Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Similar documents
THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Completeness and Hedging. Tomas Björk

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

Risk Neutral Measures

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE.

************* with µ, σ, and r all constant. We are also interested in more sophisticated models, such as:

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

VII. Incomplete Markets. Tomas Björk

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Lévy models in finance

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Black-Scholes Option Pricing

Finance II. May 27, F (t, x)+αx f t x σ2 x 2 2 F F (T,x) = ln(x).

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

CHAPTER 2: STANDARD PRICING RESULTS UNDER DETERMINISTIC AND STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATES

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Good Deal Bounds. Tomas Björk, Department of Finance, Stockholm School of Economics, Lausanne, 2010

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Derivative Securities Section 9 Fall 2004 Notes by Robert V. Kohn, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences.

Path Dependent British Options

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 6

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Stochastic Finance - A Numeraire Approach

Hedging under Arbitrage

Risk Neutral Valuation

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

Stochastic Volatility

Interest rate models in continuous time

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Enlargement of filtration

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

To have a concrete example in mind, suppose that we want to price a European call option on a stock that matures in six months.

Risk Neutral Pricing. to government bonds (provided that the government is reliable).

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS

CHAPTER 12. Hedging. hedging strategy = replicating strategy. Question : How to find a hedging strategy? In other words, for an attainable contingent

Arbitrages and pricing of stock options

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

Discrete time interest rate models

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

FINANCIAL OPTIMIZATION. Lecture 5: Dynamic Programming and a Visit to the Soft Side

Help Session 2. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Basics of Asset Pricing Theory {Derivatives pricing - Martingales and pricing kernels

The British Russian Option

An application of an entropy principle to short term interest rate modelling

Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee

The Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

1 Implied Volatility from Local Volatility

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends.

Martingale Measure TA

The Black-Scholes Model

Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model

A Simple Approach to CAPM and Option Pricing. Riccardo Cesari and Carlo D Adda (University of Bologna)

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria web: July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M

The Black-Scholes Equation

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

Advanced topics in continuous time finance

BLACK SCHOLES THE MARTINGALE APPROACH

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

Transcription:

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH 2010 Tomas Björk Tomas Björk, 2010

Contents 1. Mathematics recap. (Ch 10-12) 2. Recap of the martingale approach. (Ch 10-12) 3. Change of numeraire. (Ch 26) Björk,T. Arbitrage Theory in Continuous Time. 3:rd ed. 2009. Oxford University Press. Tomas Björk, 2010 1

1. Mathematics Recap Ch. 10-12 Tomas Björk, 2010 2

Contents 1. Conditional expectations 2. Changing measures 3. The Martingale Representation Theorem 4. The Girsanov Theorem Tomas Björk, 2010 3

1.1 Conditional Expectation Tomas Björk, 2010 4

Conditional Expectation If F is a sigma-algebra and X is a random variable which is F-measurable, we write this as X F. If X F and if G F then we write E [X G] for the conditional expectation of X given the information contained in G. Sometimes we use the notation E G [X]. The following proposition contains everything that we will need to know about conditional expectations within this course. Tomas Björk, 2010 5

Main Results Proposition 1: Assume that X F, and that G F. Then the following hold. The random variable E [X G] is completely determined by the information in G so we have E [X G] G If we have Y G then Y is completely determined by G so we have E [XY G] = Y E [X G] In particular we have E [Y G] = Y If H G then we have the law of iterated expectations In particular we have E [E [X G] H] = E [X H] E [X] = E [E [X G]] Tomas Björk, 2010 6

1.2 Changing Measures Tomas Björk, 2010 7

Absolute Continuity Definition: Given two probability measures P and Q on F we say that Q is absolutely continuous w.r.t. P on F if, for all A F, we have P (A) = 0 Q(A) = 0 We write this as Q << P. If Q << P and P << Q then we say that P and Q are equivalent and write Q P Tomas Björk, 2010 8

