Vector Autoregression Analysis of Exchange Rate Movement

Similar documents
Government Tax Revenue, Expenditure, and Debt in Sri Lanka : A Vector Autoregressive Model Analysis

MONEY, PRICES AND THE EXCHANGE RATE: EVIDENCE FROM FOUR OECD COUNTRIES

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus)

CAN MONEY SUPPLY PREDICT STOCK PRICES?

COINTEGRATION AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: AN APPLICATION TO THE CANADIAN TREASURY BILL MARKET. Soo-Bin Park* Carleton University, Ottawa, Canada K1S 5B6

An Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between Macroeconomic Variables and Stock Prices in Bangladesh

A study on the long-run benefits of diversification in the stock markets of Greece, the UK and the US

Market Integration, Price Discovery, and Volatility in Agricultural Commodity Futures P.Ramasundaram* and Sendhil R**

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

Weak Policy in an Open Economy: The US with a Floating Exchange Rate, Henry Thompson

Sectoral Analysis of the Demand for Real Money Balances in Pakistan

MONEY AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: SOME INTERNATIONAL EVIDENCE. Abstract

Cointegration and Price Discovery between Equity and Mortgage REITs

Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note*

Foreign direct investment and profit outflows: a causality analysis for the Brazilian economy. Abstract

Exchange Rate Market Efficiency: Across and Within Countries

EMPIRICAL STUDY ON RELATIONS BETWEEN MACROECONOMIC VARIABLES AND THE KOREAN STOCK PRICES: AN APPLICATION OF A VECTOR ERROR CORRECTION MODEL

Personal income, stock market, and investor psychology

Cointegration Tests and the Long-Run Purchasing Power Parity: Examination of Six Currencies in Asia

The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock

Introductory Econometrics for Finance

Foreign Capital inflows and Domestic Saving in Pakistan: Cointegration techniques and Error Correction Modeling

The Demand for Money in Mexico i

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

PRIVATE AND GOVERNMENT INVESTMENT: A STUDY OF THREE OECD COUNTRIES. MEHDI S. MONADJEMI AND HYEONSEUNG HUH* University of New South Wales

Spending for Growth: An Empirical Evidence of Thailand

AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF THE PUBLIC DEBT RELEVANCE TO THE ECONOMIC GROWTH OF THE USA

List of tables List of boxes List of screenshots Preface to the third edition Acknowledgements

The Current Account and Real Exchange Rate Dynamics in African Countries. September 2012

Assessing the Dynamic Relationship Between Small and Large Cap Stock Prices

CURRENT ACCOUNT DEFICIT AND FISCAL DEFICIT A CASE STUDY OF INDIA

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

A joint Initiative of Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität and Ifo Institute for Economic Research

Validity of the Monetary Model of the Exchange Rate: Empirical Evidence from Sri Lanka 1. Sujeetha Jegajeevan. Abstract

Lecture 3, Part 1 (Bubbles, Portfolio Balance Models)

Can P* Be a Basis for Core Inflation in the Philippines?

Zhenyu Wu 1 & Maoguo Wu 1

Why the saving rate has been falling in Japan

The Demand for Money in China: Evidence from Half a Century

Investigating Causal Relationship between Indian and American Stock Markets , Tamilnadu, India

THE EFFECTIVENESS OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANNEL OF MONETARY POLICY TRANSMISSION MECHANISM IN SRI LANKA

IMPACT OF MONETARY POLICY AND BALANCE OF PAYMENT ON PRICE STABILIZATION IN NIGERIA

The relationship amongst public debt and economic growth in developing country case of Tunisia

Does the Unemployment Invariance Hypothesis Hold for Canada?

ESTIMATING MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION OF BANGLADESH

Impact of interest rate differentials on Net foreign institutional investment (FIIs) in India

Impact of Fed s Credit Easing on the Value of U.S. Dollar

Volume 29, Issue 2. Measuring the external risk in the United Kingdom. Estela Sáenz University of Zaragoza

INTERDEPENDENCE OF THE BANKING SECTOR AND THE REAL SECTOR: EVIDENCE FROM OECD COUNTRIES

RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN CRUDE PRICE AND INDONESIA STOCK MARKET

THE IMPACT OF IMPORT ON INFLATION IN NAMIBIA

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE EFFECT OF OIL INCOME ON REAL EXCHANGE RATE IN IRANIAN ECONOMY. Adibeh Savari. Hassan Farazmand.

