"FOREIGN" BEHAVIOR FOR THE U.S.? Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer Rotary Club of Paducah September 14, 1988

Similar documents
"FOREIGN" BEHAVIOR FOR THE U.S.? Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer 1988 Kickoff Breakfast Greater St. Louis U.S. Savings Bonds Drive March 2, 1988

TRUE FACTS AND FALSE PERCEPTIONS ABOUT FEDERAL DEFICITS" Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer Rotary Club of Springfield, Missouri December 6, 1988

THE SHRINKING CURRENT ACCOUNT DEFICIT: Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer St. Louis Society of Financial Analysts St. Louis, Missouri May 28, 1992

FIRST LOOK AT MACROECONOMICS*

Trade deficits and the US economy Part I

HOW CAN THE FED INFLUENCE INTEREST RATES AND SUSTAIN GROWTH? Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer President, Federal Reserve Bank of St.

Normalizing Monetary Policy

Ewart S Williams: Understanding the Heritage and Stabilisation Fund

Helpful Hint Fiscal Policy and the AS-AD Model

Rebalancing Toward Sustainable Growth. Thomas M. Hoenig President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

18 INTERNATIONAL FINANCE* Chapter. Key Concepts

DEBT-EQUITY SWAPS. Euromoney-Mexico Debt to Equity Conversion and Investment Conference. Mexico City, May 26-27, 1987.

The Benefits of World Capital Flows

DEFICITS DEBT AND DEFICITS: WHAT ARE THEY? . i:

Haruhiko Kuroda: Japan s economy and monetary policy

10 Chapter Outline What is Keynesianism?

In our recent discussion of the Common Market we stated that. economic and political factors often are just as important as military

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

THE NEW ECONOMY RECESSION: ECONOMIC SCORECARD 2001

FED POLICY POST OCTOBER 6. Remarks by. David P. Eastburn. President. Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. Before the. Philadelphia Chapter

Club Accounts - David Wilson Question 6.

Economic Barometer. Mixed Signals. Labor Market Improvement Household Demand Household Demand Continued Business Demand

Appropriate monetary policy and the strong economy Before the Committee on Banking and Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives July 23, 1997

Precarious to prosperous: Tackling income volatility in Canada. Bharat Masrani Group President and Chief Executive Officer, TD Bank Group

Ric Battellino: Recent financial developments

Lyle E. Gramley MEMBER, BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM. Conrnunity Leaders in Seattle

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES U.S. GROWTH IN THE DECADE AHEAD. Martin S. Feldstein. Working Paper

Canada s Economic Future: What Have We Learned from the 1990s?

INCREASING THE RATE OF CAPITAL FORMATION (Investment Policy Report)

Lecture #8: How Scary is the US Trade Deficit?

Monetary Policy and Economic Outcomes *

Small Business Lending Roundtable Committee on Small Business United States House of Representatives

How Is Global Trade Financed? (EA)

From The Collected Works of Milton Friedman, compiled and edited by Robert Leeson and Charles G. Palm.

Are we on the road to recovery?

A Look at the Regional and National Economies

Can collective pension schemes work in the United Kingdom? Received (in revised form): 14 th August 2012

Japan's Economy and Monetary Policy

Remarks by James K. Galbraith at the Economists for Peace and. Security Bernard Schwartz Symposium on Jobs, Investment and Energy.

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 4

Club of Nashville. I am familiar with the tight ship you run to get your speakers on and off,

Mr Thiessen converses on the conduct of monetary policy in Canada under a floating exchange rate system

Canada s Economy and Household Debt: How Big Is the Problem?

Know when to use them.know when to lose them

GOVERNMENT DEFICITS, MONETARY POLICY, AND INFLATION Remarks by Darryl R. Francis, President. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit

What Should the Fed Do?

Views on the Economy and Price-Level Targeting

Introduction To The Income Statement

Implications of Fiscal Austerity for U.S. Monetary Policy

The Circular Flow Model

Ian J Macfarlane: Payment imbalances

Economy In Crisis: How Global Financial Crisis Affects India & The World?

BALANCING THE FEDERAL BUDGET: ECONOMIC RATIONALE AND ISSUES

Commentary: Achieving Growth Amid Fiscal Imbalances

Economic Activity, Prices, and Monetary Policy in Japan

Wednesday, November 14 Lecture: The Banking System and the Federal Reserve Board

Policy Note 2000/6 Drowning In Debt

Chapter 21: Study Questions Key, Version A

GETTING RID OF DEBT: WHAT IS THE BEST OPTION FOR YOU?