Equivalent measures It is easy to see that P and Q are equivalent if and only if P (A) = 0 Q(A) = 0 or, equivalently, P (A) = 1 Q(A) = 1 Two equivalent measures thus agree on all certain events and on all impossible events, but can disagree on all other events. Simple examples: All non degenerate Gaussian distributions on R are equivalent. If P is Gaussian on R and Q is exponential then Q << P but not the other way around. Tomas Björk, 2010 9

Absolute Continuity ct d Consider a given probability measure P and a random variable L 0 with E P [L] = 1. Now define Q by Q(A) = A LdP then it is easy to see that Q is a probability measure and that Q << P. A natural question is now if all measures Q << P are obtained in this way. The answer is yes, and the precise (quite deep) result is as follows. Tomas Björk, 2010 10

The Radon Nikodym Theorem Consider two probability measures P and Q on (Ω, F), and assume that Q << P on F. Then there exists a unique random variable L with the following properties 1. Q(A) = LdP, A F A 2. L 0, P a.s. 3. E P [L] = 1, 4. L F The random variable L is denoted as L = dq dp, on F and it is called the Radon-Nikodym derivative of Q w.r.t. P on F, or the likelihood ratio between Q and P on F. Tomas Björk, 2010 11

A simple example The Radon-Nikodym derivative L is intuitively the local scale factor between P and Q. If the sample space Ω is finite so Ω = {ω 1,..., ω n } then P is determined by the probabilities p 1,..., p n where p i = P (ω i ) i = 1,..., n Now consider a measure Q with probabilities q i = Q(ω i ) i = 1,..., n If Q << P this simply says that p i = 0 q i = 0 and it is easy to see that the Radon-Nikodym derivative L = dq/dp is given by L(ω i ) = q i p i i = 1,..., n Tomas Björk, 2010 12

If p i = 0 then we also have q i = 0 and we can define the ratio q i /p i arbitrarily. If p 1,..., p n as well as q 1,..., q n are all positive, then we see that Q P and in fact as could be expected. dp dq = 1 L = ( ) 1 dq dp Tomas Björk, 2010 13

Computing expected values A main use of Radon-Nikodym derivatives is for the computation of expected values. Suppose therefore that Q << P on F and that X is a random variable with X F. With L = dq/dp on F then have the following result. Proposition 3: With notation as above we have E Q [X] = E P [L X] Tomas Björk, 2010 14

The Abstract Bayes Formula We can also use Radon-Nikodym derivatives in order to compute conditional expectations. The result, known as the abstract Bayes Formula, is as follows. Theorem 4: Consider two measures P and Q with Q << P on F and with L F = dq dp on F Assume that G F and let X be a random variable with X F. Then the following holds E Q [X G] = EP [ L F X G ] E P [L F G] Tomas Björk, 2010 15

Dependence of the σ-algebra Suppose that we have Q << P on F with L F = dq dp on F Now consider smaller σ-algebra G F. Our problem is to find the R-N derivative L G = dq dp on G We recall that L G is characterized by the following properties 1. Q(A) = E [ ] P L G I A A G 2. L G 0 3. E [ P L G] = 1 4. L G G Tomas Björk, 2010 16

A natural guess would perhaps be that L G = L F, so let us check if L F satisfies points 1-4 above. By assumption we have Q(A) = E P [ L F I A ] A F Since G F we then have Q(A) = E P [ L F I A ] A G so point 1 above is certainly satisfied by L F. It is also clear that L F satisfies points 2 and 3. It thus seems that L F is also a natural candidate for the R-N derivative L G, but the problem is that we do not in general have L F G. This problem can, however, be fixed. expectations we have, for all A G, By iterated E P [ L F I A ] = E P [ E P [ L F I A G ]] Tomas Björk, 2010 17

Since A G we have E P [ L F I A G ] = E P [ L F G ] I A Let us now define L G by L G = E P [ L F G ] We then obviously have L G G and Q(A) = E P [ L G I A ] A G It is easy to see that also points 2-3 are satisfied so we have proved the following result. Tomas Björk, 2010 18