A Study of Inflation Dynamics in India: A Cointegrated Autoregressive Approach

ON THE NEXUS BETWEEN SERVICES EXPORT AND SERVICE SECTOR GROWTH IN INDIAN CONTEXT

A Study on the Relationship between Monetary Policy Variables and Stock Market

Multivariate Causal Estimates of Dividend Yields, Price Earning Ratio and Expected Stock Returns: Experience from Malaysia

Analysis of monetary policy variables with stock returns using var frame work

Asian Economic and Financial Review EMPIRICAL TESTING OF EXCHANGE RATE AND INTEREST RATE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS IN CHINA

THE EFFECTS OF BUDGET DEFICIT ON NATIONAL SAVING IN MALAYSIA 1. Fatimah Wati Ibrahim Asmawi Hashim ABSTRACT

INFORMATION EFFICIENCY HYPOTHESIS THE FINANCIAL VOLATILITY IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC CASE

DOES GOVERNMENT SPENDING GROWTH EXCEED ECONOMIC GROWTH IN SAUDI ARABIA?

Uncertainty and the Transmission of Fiscal Policy

A DISAGGREGATED ANALYSIS OF GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURES AND PRIVATE INVESTMENT IN TURKEY. Erdal Karagöl

Determinants of Cyclical Aggregate Dividend Behavior

Inflation and Stock Market Returns in US: An Empirical Study

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

The Random Walk Hypothesis in Emerging Stock Market-Evidence from Nonlinear Fourier Unit Root Test

Bruno Eeckels, Alpine Center, Athens, Greece George Filis, University of Winchester, UK

Integration of Foreign Exchange Markets: A Short Term Dynamics Analysis

Forecasting Nominal Exchange Rate of Indian Rupee vs. US Dollar

Intraday arbitrage opportunities of basis trading in current futures markets: an application of. the threshold autoregressive model.

Analysis of the Relation between Treasury Stock and Common Shares Outstanding

Examining Capital Market Integration in Korea and Japan Using a Threshold Cointegration Model

EFFECT OF EXCHANGE RATE VOLATILITY ON MACROECONOMIC PERFORMANCE IN NIGERIA

Conditional Heteroscedasticity and Testing of the Granger Causality: Case of Slovakia. Michaela Chocholatá

Thi-Thanh Phan, Int. Eco. Res, 2016, v7i6, 39 48

IMPACT OF MACROECONOMIC VARIABLE ON STOCK MARKET RETURN AND ITS VOLATILITY

Conflict of Exchange Rates

The Effects of Public Debt on Economic Growth and Gross Investment in India: An Empirical Evidence

VARIABILITY OF THE INFLATION RATE AND THE FORWARD PREMIUM IN A MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION: THE CASE OF THE GERMAN HYPERINFLATION

Quality Decision Control, Marketing Applied Strategic Agility and Energy Projects Performance

The Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate in a Commodity Exporting Country: Algeria s Experience

THE REACTION OF THE WIG STOCK MARKET INDEX TO CHANGES IN THE INTEREST RATES ON BANK DEPOSITS

The Credit Cycle and the Business Cycle in the Economy of Turkey

3. HOUSING PRICES AND MORTGAGE CREDIT IN LUXEMBOURG

Quarterly Journal of Econometrics Research

The Agricultural Sector in the Macroeconomic Environment: An Empirical Approach for EU.

Impact of Inflation on Stock Exchange Market Returns

Dividend, investment and the direction of causality

Impact of Selected Macroeconomic Indicators on Inflation in Kenya

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility

TESTING WAGNER S LAW FOR PAKISTAN:

The Effects of Oil Shocks on Turkish Macroeconomic Aggregates

A SEARCH FOR A STABLE LONG RUN MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION FOR THE US

Currency Substitution, Capital Mobility and Functional Forms of Money Demand in Pakistan

1 There are subtle differences between lapse and surrender. Policyholders could actively terminate

Most recent studies of long-term interest rates have emphasized term

The Causal Relationship between Government Expenditure & Tax Revenue in Barbados. Authors:Tracy Maynard & Kester Guy

The Impact of Oil Price Volatility on the Real Exchange Rate in Nigeria: An Error Correction Model

THE CREDIT CYCLE and the BUSINESS CYCLE in the ECONOMY of TURKEY

Transcription:

Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU Economic Research Institute Study Papers Economics and Finance 1993 Vector Autoregression Analysis of Exchange Rate Movement Rajiv Mallick Utah State University Basudeb Biswas Utah State University Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.usu.edu/eri Recommended Citation Mallick, Rajiv and Biswas, Basudeb, "Vector Autoregression Analysis of Exchange Rate Movement" (1993). Economic Research Institute Study Papers. Paper 27. https://digitalcommons.usu.edu/eri/27 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Economics and Finance at DigitalCommons@USU. It has been accepted for inclusion in Economic Research Institute Study Papers by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@USU. For more information, please contact dylan.burns@usu.edu.

