICROECONOMICS ANALYSIS MODULE NO.6 : INDIFFERENCE CURVES

Econ 4601 Urban & Regional Economics. Lecture 4: Utility. Instructor: Hiroki Watanabe. Summer 2010

Chapter 4 The Theory of Individual Behavior

myepathshala.com (For Crash Course & Revision)

CONSUMER BEHAVIOR. Total and Marginal Utility

(0.50, 2.75) (0,3) Equivalent Variation Compensating Variation

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 2

Topic 4b Competitive consumer

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Chapter Three. Preferences. Preferences. A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set of available alternatives.

Price. Quantity. Economics 101 Fall 2013 Homework 4 Due Tuesday, November 5, 2013

Consumer Theory. The consumer s problem: budget set, interior and corner solutions.

(0, 1) (1, 0) (3, 5) (4, 2) (3, 10) (4, 8) (8, 3) (16, 6)

Microeconomics I 2011/12

Chapter 4. Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization

x 1 = m 2p p 2 2p 1 x 2 = m + 2p 1 10p 2 2p 2

Chapter 3. Consumer Behavior

Problem Set 2 Solutions

Consider the production function f(x 1, x 2 ) = x 1/2. 1 x 3/4

1. You have an income of $40 to spend on two commodities. Commodity 1 costs $10 per unit and commodity 2 costs $5 per unit.

1 Consumer Choice. 2 Consumer Preferences. 2.1 Properties of Consumer Preferences. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 4 of the text.

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomics University of California - Davis July 7, 2010 Instructor: John Parman. Midterm - Solutions

U(x 1, x 2 ) = 2 ln x 1 + x 2

Sign Pledge I have neither given nor received aid on this exam

MIDTERM EXAM ANSWERS

MICROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH CONSUMER CHOICE AND BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS

<Table 1> Total Utility Marginal Utility Total Utility Marginal Utility

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

Practice Problems: First-Year M. Phil Microeconomics, Consumer and Producer Theory Vincent P. Crawford, University of Oxford Michaelmas Term 2010

Solutions to Assignment #2

Transcription:

Utility Functions Handout Intro: A big chunk of this class revolves around utility functions. Bottom line, utility functions tell us how we prefer to consume goods (and later how we want to produce) so that we maximize our utility (benefit). Some goods need to be consumed together in a fixed ratio, such as peanut butter and jelly (perfect complements). Some goods hurt us, or have negative utility, such as bad milk. Sometimes two goods serve the same purpose, and the consumption of one does not make the other better, such as Pepsi and Coke, since drinking Pepsi does not make Coke better (perfect substitutes). Most of the time our consumption will be restrained by a constraint, for example, a budget constrain. Using our utility functions (how we want to consume) and our constraint (the restriction on how much we can consume) we can find what our demand for each good is. We are going to spend a lot of time finding demand. Our functions include perfect substitutes, perfect complements, Cobb-Douglas, quasilinear increasing and decreasing, and max functions. Throughout this class, we will look at the SAME utility functions from DIFFERENT angles. At first, we look at the utility functions using the budget constraint. Later we will look at the utility functions from a different angle using the intertemporal budget constraint (a time constraint). When look at utility functions from different angles, their underlying characteristics STAY THE SAME, but solving the problems is slightly different. When we are looking at substitutes, regardless of whether we are using the budget constraint or the intertemporal budget constraint, we will want all of the good that gives the most bang for our buck. However, how we get there may be slightly different depending on what angle we are utilizing. When we go over a new angle at which to view preferences, the lecture notes and problems sets may only cover this new angle for some of the preferences (usually Cobb-Doug, maybe substitutes and complements). It would take the professor forever to cover every possibility. However, you are expected to know how to solve ALL of the applicable utility functions from the new angle. This sheet talks about the utility functions using the budget constraint, but the general rules learned here apply to preferences no matter what angle we are using. Learning how to identify, characterize, and solve all of the preferences now will make a significant portion of this class a lot easier. This guide is not exhaustive, nor does it replace lecture, section, hard work, ect. Take your time looking over this, and revisit it when you have done more problems. Best of luck, and I hope this helps!