A formula for L G Proposition 5: If Q << P on F and G F then, with notation as above, we have L G = E P [ L F G ] Tomas Björk, 2010 19

The likelihood process on a filtered space We now consider the case when we have a probability measure P on some space Ω and that instead of just one σ-algebra F we have a filtration, i.e. an increasing family of σ-algebras {F t } t 0. The interpretation is as usual that F t is the information available to us at time t, and that we have F s F t for s t. Now assume that we also have another measure Q, and that for some fixed T, we have Q << P on F T. We define the random variable L T by L T = dq dp on F T Since Q << P on F T we also have Q << P on F t for all t T and we define L t = dq dp on F t 0 t T For every t we have L t F t, so L is an adapted process, known as the likelihood process. Tomas Björk, 2010 20

The L process is a P martingale We recall that L t = dq dp on F t 0 t T Since F s F t for s t we can use Proposition 5 and deduce that L s = E P [L t F s ] s t T and we have thus proved the following result. Proposition: Given the assumptions above, the likelihood process L is a P -martingale. Tomas Björk, 2010 21

Where are we heading? We are now going to perform measure transformations on Wiener spaces, where P will correspond to the objective measure and Q will be the risk neutral measure. For this we need define the proper likelihood process L and, since L is a P -martingale, we have the following natural questions. What does a martingale look like in a Wiener driven framework? Suppose that we have a P -Wiener process W and then change measure from P to Q. What are the properties of W under the new measure Q? These questions are handled by the Martingale Representation Theorem, and the Girsanov Theorem respectively. Tomas Björk, 2010 22

1.3 The Martingale Representation Theorem Tomas Björk, 2010 23

Intuition Suppose that we have a Wiener process W under the measure P. We recall that if h is adapted (and integrable enough) and if the process X is defined by X t = x 0 + t 0 h s dw s then X is a a martingale. We now have the following natural question: Question: Assume that X is an arbitrary martingale. Does it then follow that X has the form X t = x 0 + t 0 h s dw s for some adapted process h? In other words: Are all martingales stochastic integrals w.r.t. W? Tomas Björk, 2010 24

Answer It is immediately clear that all martingales can not be written as stochastic integrals w.r.t. W. Consider for example the process X defined by { 0 for 0 t < 1 X t = Z for t 1 where Z is an random variable, independent of W, with E [Z] = 0. X is then a martingale (why?) but it is clear (how?) that it cannot be written as X t = x 0 + t 0 h s dw s for any process h. Tomas Björk, 2010 25

Intuition The intuitive reason why we cannot write X t = x 0 + t 0 h s dw s in the example above is of course that the random variable Z has nothing to do with the Wiener process W. In order to exclude examples like this, we thus need an assumption which guarantees that our probability space only contains the Wiener process W and nothing else. This idea is formalized by assuming that the filtration {F t } t 0 is the one generated by the Wiener process W. Tomas Björk, 2010 26

The Martingale Representation Theorem Theorem. Let W be a P -Wiener process and assume that the filtation is the internal one i.e. F t = F W t = σ {W s ; 0 s t} Then, for every (P, F t )-martingale X, there exists a real number x and an adapted process h such that X t = x + t 0 h s dw s, i.e. dx t = h t dw t. Proof: Hard. This is very deep result. Tomas Björk, 2010 27

Note For a given martingale X, the Representation Theorem above guarantees the existence of a process h such that X t = x + t 0 h s dw s, The Theorem does not, however, tell us how to find or construct the process h. Tomas Björk, 2010 28

1.4 The Girsanov Theorem Tomas Björk, 2010 29

Setup Let W be a P -Wiener process and fix a time horizon T. Suppose that we want to change measure from P to Q on F T. For this we need a P -martingale L with L 0 = 1 to use as a likelihood process, and a natural way of constructing this is to choose a process g and then define L by { dlt = g t dw t L 0 = 1 This definition does not guarantee that L 0, so we make a small adjustment. We choose a process ϕ and define L by { dlt = L t ϕ t dw t L 0 = 1 The process L will again be a martingale and we easily obtain L t = e R t 0 ϕ sdw s 1 R t 2 0 ϕ2 s ds Tomas Björk, 2010 30