June 1993 ERI Study Paper #93-02 VECTOR AUTOREGRESSION ANALYSIS OF EXCHANGE RATE MOVEMENT By Rajiv Mallick Basudeb Biswas

Paper to be presented at the 68th Annual Western Economic Association International Conference June 20 - June 24, 1993, Lake Tahoe, Nevada Vector Autoregression Analysis of Exchange Rate Movement Rajiv Mallick Utah State University & Basudeb Biswas Utah State University Session 52, Tuesday, June 22, 1993 8:15-10:00 a.m., Exchange Rate I

1 I Introduction Since 1973 when major nations adopted the floating exchange rate system there have been greater fluctuations in the exchange rate. Figures 1 and 2 show that both the real and the nominal exchange rates have moved together and both have fluctuated considerably in the post Bretton Woods era. The major reason for the greater volatility of the exchange rate is the move towards flexible exchange rates in the world economy. This volatility is regarded as a disequilibrium phenomenon. By disequilibrium it is meant that the exchange rate deviates in the short run from the long run equilibrium level. This deviation is regarded as a case of misalignment, and produces excess social welfare cost. The policy implication is that the government should intervene in the foreign exchange market to manage the floating rate. Left to market forces the exchange rate is determined by the demand and supply of foreign exchange. The demand for foreign currency stems from two sources, the desire to buy foreign goods and the desire to buy securities denominated in foreign currency. The supply of foreign currency comes from the foreigners' desire to buy securities denominated in domestic currency. Demand for goods and services remain stable in the short run since forces affecting the goods market change slowly. The highly volatile movements of the exchange rate can be attributed to changes in the assets markets. In this paper we analyze the determinants of the dollar-deutsche mark exchange rate within the framework of assets markets. This paper is organized as follows. Section II briefly discusses the Dornbusch model (1976) and identifies the key variables determining the exchange rate. These macrovariables

Figures 1 & 2 2 0.7~----------------------------------------, 0.6 0.5 0.4-0.3 0.2~~~~~~~~~~~~~mmmm~~~~~~~ 60 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 Exchange Rate 0.70 -r---------------------_---, 0.65 0.60 0.55 0.50 0.45 0.4 0 0.35 Real Exchange Rate 84-86 88 90

3 are the dollar-deutsche mark exchange rate, the real money supply, and the real output. The forward exchange rate is another macrovariable which is used as a proxy for the expected change in the exchange rate. A vector autoregression model is used to find the interrelationships among these variables. Section m gives an outline of an econometric model showing the relationship among the exchange rate, the real money supply, the real income, and the forward rate. Empirical results are presented in section IV, and section V gives the concluding remarks. II The Dornbusch Model The building blocks of the Dornbusch model are (i) interest parity condition, (ii) perfect capital mobility, (iii) the expectation about change in the exchange rate, (iv) a moneymarket equilibrium condition, and (v) a price-level adjustment equation. Expected return on Deutsche Mark deposits The expected return on deutsche mark (DM) deposits measured in the US dollar is approximately equal to the German interest rate and the expected rate of depreciation of the dollar against the DM. Let RDM denote the interest rate on DM deposits, ES/DM denote the spot exchange rate i.e., the price of DM in terms of dollars and E$/DM' the expected $/DM exchange rate. Thus the expected return on DM deposits is RDM + (&jdm - ES/DM) /ES/DM (1) The above expression measures the expected rate of return on a DM deposit in terms of the

4 DM interest rate and the expected rate of dollar depreciation against the DM. Under the assumption that the interest parity condition always holds, a forward exchange rate equals the expected exchange rate. The expected rate of return of a DM deposit measured in the US dollar should be compared with the US interest rate. This comparison is mathematically expressed as the following: Rs - [RDM + (ES/DM- ES/DM)/Es/DM] (2) When the expression in (2) is positive, dollar deposits are preferred to DM deposits, and vice-versa. The foreign exchange market attains equilibrium when the domestic interest is equal to the expected dollar return on deposits denominated in DM. This condition is called the interest parity condition. The equilibrium condition is written as: Rs = RDM + (ES/DM - ES/DM) /ES/DM (3) At equilibrium, deposit holders remain indifferent at the margin to holding deposits in different currencies. Therefore it can be said that the interest parity condition is a function of the US interest rate, the D M interest rate, and the forward exchange rate. When the interest parity condition holds, the foreign exchange market is in equilibrium. Figure 3 shows the equilibrium exchange rate at which Rs = RDM + (ES/DM - ES/DM) /ES/DM. If it is expected that the exchange rate is going to increase, the schedule showing the return on DM deposits measured in the US dollar shifts to the right for the given US interest rate, and the current spot rate increases. Figure 3 shows the comparative static result of a change in expectation of the current exchange rate. Since we take the forward exchange rate as a proxy for the expected change in the exchange rate we can postulate that an increase in the forward rate will raise the exchange rate. This hypothesis is tested.