The Social Security Protection Plan

Masaaki Shirakawa: The transition from high growth to stable growth Japan s experience and implications for emerging economies

YOUR GUIDE TO PRE- SETTLEMENT ADVANCES

The fiscal adjustment after the crisis in Argentina

The U.S. Economy and Monetary Policy. Esther L. George President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

Global Imbalances. January 23rd

Testimony of. William Grant. On Behalf of the. Before the. Of the. United

Lars Nyberg: Developments in the property market

JAPAN s CURRENT FINANCIAL & ECONOMIC CRISIS. AContrarianView?

DEBTS AND DISPUTES. Understanding Debt. What to do?

Answers to Questions: Chapter 5

KEYNOTE SPEECH Deputy Governor of Bank Indonesia, Bp. Perry Warjiyo Ph.D at BNP Paribas Economic Outlook 2016 Jakarta, 23 March 2016

The Future Performance of the Canadian Economy

DEFICITS AND DEBT Macroeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Econ 340: Money, Banking and Financial Markets Midterm Exam, Spring 2009

Welcome again to our Farm Management and Finance educational series. Borrowing money is something that is a necessary aspect of running a farm or

Chapter 02 National Income Accounting

by David P. Eastburn President, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia before THE PHILADELPHIA JAYCEES at the "First Thursday Luncheon"

Objectives for Chapter 24: Monetarism (Continued) Chapter 24: The Basic Theory of Monetarism (Continued) (latest revision October 2004)

Ch. 2 AN OVERVIEW OF THE FINANCIAL SYSTEM

CFEPS. Center for Full Employment and Price Stability. Special Report 04/02 REVISITING THE LIBERAL AGENDA BY WARREN B. MOSLER

Central Bank Balance Sheets: Misconceptions and Realities

PubPol 201. Module 1: International Trade Policy. Class 3 Outline. Definitions. Class 3 Outline. Definitions. Definitions. Class 3

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld

I don't understand the argument that even though inflation is not accelerating, the world nevertheless suffers from "global excess liquidity":

The Bible and Personal Finances Part 3

Economic Discussion A Review of the Economy and Financial Markets

ECONOMIC UPDATE. Rotary Club of Northern Guam. Bank of Guam. Presented to the. as a Value Added Service by

Causes of the Trade Deficit. Written Statement of. Barry K. Rogstad, President American Business Conference. The Trade Deficit Review Commission

Micro versus Macro PP542. National Income Accounts. Micro versus Macro (cont.) National Income Accounts: GNP. National Income Accounts: GNP (cont.

Laurence Ball Johns Hopkins University March 25, 2010 TESTIMONY BEFORE THE HOUSE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES

MONEY. Economics Unit 4 Macroeconomics Just the Facts Handout

Lower prices. Lower costs, esp. wages. Higher productivity. Higher quality/more desirable exports. Greater natural resources. Higher interest rates

Test bank for Macroeconomics 12th Edition by Rudiger Dornbusch Dr, Stanley Fischer, Richard Startz

The Role of Foreign Financial Institutions in Japan's Financial System

Global Imbalances and the Financial Crisis: Products of Common Causes

AND INVESTMENT * Chapt er. Key Concepts

Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit

Objectives for Class 26: Fiscal Policy

How Do You Calculate Cash Flow in Real Life for a Real Company?

Transcription:

SAVING: "FOREIGN" BEHAVIOR FOR THE U.S.? Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer Rotary Club of Paducah September 14, 1988 Today, we all recognize that economic events and related policy actions have a powerful influence on what happens in our communities, our businesses and, of course, our own lives. Thus, while we can take comfort that, at the present moment, the economy is in reasonably good shape, we are naturally concerned about what the future holds. As a result, widespread public attention is focused on announcements of the latest inflation, output and employment numbers, the most recent federal deficit figures, and the current trade deficit calculations. We wonder whether the next announcement will bring good news or bad; and what, if anything, we can do to prevent some of our potential problems from becoming actual ones. It is certainly true that the causes of our current and prospective economic problems are many and varied. However, there is one factor that is related in a fundamental way to many of the prospective problems we face the extremely low rate of personal saving in this country. Today, I would like to say a few words about the general importance of saving; why we, as a nation, need to save more; and what the Federal Reserve can do to encourage saving. Throughout history, saving has been characterized as truly virtuous behavior. In recent years, I am sorry to say, savings behavior in the U.S. has not been all that virtuous. Since 1982, as individuals, we have saved, on average, about 2.3 percent of our income each year. Our personal savings rate is not only down sharply from its 6.6 percent