Thus we are guaranteed that L 0. We now change measure form P to Q by setting dq = L t dp, on F t, 0 t T The main problem is to find out what the properties of W are, under the new measure Q. This problem is resolved by the Girsanov Theorem. Tomas Björk, 2010 31

The Girsanov Theorem Let W be a P -Wiener process. Fix a time horizon T. Theorem: Choose an adapted process ϕ, and define the process L by { dlt = L t ϕ t dw t L 0 = 1 Assume that E P [L T ] = 1, and define a new mesure Q on F T by dq = L t dp, on F t, 0 t T Then Q << P and the process W Q, defined by W Q t = W t t 0 ϕ s ds is Q-Wiener. We can also write this as dw t = ϕ t dt + dw Q t Tomas Björk, 2010 32

Changing the drift in an SDE The single most common use of the Girsanov Theorem is as follows. Suppose that we have a process X with P dynamics dx t = µ t dt + σ t dw t where µ and σ are adapted and W is P -Wiener. We now do a Girsanov Transformation as above, and the question is what the Q-dynamics look like. From the Girsanov Theorem we have dw t = ϕ t dt + dw Q t and substituting this into the P -dynamics we obtain the Q dynamics as dx t = {µ t + σ t ϕ t } dt + σ t dw Q t Moral: The drift changes but the diffusion is unaffected. Tomas Björk, 2010 33

The Converse of the Girsanov Theorem Let W be a P -Wiener process. Fix a time horizon T. Theorem. Assume that: Q << P on F T, with likelihood process L t = dq dp, on F t 0, t T The filtation is the internal one.i.e. F t = σ {W s ; 0 s t} Then there exists a process ϕ such that { dlt = L t ϕ t dw t L 0 = 1 Tomas Björk, 2010 34

2. The Martingale Approach Ch. 10-12 Tomas Björk, 2010 35

Financial Markets Price Processes: S t = [ S 0 t,..., S N t ] Example: (Black-Scholes, S 0 := B, S 1 := S) ds t = αs t dt + σs t dw t, db t = rb t dt. Portfolio: h t = [ h 0 t,..., h N t ] h i t = number of units of asset i at time t. Value Process: V h t = N h i tst i = h t S t i=0 Tomas Björk, 2010 36

Self Financing Portfolios Definition: (intuitive) A portfolio is self-financing if there is no exogenous infusion or withdrawal of money. The purchase of a new asset must be financed by the sale of an old one. Definition: (mathematical) A portfolio is self-financing if the value process satisfies N dv t = h i tdst i i=0 Major insight: If the price process S is a martingale, and if h is self-financing, then V is a martingale. NB! This simple observation is in fact the basis of the following theory. Tomas Björk, 2010 37

Arbitrage The portfolio u is an arbitrage portfolio if The portfolio strategy is self financing. V 0 = 0. V T 0, P a.s. P (V T > 0) > 0 Main Question: When is the market free of arbitrage? Tomas Björk, 2010 38

First Attempt Proposition: If St 0,, St N are P -martingales, then the market is free of arbitrage. Proof: Assume that V is an arbitrage strategy. Since dv t = N h i tdst, i i=0 V is a P -martingale, so This contradicts V 0 = 0. V 0 = E P [V T ] > 0. True, but useless. Tomas Björk, 2010 39

Example: (Black-Scholes) ds t = αs t dt + σs t dw t, db t = rb t dt. (We would have to assume that α = r = 0) We now try to improve on this result. Tomas Björk, 2010 40

Choose S 0 as numeraire Definition: The normalized price vector Z is given by Z t = S t S 0 t = [ 1, Z 1 t,..., Z N t ] The normalized value process V Z is given by V Z t = N h i tzt. i 0 Idea: The arbitrage and self financing concepts should be independent of the accounting unit. Tomas Björk, 2010 41