5 Figure 3 Exchange Rate. ($IDM) Return on Dollar deposits 3 Return on DM ~--------~----~~~ deposits measured in the US dollar Rate of Return (in! Dollar)

6 Interest Rate Although the interest rate is determined in the money market, the exchange rate movements can be attributed to changes in the domestic and foreign interest rates. Given that the supply of money is exogenous, the interest rate is determined when the money market is in equilibrium. An increase in the money supply will lower the interest rate. A lower interest rate in the home country results in the net outflow of capital and the domestic currency will depreciate. Similarly an increase in the money supply in the foreign country will result in a lower foreign interest rate. There will be a net inflow of foreign capital and the exchange rate decreases. It is assumed that under the interest parity condition there is no excess demand for foreign currencies. This analysis indicates that the exchange rate and the real domestic money supply are positively related. As the real money supply increases the interest rate declines, which results in a depreciation of the domestic currency, and an increase in the exchange rate. Interaction of Real Money Supply and Real GNP, and Price Level Money market equilibrium is attained when the money supply equals the aggregate money demand. Thus the money supply and the money demand determine the interest rate, given that the output and the price level remain constant in the short run. An increase in the money supply will result in lower interest rate, in the short full, because of sluggish response of prices to changes in other economic variables. Similarly a higher money

7 demand will raise the interest rate, and domestic currency would appreciate. We now trace the consequence of changes in the price-level on the interest rate, and the exchange rate. Assuming that the price level and the output remain fixed in the short run, the money market equilibrium is expressed as: (4) where M IP S is the real money supply, R is the interest rate, and Y is the output. In the short run as the prices of goods and services do not react to increase in the money supply, the interest rate declines more than the long-run level. This decline in the interest rate leads changes in the expected exchange rate causing "overshooting" of the exchange rate in the short run (Dornbusch, 1976). As prices start to respond to the increased money supply, the real money supply is reduced and the interest rate as well as the exchange rate reach the long-run equilibrium. Thus an increase in the price level results in a higher interest rate. An increase in the interest rate is followed by a decrease in the exchange rate. The analysis can be extended to determine the effect of a change in the domestic real GNP on the e~change rate. An increase in the real GNP will increase the aggregate money demand, and the interest rate will increase. When the interest rate increases, the exchange rate decreases, i.e, pay less in domestic currency per unit of foreign currency. Thus an increase in real domestic income has a negative effect on the exchange rate. III Econometric Model

Econometric Modelling of the relationship among the exchange rate, the real money supply, the real output, and the forward rate 8 In this section we briefly explain the model and the methodology used in this paper. The model is based on the interest parity theory. The previous section explains how the real money supplies, and real incomes of countries, and the forward exchange rate explain the long run behavior of the $/DM exchange rate. Using the US-Germany quarterly data for the period 1960 to 1991, we empirically examine whether there is any long-run economic relationship among these variables. This is done by testing for cointegration among these variables. Before testing for cointegration we need to test for stationarity and determine the order of integration of the time series. To test for stationarity (unit root) the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) tests were conducted on the time series. The following regression is performed to determine whether the time series is stationary or not (Dickey and Fuller 1979). (Yt-~-l) - (X+Pl~-1+P2(Yt-l-~-2)+ (5) P3(~-3-Y,-2) + P,(Y,-4-Y,-J+ Pl+e t In case of unit root 13 1 will not be significantly different from zero and we accept the null hypothesis that the time series is not stationary. The next step would be to determine the order of integration. To determine the order of integration the stationarity of Y t - 1 -Y t - 2 is checked. If it is found to be stationary, the conclusion is made that Y t is integrated of order