- 2 - average rate in the late 1970s; it is also abysmally low when compared to personal savings rates in other industrial countries. For example, in 1987, the personal savings rate in Japan was about 11 percent, and in Germany, almost 8 percent. While these rates may be a bit overstated due to differences in measurement, there is still a whopping imbalance. Now, it might be easy to say "so what?" when confronted with comparisons showing how low this nation ranks in terms of its savings. After all, we are well into the sixth year of the current expansion. Since 1982, more than 15 million new jobs have been created; and over this period, our real output growth has averaged better than 4 percent per year. However, such a quick-and-easy dismissal of our failure to save more would be a serious mistake. Our lack of saving in this decade has come to be viewed with alarm by many people for reasons that relate closely to our national self-interest. The problem we face is simple to state, but difficult to solve as long as our savings rate remains low. Our problem is where to find the funds to provide for private investment, on the one hand, and to cover our federal deficit, on the other. As you well know, investment is vital to maintaining economic growth and, thereby, providing for continued expansion of jobs and income in this country. The record of continuing growth since 1982 could not have been achieved if, in recent years, we had not spent about 16 percent of our GNP on gross private domestic investment. Last year, for example, gross investment totalled nearly $720 billion. This year and next, we will need to spend even more if our expansion is to continue into the future.

- 3 - Another activity that absorbs funds is our federal deficit When government spending exceeds its tax receipts and other revenues, the additional funds must come from someone. During the 1980s, federal deficits have grown to substantial proportions. Last year, for example, the federal deficit exceeded $150 billion the sixth triple-digit deficit in a row; and this year it will again reach $150 billion or more. Thus, despite all our good intentions, it appears that large federal deficits will be with us for some time to come. Whether federal deficits are "good" or "bad" per se is not important to what I am saying. My point is simply that someone is going to have to provide the funds to cover them someone is going to have to buy those government bonds. And given the sheer size of our federal deficit, a shortfall in funding could "squeeze out" private investment to a significant extent. Now, "the $870 billion dollar question," to use last year f s total gross investment and federal deficit figure, is who is going to provide the funds necessary to finance these requirements? There are only three potential sources of funds available for this purpose: our own domestic savings, the savings of foreigners, and government bond purchases by the Federal Reserve System. The only way to answer Does it matter to us who provides these funds? this is to look at the consequences of each of these sources of financing. Let's start with our own domestic savings. People save by spending less on consumption goods than they earn in income. We save for a variety of reasons: to provide for retirement, to insure against those nasty "rainy days," to purchase big-ticket items like cars and houses, and to leave bequests. Saving is a conscious effort to spend less now so that we can spend more in the future. Digitized for FRASER

- 4 - Last year, our personal savings totalled $120 billion, about 2.7 percent of our GNP. This is less than 14 percent of the funds that were spent on investment and the federal deficit. Thankfully, there are other sources of domestic savings in addition to our personal savings. Gross business savings contributed more than $550 billion; state and local government surpluses added another $45 billion. Thus, in total, we saved about $720 billion of the $870 billion that was spent to fund U.S. investment and the federal deficit last year. Now, where in the world did the other $150 billion come from? Where in the world indeed! It came from the rest of the world. When people in one nation save more than their own current investment spending and government deficits, these additional savings will flow to wherever the demand for them is the greatest. Because we do not save enough to fund our own investment and government deficits, we have had to rely on the savings of our friends abroad. Last year, foreigners bought, on net, about $150 billion of U.S. bonds, equities and other assets. But the process of attracting foreign savings is not costless; nor, can it last forever. To purchase dollar-denominated assets, foreigners first had to acquire these dollars. In the process, they bid up its value. The increased value of the dollar encourages more imports and discourages exports the trade deficit that ensues provides the necessary dollars for foreign investment in the U.S. Thus, for every dollar of foreign savings we attracted, our trade deficit increased by one dollar. Last year alone, our trade deficit reached approximately $150 billion. This figure is no coincidence. It represents precisely the $150 billion worth of our investment and government deficit that was financed by foreigners.