Invariance of numeraire Proposition: One can show (see the book) that S-arbitrage Z-arbitrage. S-self-financing Z-self-financing. Insight: If h self-financing then dv Z t = N h i tdzt i 1 Thus, if the normalized price process Z is a P - martingale, then V Z is a martingale. Tomas Björk, 2010 42

Second Attempt Proposition: If Zt 0,, Zt N are P -martingales, then the market is free of arbitrage. True, but still fairly useless. Example: (Black-Scholes) ds t = αs t dt + σs t dw t, db t = rb t dt. dz 1 t = (α r)z 1 t dt + σz 1 t dw t, dz 0 t = 0dt. We would have to assume risk-neutrality, i.e. that α = r. Tomas Björk, 2010 43

Arbitrage Recall that h is an arbitrage if h is self financing V 0 = 0. V T 0, P a.s. P (V T > 0) > 0 Major insight This concept is invariant under an equivalent change of measure! Tomas Björk, 2010 44

Martingale Measures Definition: A probability measure Q is called an equivalent martingale measure (EMM) if and only if it has the following properties. Q and P are equivalent, i.e. Q P The normalized price processes Z i t = Si t S 0 t are Q-martingales., i = 0,..., N Wan now state the main result of arbitrage theory. Tomas Björk, 2010 45

First Fundamental Theorem Theorem: The market is arbitrage free there exists an equivalent martingale measure. iff Note: The martingale measure will depend on your choice of numeraire. The martingale measure (if it exists) is not necessarily unique. Tomas Björk, 2010 46

Comments It is very easy to prove that existence of EMM imples no arbitrage (see below). The other imnplication is technically very hard. For discrete time and finite sample space Ω the hard part follows easily from the separation theorem for convex sets. For discrete time and more general sample space we need the Hahn-Banach Theorem. For continuous time the proof becomes technically very hard, mainly due to topological problems. See the textbook. Tomas Björk, 2010 47

Proof that EMM implies no arbitrage This is basically done above. Assume that there exists an EMM denoted by Q. Assume that P (V T 0) = 1 and P (V T > 0) > 0. Then, since P Q we also have Q(V T 0) = 1 and Q(V T > 0) > 0. Recall: dv Z t = N h i tdzt i Q is a martingale measure 1 V Z is a Q-martingale V 0 = V Z 0 = E Q [ V Z T ] > 0 No arbitrage Tomas Björk, 2010 48

Choice of Numeraire The numeraire price S 0 t can be chosen arbitrarily. The most common choice is however that we choose S 0 as the bank account, i.e. S 0 t = B t where db t = r t B t dt Here r is the (possibly stochastic) short rate and we have B t = e R t 0 r sds Tomas Björk, 2010 49

Example: The Black-Scholes Model ds t = αs t dt + σs t dw t, db t = rb t dt. Look for martingale measure. We set Z = S/B. dz t = Z t (α r)dt + Z t σdw t, Girsanov transformation on [0, T ]: { dlt = L t ϕ t dw t, L 0 = 1. dq = L T dp, on F T Girsanov: dw t = ϕ t dt + dw Q t, where W Q is a Q-Wiener process. Tomas Björk, 2010 50

The Q-dynamics for Z are given by dz t = Z t [α r + σϕ t ] dt + Z t σdw Q t. Unique martingale measure Q, with Girsanov kernel given by ϕ t = r α σ. Q-dynamics of S: ds t = rs t dt + σs t dw Q t. Conclusion: arbitrage. The Black-Scholes model is free of Tomas Björk, 2010 51

Pricing We consider a market B t, S 1 t,..., S N t. Definition: A contingent claim with delivery time T, is a random variable X F T. At t = T the amount X is paid to the holder of the claim. Example: (European Call Option) X = max [S T K, 0] Let X be a contingent T -claim. Problem: How do we find an arbitrage free price process Π t [X] for X? Tomas Björk, 2010 52