9 1 (Dickey and Fuller, 1979). Johansen's maximum likelihood model is used to test for cointegration (Dickey, Jansen, Thornton, 1991). This method is preferred to the other methods of testing cointegration because it uses the maximum likelihood estimation procedure which does not require a priori, the variable to be treated as the dependent one in estimating the cointegrating vector. Johansen's method has two test statistics for the number of cointegrating vectors. These are the trace statistic and maximum eigenvalue statistic. The null hypothesis for the trace test is that the number of cointegrating vectors is less than or equal to r, where r is 0, 1, 2, 3, 4, 5 or 6. In the maximum eigenvalue test the null hypothesis of r = 0, r~ 1, r~2, r~3, and r~5 is tested against the alternative hypothesis of r = 1, 2, 3, 4, 5 or 6 (Dickey, Jansen and Thornton 1991). Johansen's maximum likelihood test for cointegration determines whether the lagged values of changes in a system of variables help explain the changes in the dependent variable. The presence of cointegrating vector indicates a long run relationship among the variables. Error correction terms can be computed once the presence of the cointegrating vectors is established. In presence of cointegrating vector an error correction term will be included in the vector autoregression (V AR) model. The V AR is set up to explain the short run dynamics of the system. IV Data and Empirical Results For this paper data on the US $/DM exchange rate, the forward exchange rate, the real

money supply and the real income for Germany and the US were obtained from various issues of International Financial Statistics of the International Monetary Fund. The forward exchange rate is taken as a proxy for the expected exchange rate (E e S / DM ) in equation (1). The data sets were initially tested for stationarity ( or unit root). The ADF tests were performed on all time series. The null hypothesis is that the time series has unit root. A higher absolute value of the Dickey-Fuller t-statistic compare to that of the MacKinnon values at 5% level of significance leads to rejection of the null hypothesis, i.e., data set is stationary. Table 1 presents the results of Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test for the time series in levels and their first difference. 10 Table 1 Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test for Unit Root with two lags Variables D-F! Exchange Rate -2.126 Forward Rate -1.813 Real US GNP -3.041 Real German GNP -1.409 Real German Money 0.022 Real US Money -1.549 aexchange Rate aforward Rate areal German GNP areal US GNP areal German Money areal US Money - 5.233- - 5.964- - 5.593- - 9.529- -11.005- -12.007-1 Dickey-Fuller t-statistics MacKinnon Critical Values (5%) = -3.446 Statistically significant at the 5 percent level of significance. Table 1 shows the results of the ADF test for unit root for all variables. A higher absolute

11 value of MacKinnon critical value than the absolute value of the Dickey-Fuller t-statistics at the 5% level of significance would reject the null hypothesis of nonstationarity and accept the alternative hypothesis that the time series is stationary. Table 1 indicates that all the variables are nonstationary at their levels and are integrated of order one. Exchange Rate and Forward Rate We find that both the exchange rate and the forward exchange rate are integrated of order one. Our theoretical analysis suggests that an increase in the forward rate will cause an increase in the spot rate. We run a regression of the exchange rate on the forward rate. The variables are used in their first differences. (6) where aet is the first difference of the exchange rate, aft is the first difference of the forward rate, and aft_ 1 is the lagged values of the first difference of the forward rate. Results of this regression is reported in table 2. Table 2 Dependent Variable is ae t Variable C aft a F t _ 1 Coefficient -5.359E-05 0.4527438-0.5280553- R2 = 0.82, F-stat = 273.37 Significant at 5 %

Results indicate that there is a positive association between the forward rate and the exchange rate. This result is also verified using the cointegration test. 12 Test for Cointegration It was determined that the exchange rate, the forward exchange rate, the real money supply of the US and Germany, the real income of the US and Germany are integrated of order one. To determine a long run relationship among them, we do the Johansen Maximum Likelihood test for cointegration. The results of the test are presented in table 3. Table 3 Johansen Maximum Likelihood Method Cointegration LR Test Based on the Maximal Eigenvalue of the Stochastic Matrix Null Alternative Statistic r=o.r=1 90.4113 r~1 r=2 60.7465 r~2 r=3 17.1410 r~3 r=4 7.9272 r~4 r=5 4.8655 r~5 r=6 3.6238 -------------------~-------------------------------------------- Statistically significant at the 5 percent level of significance. According to the above results there are two co integrating vectors.

13 Table 4 Johansen Maximum Likelihood Method Cointegration LR Test Based on Trace of the Stochastic Matrix Null Alternative Statistic r=o r~l 184.7155 r~l r~2 94.3042 r~2 r~3 33.5576 r~3 r~4 16.4166 r~4 r~5 8.4894 r~5 r~6 3.6238 Statistically significant at the 5 percent level of significance. According to the above results there are two co integrating vectors. The cointegrating vectors are reported in Table 6 with the normalized values in brackets. Table 5 tabulates the ADF test results of the residuals of the co integrating vectors. Table 5 Augmented Dickey-Fuller Tests for Unit Root for the residuals of Johansen Maximum Likelihood Method with four lags Residual RES1 RES2 Statistic -4.6256-3.1431 J ----------------------------------------------------------------- MacKinnon Critical Values (5%) = -3.4478 Statistically significant at the 5 percent level of significance.