Perfect Substitutes U(X,Y)=aX +by Examples: Pepsi and coke OR Ice-cream and frozen yogurt Since the marginal utility of x and the marginal utility of y (Mux and Muy) are constant, the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) is constant (EX MRS= -2 OR MRS = 5 OR MRS =1/2) Since the slope of the Indifference curves (IDCs) is the MRS, the IDCs are represented by a constant slope Examples: X + Y OR 4X + 5Y OR 10X +Y Any monotonic transformation of X + Y, Such as (X + Y) 3 OR X + Y +100 Think conceptually: Buy all of the good that gives the most BANG for your buck If both goods give the same bang for your buck, then you are indifferent between the two goods. You could consume all of good X, all of good Y, or some combination of the goods. o Methods (know all of the different methods!) 1. Sketch a graph: Compare the MRS (Mux/Muy) to the price ratio (Px/Py) 2. Compare Bang for Buck: Compare the utility per dollar for both goods (Mux/Px and Muy/Py) 3. Compare utility levels: find utility if all good 1 is purchased versus all good 2 purchased Check: am I getting the most utility possible?

Complements (Leontief) U(X,Y)=Min(aX,bY) Examples: Left and right shoes OR cups of coffee and sugar Examples: Min (X, Y/2) OR 5Min (X, Y) OR Min (5x, 5Y) Any Monotonic transformation of Min(aX, by) such as Min(aX, by) + 100 OR 3Min(aX,bY) (Note: monotonic transformations do NOT change the ratio at which you want to consume your goods. They DO change the total and marginal utility) Consume in a fixed ratio, where the two variables inside the Min function are equal. Think conceptually: I want to make the MOST bundles I can, while paying the least amount. This means I will not buy any extra of a good that will not contribute to a bundle. If we consume at U(x,y)= Min(10,50), our utility is 10, the lowest number. The extra 40 units of Y are not helping us at all, and it would receive the same amount of utility if we did not have them: Min(10,10)=10. We are buying 40 extra units of Y that are not increasing our utility at all! o Making peanut butter jelly sandwiches Example: Min(4X, 2Y). X= peanut butter and Y=jelly I want to make the most sandwiches I can. 1. Set the interior equal to find the fixed ratio at which to consume a. Consume at a fixed ratio 4X = 2Y X = Y/2. This means that for every unit of peanut butter, we want 2 units of jelly. This is the ratio needed to make a sandwich 2. Plug X=Y/2 into the budget constraint 3. Once one variable is solved, plug it into the budget constraint or the ratio (from setting the interior of the Min function equal) to get the other 4. Check: do I have an excess of either good?

Cobb-Douglas U(X,Y)=aX α by β Examples: 2X 1/2 Y 1/3 OR 2X 2 Y 3 + 100 Any monotonic transformation of ax α by β MRS is always diminishing (meaning our graph is convex), allowing you to use the tangency condition. Tangency tells us where are budget line (what we can afford) intersects our IDC (what we want) The slope of the budget line is P1/P2 and the slope of the IDC is the MRS, so tangency is where MRS=Px/Py This tells us where we want to consume, AKA the best IDC we can afford Think Mathematically: what are the steps to find demand in a Cobb-Douglas function? 1. Find MRS 2. Test for diminishing MRS (also known as DMRS)* 3. Set MRS = Px/Py 4. Plug answer from 3 (solved for either X or Y) into the budget constraint 5. Plug in solved variable into the budget constraint or MRS=Px/Py to find the other Variable. Check: is my math right? *Testing for DMRS is not necessary with Cobb-Douglas, since we know it has DMRS. It is, however, a good step to show on tests, and a good habit to have. Test for DMRS X Y If MRS decreases as X increases and Y decreases, the function Has DMRS. If MRS is constant for an increase in X, but is MRS? decreasing for a decrease in Y, it is still has DMRS. When one is constant, the other dominates.