Solution The extended market B t, S 1 t,..., S N t, Π t [X] must be arbitrage free, so there must exist a martingale measure Q for (B t, S t, Π t [X]). In particular Π t [X] B t must be a Q-martingale, i.e. Π t [X] B t [ ] = E Q ΠT [X] F t B T Since we obviously (why?) have Π T [X] = X we have proved the main pricing formula. Tomas Björk, 2010 53

Risk Neutral Valuation Theorem: For a T -claim X, the arbitrage free price is given by the formula [ Π t [X] = E Q e R T t ] r s ds X F t Tomas Björk, 2010 54

Risk Neutral Valuation Theorem: For a T -claim X, and the numearire S 0 the arbitrage free price is given by the formula [ ] X Π t [X] = St 0 E 0 ST 0 F t where E 0 denotes expectation w.r.t. the martingale measure Q 0 associated with the numeraire S 0. Tomas Björk, 2010 55

Example: The Black-Scholes Model Q-dynamics: ds t = rs t dt + σs t dw Q t. Simple claim: X = Φ(S T ), Kolmogorov Π t [X] = e r(t t) E Q [Φ(S T ) F t ] Π t [X] = F (t, S t ) where F (t, s) solves the Black-Scholes equation: F t + rs F s + 1 2 σ2 s 2 2 F s 2 rf = 0, F (T, s) = Φ(s). Tomas Björk, 2010 56

Problem Recall the valuation formula [ Π t [X] = E Q e R T t ] r s ds X F t What if there are several different martingale measures Q? This is connected with the completeness of the market. Tomas Björk, 2010 57

Hedging Def: A portfolio is a hedge against X ( replicates X ) if h is self financing V T = X, P a.s. Def: The market is complete if every X can be hedged. Pricing Formula: If h replicates X, then a natural way of pricing X is Π t [X] = V h t When can we hedge? Tomas Björk, 2010 58

Second Fundamental Theorem The second most important result in arbitrage theory is the following. Theorem: The market is complete iff the martingale measure Q is unique. Proof: It is obvious (why?) that if the market is complete, then Q must be unique. The other implication is very hard to prove. It basically relies on duality arguments from functional analysis. Tomas Björk, 2010 59

Black-Scholes Model Q-dynamics ds t = rs t dt + σs t dw Q t, dz t = Z t σdw Q t M t = E Q [ e rt X F t ], Representation theorem for Wiener processes there exists g such that Thus with h 1 t = g t σz t. M t = M(0) + M t = M 0 + t 0 t 0 g s dw Q s. h 1 sdz s, Tomas Björk, 2010 60

Result: X can be replicated using the portfolio defined by h 1 t = g t /σz t, h B t = M t h 1 tz t. Moral: The Black Scholes model is complete. Tomas Björk, 2010 61

Special Case: Simple Claims Assume X is of the form X = Φ(S T ) M t = E Q [ e rt Φ(S T ) F t ], Kolmogorov backward equation M t = f(t, S t ) { f t + rs f s + 1 2 σ2 s 2 2 f = 0, s 2 f(t, s) = e rt Φ(s). Itô f dm t = σs t s dw Q t, so g t = σs t f s, Replicating portfolio h: h B t = f S t f s, h 1 t = B t f s. Interpretation: f(t, S t ) = V Z t. Tomas Björk, 2010 62

Define F (t, s) by so F (t, S t ) = V t. Then F (t, s) = e rt f(t, s) h B t = F (t,s t) S t F s (t,s t ) B t, h 1 t = F s (t, S t) where F solves the Black-Scholes equation { F t + rs F s + 1 2 σ2 s 2 2 F rf = 0, s 2 F (T, s) = Φ(s). Tomas Björk, 2010 63

Main Results The market is arbitrage free There exists a martingale measure Q The market is complete Q is unique. Every X must be priced by the formula [ Π t [X] = E Q e R T t for some choice of Q. ] r s ds X F t In a non-complete market, different choices of Q will produce different prices for X. For a hedgeable claim X, all choices of Q will produce the same price for X: [ Π t [X] = V t = E Q e R T t ] r s ds X F t Tomas Björk, 2010 64