14 Table 6 Estimated Cointegrated Vectors in Johansen Estimation. Normalized values are in brackets. Maximum lag in V AR = 4, chosen r = 2 E RUSMS RGMS RGGNP RUSGNP F Vector 1 24.7916-0.04071-0.00371-0.01457 0.01632-25.1279 (1.0000) ( 0.0016) ( 0.1459E-3) ( 0.5876E-3) ( -0.6584E-3) ( 1.0136) Note: E, RUSMS, RGMS, RGGNP, RUSGNP, and F denote the nominal exchange rate, the real US money supply, the real German money supply, the real German GNP, the real US GNP and the forward exchange rate respectively. Augmented Dickey Fuller test on the residuals indicate that there is only one cointegrating vector with stationary residuals. Therefore it is concluded that there is one cointegrating vector. That is, there exists a long run relationship among real money supplies and real incomes of the US and Germany, the exchange rate and the forward rate. A test for cointegration is a pretest to avoid "spurious regression". All variables are assumed to be jointly endogenous. The elements in the cointegration vector should not be interpreted in the same manner as the structural coefficients of an equation in the system of simultaneous equations. However, the signs of coefficients of the exchange rate and the forward rate are consistent with the hypothesized direction. The short run dynamics of the model can be explained using a vector error correction model. Vector Error Correction Model In our investigation, we find that there is one cointegrating vector with stationary residuals.

15 This result indicates that one linear combination of the variables exists which can explain the long run relationship among them. According to the Granger representation theorem, the presence of a cointegrating vector can be helpful in explaining the short-run dynamics. To explain the short run dynamics the vector error correction model (VECM) is developed. The VECM is a system of equations in which endogenous variables are a linear function of its past values, past values of other endogenous variables in the system, exogenous variables whose lagged values are considered as endogenous variables, and constant terms and the error correction term. This model is used to analyze the dynamic effects of random disturbances. The following series of regressions are performed and the results are analyzed. aet - c 1 + P lz,-l + iagged(ae"aft,arggnp t, arusgnpt,argmst,arusmst)+ lt (7) aft - c 2 + PzZ,-l +iagged(ae"aft,arggnpt, arusgnp t,argms t,arusms t )+ 2t (8) arggnpt - C3+P3Z,-1 +iagged(a Et,a F"aRGGNP t, arusgnp t,argms t,arusms t )+ 3t (9)

16 arusgnp t - C"+P,,Z,-l +lagged(aet,af"arggnp" arusgnpt,argmst,arusms t )+ ", (10) argms t - cs + PSZ,-l +lagged(aet,af "arggnp t, arusgnpt,argmst,arusmst)+ St (11) arusms t - C 6 +P6Z,-1 +lagged(a Et,a F"aRGGNP t, arusgnp t,ilrgms t,arusms t )+ 6t (12) where Zt_1 is the error correction term obtained from the co integration test, PI' P2' P3' P4' P 5 and p 6 are the coefficients of the error correction term, and at least one of them should be nonzero, IJ' 2t' 3V 4t' St and 6t are white noise, and ae, ilf, arggnp, arusgnp, argms, and arusms are the first differences of the exchange rate, the forward rate, the real income of Germany, the real income of the US, the real money supply of Germany, and the real money supply of the US respectively. The regression results are reported in appendix l. In two of the VECM regressions (equations 7 and 12) the coefficients of the error correction terms are significant. The lagged values of the first difference of the exchange

17 rate, the forward exchange rate, the real money supply of Germany, and the real money supply of the US are found significant in some of the VECM regression. Though VECM has been used very often with a system of equations for forecasting purposes, its use as a forecasting tool for economic variables is controversial. The empirical results obtained from VECMs are not stable or robust. This indicates that VECM statistics may be sensitive to modifications to VECM's random and non-random parts (Todd, 1990). It would be desirable to check for stability, though it is not easy to do so using current techniques. To interpret the coefficients of the VECM model, a common practice is to analyze impulse response functions and variance decompositions of the system. The impulse response function measures the response of shocks on endogenous variable over time in itself or in another variable, and how they filter through the model to affect other variables. In interpreting the impulse response function the common practice is to attribute all the effects of such common components of shocks to the dependent variable of the first equation in the model. The results of impulse response function indicate that there is insignificant effect of one standard deviation in the first differences of each variables on the VECM. These results indicate that there should be less volatility in the exchange rate, which is contrary to what is generally observed. The impulse response function also indicates that the growth in the exchange rate is positive initially and becomes negative in the fourth quarter in response to a one standard deviation positive shock in the growth in the real money supply of the US (see table 7, figure 4). The negative effect persists for over a long period of time.