- 5 - Now, should we worry if foreigners want to channel their savings into the U.S.? Perhaps, as long as this flow of foreign savings continues unabated, we don't have to be overly concerned. It's true, of course, that import-competing and export industries suffer a reduction in output and employment, but other industries pick up the slack. Certainly, this is what has happened since 1982; despite our large trade deficits in recent years, our output and employment have grown at historic rates and our unemployment rate has declined substantially. So why worry? Well, like all borrowing, our foreign debt eventually must be repaid. Currently, we owe foreigners, on net, around $450 billion, and this amount is rising rapidly. When it comes time to repay our debt, we as a nation, like all debtors, will have to tighten our belts; we'll have to consume less in order to repay. This means, as we repay our foreign debt, that our standard of living will be significantly lower than it would have been otherwise. Whether our economy will be forced to undergo a period of very low growth to repay these debts depends on how productively we have used these foreign borrowings. One thing, however, is certain; repayment will not be painless. And, unless we can start to reduce the pace of growth of our foreign indebtedness, the pain will be all the more severe. A third possible source of financing is the Federal Reserve. The Fed, in the normal course of conducting monetary policy, purchases and sells government securities. This process is called open market operations. It represents the day-in and day-out manner by which the Federal Reserve adjusts the nation's bank reserves and the money stock.

- 6 - Occasionally, someone or other suggests that the Federal Reserve should buy even larger amounts of government debt and thus reduce the amount of domestic and foreign saving that is necessary. The chief problem with this "solution" is that, when the Fed buys government securities, it pays for these securities with newly-created money. If this "monetizing the deficit" were done on the scale necessary to influence our need for savings meaningfully, the result would be both perfectly predictable and catastrophic in the extreme. In no time at all, we would have high inflation, high interest rates and a general collapse of domestic financial markets. "Chaotic" would be a mild description of the consequence of such actions. Now, I f m not trying to scare us into saving more by threatening financial ruin if we don't raise our savings rate. All available evidence suggests that the Federal Reserve has not followed a policy of monetizing the deficit in the past, and we are certainly not going to do so in the future for the very reasons that I've just mentioned. My purpose for listing the potential options is to convince you how important it is for us, as a nation, to save more and to start to do so now. Let us review the possibilities. We can allow our investment to decline drastically and forego economic growth far into the future. Clearly, this is not desirable something to be avoided at all costs. We can reduce the government deficit. But that does not seem probable given our experience of the past several years. Thus, it seems that we have to assume that the rate of investment and the deficit are given, and our real options are to finance it through domestic or foreign savings.

- 7 - Financing these expenditures through foreign savings implies continuing trade deficits for now, but ultimately a major adjustment problem when we have to repay our foreign indebtedness Indeed, it seems to me that the process of adjustment may have already begun. Foreigners have become more reluctant to lend to us. This reluctance is clearly demonstrated by the decline in the dollar exchange rate since 1985 and by the decline of private foreign investment in the U.S. In the past year, a quarter of our trade deficit was financed by foreign central banks in their attempt to prevent the dollar from declining even further. What if even the central banks become reluctant? The dollar would fall more precipitously and real interest rates would have to rise. The rise in interest rates would ultimately increase savings, but it would also reduce investment and add to the volatility of financial markets. There is no doubt that market forces will eventually solve the savings and investment problem, and there is no doubt that eventually the savings disparity and the international balance will be resolved. But at what cost? On the other hand, if we were to save more at current interest rates, much of the adjustment pain could be alleviated. The dollar would stabilize, interest rates would not have to rise, and investment would not have to be curtailed. Thus, while we have always looked upon saving as an individual virtue, at this time it has become a national priority. You may recall, at the beginning of this talk, I promised to say something about what the Federal Reserve can do to encourage Americans to save more. Directly, of course, the Fed can do nothing; you and I are the ones who save and we make our savings decision based on our own circumstances and opportunities. The Federal Reserve cannot save for us;

- 8 - we have already discussed the adverse consequences that would occur if the Federal Reserve were to monetize the federal deficit. However, the Federal Reserve can play a crucial though indirect role by pursuing policy actions that foster a stable economic environment, primarily one in which we have stable prices and reasonable long-run economic growth. I believe that the Federal Reserve can accomplish this role, and I have proposed certain policy procedures that will help it to do so. I am convinced that, with the appropriate policy actions in place to provide the necessary economic backdrop, we, as a nation, will save more. And, while the increase in savings will certainly not solve all our prospective problems, it would represent a major step toward reducing the risks that we face in the coming years.