Completeness vs No Arbitrage Rule of Thumb Question: When is a model arbitrage free and/or complete? Answer: Count the number of risky assets, and the number of random sources. R = number of random sources N = number of risky assets Intuition: If N is large, compared to R, you have lots of possibilities of forming clever portfolios. Thus lots of chances of making arbitrage profits. Also many chances of replicating a given claim. Tomas Björk, 2010 65

Rule of thumb Generically, the following hold. The market is arbitrage free if and only if N R The market is complete if and only if N R Example: The Black-Scholes model. ds t = αs t dt + σs t dw t, db t = rb t dt. For B-S we have N = R = 1. Thus the Black-Scholes model is arbitrage free and complete. Tomas Björk, 2010 66

Stochastic Discount Factors Given a model under P. For every EMM Q we define the corresponding Stochastic Discount Factor, or SDF, by D t = e R t 0 rsds L t, where L t = dq dp, on F t There is thus a one-to-one correspondence between EMMs and SDFs. The risk neutral valuation formula for a T -claim X can now be expressed under P instead of under Q. Proposition: With notation as above we have Π t [X] = 1 D t E P [D T X F t ] Proof: Bayes formula. Tomas Björk, 2010 67

Martingale Property of S D Proposition: If S is an arbitrary price process, then the process S t D t is a P -martingale. Proof: Bayes formula. Tomas Björk, 2010 68

3. Change of Numeraire Ch. 26 Tomas Björk, 2010 69

General change of numeraire. Idea: Use a fixed asset price process S t as numeraire. Define the measure Q S by the requirement that Π (t) S t is a Q S -martingale for every arbitrage free price process Π (t). We assume that we know the risk neutral martingale measure Q, with B as the numeraire. Tomas Björk, 2010 70

Constructing Q S Fix a T -claim X. From general theory: Π 0 [X] = E Q [ X B T ] Assume that Q S exists and denote L t = dqs dq, on F t Then Π 0 [X] S 0 = E S [ ] [ ] ΠT [X] = E S XST S T [ ] = E Q X L T S T Thus we have [ ] Π 0 [X] = E Q X S 0 L T S T, Tomas Björk, 2010 71

For all X F T we thus have E Q [ X B T ] [ ] = E Q X S 0 L T S T Natural candidate: L t = dqs t dq t = S t S 0 B t Proposition: Π (t) /B t is a Q-martingale. Π (t) /S t is a Q S -martingale. Tomas Björk, 2010 72

Proof. E S [ Π (t) S t ] F s = E Q [ L t Π(t) S t F s ] L s = E Q [ Π(t) B t S 0 F s ] L s = Π (s) B(s)S 0 L s = Π (s) S(s). Tomas Björk, 2010 73

Result Π t [X] = S t E S [ X S t F t ] We can observe S t directly on the market. Example: X = S t Y Π t [X] = S t E S [Y F t ] Tomas Björk, 2010 74

Several underlying X = Φ [S 0 (T ), S 1 (T )] Assume Φ is linearly homogeous. Transform to Q 0. Π t [X] = S 0 (t)e 0 [ Φ [S0 (T ), S 1 (T )] S 0 (T ) = S 0 (t)e 0 [ϕ (Z T ) F t ] ] F t ϕ (z) = Φ [1, z], Z t = S 1(t) S 0 (t) Tomas Björk, 2010 75

Exchange option X = max [S 1 (T ) S 0 (T ), 0] Π t [X] = S 0 (t)e 0 [max [Z(T ) 1, 0] F t ] European Call on Z with strike price K. Zero interest rate. Piece of cake! Tomas Björk, 2010 76

Identifying the Girsanov Transformation Assume Q-dynamics of S known as ds t = r t S t dt + S t v t dw t L t = S t S 0 B t From this we immediately have and we can summarize. dl t = L t v t dw t. Theorem:The Girsanov kernel is given by the numeraire volatility v t, i.e. dl t = L t v t dw t. Tomas Björk, 2010 77