18 Table 7 Response to one Standard Deviation Shock of ~ R USMS Period de df drgms drusms ~RGGNP ~RUSGNP 1 0.000000 0.000000 0.000000 0.099447 0.045293 0.020883 2 0.001013 0.002153-0.010753-0.016729-0.009680 0.217511 3 0.001025 0.003612 0.003476 0.012859-0.008457-0.088643 4-0.000117 0.002362 0.019337 0.043101-0.012048-0.154922 5-0.001206 0.001141 0.020653 0.145361 0.013348 0.043659 6-0.002037 0.001794-0.002772 0.052383-0.017856 0.205962 7-0.001698 0.002753 0.014188 0.091862-0.001303 0.115830 8-0.001164 0.004315 0.029420 0.120889 0.017306 0.125579 9 -O.ooom 0.005980 0.041039 0.231234 0.029530 0.199715:. 10-0.001667 0.006692 0.017779 0.179455-0.004449 0.254856 11-0.002166 0.007956 0.037875 0.250012 0.014171 0.224633 12-0.002315 0.011149 0.057237 0.307829 0.034836 0.326869 ------------------------.------------------.-----.----------.------------------.-----------------------.------------------------------------- where E is the exchange rate, F is the forward rate, RGGNP is the real-income of Germany, RUSGN:P is the real income of the US, RGMS is the real money supply of Germany, and RUSMS is the real money supply of the US. Figure 4 Response to one SD shock in RUSMS 0.0015,..--------------------------, 0.001 0.0005 o~~----~-------------~ -0.0005-0.001-0.0015-0.002 1 :a l 4 5 ~? ~ 10 11 12 P4J:iod ODie. Itxchang4 tt..t.

19 This finding can be interpreted as the short run "overshooting" phenomenon of the exchange rate (Dornbusch, 1976). The variance decomposition results should be interpreted with some caution. The results may vary with changes in the order of the time series. Most of the variables except the forward exchange rate explain most of their own variances. In most of the cases the innovation is captured by the exchange rate and the forward rate in a span of two to four quarters. Other variables have limited role in explaining innovations. V Conclusion This paper examines the relationship among the exchange rate, the forward rate, the real incomes and the real money supplies of Germany and the US. The forward exchange rate is used as a proxy for the expected exchange rate. Johansen's maximum likelihood method is used to estimate the cointegrating vector, and explain the long run relation among these variables. We find that the exchange rate and the forward rate move very closely. The forward rate is found to be a good indicator of the expected exchange rate. Empirical results of the analysis indicate that the forward rate explains significantly the movements in the exchange rate. The cointegration test indicates that there exists a long run relationship among the variables. The cointegration test also indicates that there is an inverse relation between the exchange rate and the domestic real income. Results of the vector error correction model show that the shocks in the real US money supply have an "overshooting" effect on the exchange rate. Variance decomposition analysis of the model indicates that

20 most of the innovation is captured by the exchange rate and the forward rate. The findings of the analysis are that the changes in the expectation regarding the exchange rate is well captured by the forward rate. The exchange rate and the forward rate move very closely. The notion of exchange rate "overshooting" is also found to be relevant in this case. In foreign exchange markets innovations are well captured by changes in the exchange rate and the forward rate.