Quasi-Linear U(X,Y)=V(X) + by For decreasing quasi-linear Examples: X + ln(y) OR 2X + Y 1/2 OR X 2 + Y Any monotonic transformation of V(X) + by If diminishing MRS Ex ( X + 2Y 1/2 ) The function is convex Notice that Mux is constant, while the Muy is diminishing. This means that at some point the next unit of x will give more utility than the next unit of Y, and you will not demand any more Y Y in this case is a zero-income effect good, meaning the amount of income you have does not affect how much Y you want An example would be pencils and all other goods. Assume you need 10 pencils to make it through the school year. No matter what your income is, you demand 10 pencils. More will not help you and less won t be enough to finish off the year. In this case, pencils are a zero-income effect good meaning income does not change the demand for pencils. When you solve for the demand for the diminishing Mu good, you will notice that income (M) is not a part of the equation. This is how you know it is a zero income effect good, since the level of M does not change the amount demanded 1. Find MRS 2. Test for DMRS 3. Decreasing quasi-linear has DMRS, so use tangency 4. MRS=Px/Py (you will solve for the variable with diminishing Mu in this step) 5. Plug the solved variable into the budget constraint, or into MRS=Px/Py

If increasing MRS Ex (X 2 + 2Y) The function does not have DMRS and is therefore not convex. You cannot use tangency Function has increasing MRS, meaning the graph is concave You buy all of one or the other. Consume which ever gives the most utility. One good (in this case Y) has constant MU, while the other good (in this case X) has increasing MU. Eventually the good with increasing MU will be better than the good with constant MU. For example and chocolate and an addictive drug: the first couple units of chocolate may be as good or better than the addictive drug, but if you are able to afford lots of units, the addictive drug becomes much better (Don t do drugs, kids!) Ex U(X,Y)=(X 2 + 2Y) If you could only consume 1 unit total you would buy all Y (chocolate). If you could consume 10 units, you would buy all of X (addictive drug). 1. Find MRs 2. Test for increasing MRS 3. Increasing MRS, can t use tangency, consume all of one or the other 4. Consume all of the good that gives the most utility Max U(X,Y)=Max(X,Y) Examples Max (3X, Y) OR 6Max(X, 3Y) OR Max(2X, 2Y) +100 Any monotonic transformation of Max(X,Y) Notice how the cheapest point on each IDC is on the corner, this tells us we will consume all of one or the other U(X,Y)=Max(100,0) = 100 AND Max(100,99)=100 Our utility in both cases is 100. Notice that only the highest number maters. There is no point in purchasing 99 units of good Y. Purchase all of one or the other. Buy all of the good that gives the most utility Compare Bang for Buck: Compare the utility per dollar for both goods Compare utility levels: find utility if all good 1 is purchased versus all good 2 purchased

Demand Problems Substitutes 1. U(X, Y) = 5X + 2Y Px=6 Py=2 M=24 What is X* and Y*? 2. U(X, Y) = 2X + 3Y Px=2 Py=2 M=12 What is X* and Y*? 3. U(X, Y) = 3X + Y No prices/income given What is X* and Y*? Complements 1. U(X, Y) = Min(2X, Y) Px=10 Py=2 M=28 What is X* and Y*? 2. U(X, Y) = 5Min(X, Y/5) Px=5 Py=1 M=50 Y=20 What is X*? a. What would X* and Y* be if Y was not fixed at 20? Cobb-Douglas 1. U(X, Y) = X 2 Y No prices/income given What is X* and Y*? Quasi-Linear Decreasing 1. U(X,Y) = 2X 1/2 + Y No prices/income given What is X* and Y*? 2. U(X, Y) = X + ln(y) No prices/income given What is X* and Y*? Quasi-Linear Increasing Max 1. U(X, Y) = X 2 + 5Y Px=5 Py=3 M=30 What is X* and Y*? 1. U(X, Y) = 2Max(3X, Y) Px=4 Py=1 M=20 What is X* and Y*?