21 References Caves, Richard E., Jeffrey A Frankel and Ronald W. Jones. "World Trade and Payments - An Introduction" Sixth Edition, Harper Collins College Publishers. Dickey, David A, Dennis W. Jansen and Daniel L. Thornton. "A Primer On Cointegration with an Application to Money and Income" Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Marchi April 1991, 58-78. Dickey, D. and Wayne A Fuller, "A Theory of the Estimators of Time Series Regression with a Unit Root" Journal of the American Statistical Association, 1979, 427-431. Dornbusch, Rudiger. "Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics." Journal of Political Economy, December 1976, 1161-76. Driskill, Robert A "Exchange-Rate Dynamics: An Empirical Investigation" Journal of Political Economy, 1981, vol. 89, no 21, 357-371. Engle, Robert F., and C. W. J. Granger, "Cointegration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation and Testing," Econometrica, 1987, 55.2, 251-276., and Byung Sam Yoo, "Forecasting and Testing in Co-integrated System," ----- Journal of Econometrics, May 1987, 251-276. Fleming, J. M., "Domestic Financial Policies Under Fixed and Floating Exchange Rates," International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, Nov. 1962, 9, 369-79. Frankel, Jeffrey A. "On the Mark: A Theory of Floating Exchange Rates Based on Real Interest Differentials." The American Economic Review, September 1979, 610-622. Gordon, Robert J., "Macroeconomics," Sixth Edition, Uttle, Brown and Company. International Financial Statistics, International Monetary Fund, Washington D.C., various issues. Johansen, S. "Statistical Analysis of Cointegration Vectors," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 1988, Vol. 12, 231-254. Krugman, Paul R., and Maurice Obstfeld. International Economics - Theory and Policy. Harper Collins Publishers, 1991. Kyereme, S. S. "Exchange Rate, Price, and Output Inter-relationships in Ghana: Evidence from Vector Autoregressions." Applied Economics, December 1991, 1801-1810.

Maddala, G. S., "Introduction to Econometrics," Second Edition, Macmillan Publishing Company. Mundell, Robert, "The International Disequilibrium System," Kyklos 14 (1961), 154-227. Hall, Robert E., Jack Johnston, David M. Lilien., "Micro TSP User's Manual," Quantitative Micro Software Version Z O. Todd, Richard M. "Vector Autoregressions, Evidence on Monetarism: Another Look at the Robustness Debate" Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 1990, 14, 19-37. 22

Appendix 1 Vector Error Correction Model - Parameters Estimates -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- Explanatory Dependent Dependent Dependent Dependent Dependent Dependent variable variable variable variable variable variable variable ~E ~F ~RGMS ~RUSMS ~RGGNP ~RUSGNP ~E.1 0.3412-0.142-2.142-12.38* 5.6762 44.501 ~E.2 0.6165 0.1502-1.602-9530 1.3815 1.1157 ~E.3 0.3045 0.1109-1.791-6.663 1.5551-9.473 ~E-4-0.106-0.0513-1.303-1.644 0.0554-10.87 ~F.1-0.272 0.3798 4.1570 15.161-7.135-49.66 ~F. 2-0.592-0.240 2.5311 10.580-3.765-23.05 ~F.3-0.408 0.0298 2.0732 8.9699-1.367-6.416 ~F-4-0.079 0.0749 2.6163* 3.5404* -1.557 7.9363 ~RGMS.l 0.0160 0.0025-0.099 0.1155 0.7169 0.3674 ~RGMS.2-0.010-0.072-0.056-0.051 0.3617-0.019 ~RGMS.3-0.019-0.058* -0.314-0.215 0.4615 2.1232 ~RGMS-4 0.0195 0.0467 03992 0.0937 0.3897 0.4114 ~RUSMS'l 0.0067 0.0108-0.126* -0.161-0.0387 1.9187 ~RUSMS.2 0.0130 0.0260-0.053-0.038 0.0925 1.5366* ~RUSMS.3 0.0116 0.0128 0.0487-0.119 0.1383 0.7669 ~RUSMS-4 0.0088-0.0013 0.0949 0.6900* 0.2689 1.6445* ~RGGNP'l 0.0067 0.0224 0.0283-0.022-0.134 0.8124 ~RGGNP.2 0.0039 0.0120-0.032-0.038-0.152-0.125 ~RGGNP.3 0.0065 0.0071 0.0245 0.0561 0.0646 0.0370 ~RGGNP-4 0.0058 0.0036-0.0924-0.040 0.2344-0.521 ~RUSGNP'l 0.0007 0.0013 0.0049-0.012 0.0177-0.5.45* ~RUSGNP.2-0.0004-0.001-0.007-0.008 0.0027-0.405 ~RUSGNP.3-0.0003 0.0011-0.011-0.009 0.0059-0.252 ~RUSGNP-4 0.0003 0.0021 0.0017-0.004 0.0013-0.081 C -0.00606-0.0005 0.0431 0.0766 0.0438 0.1765 2,.1-1.23* 0.4167 4.480 14.94-9.56-54.83 R2 0.69 0.35 0.74 0.87 0.28 0.45 f-stat 8.494 2.04 10.49 25.15 1.489 3.054 -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- * Statistically significant at 5% where E is the exchange rate, F is the forward rate, RGGNP is the real income of Germany, RUSGNP is the real income of the US, RGMS is the real money supply of Germany, and RUSMS is the real money supply of the US.