The Solow Growth Model

Similar documents
5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

ECON 3560/5040 Week 3

Chapter 7. Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth (The Very Long Run) CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I. slide 0

CHAPTER SEVEN - Eight. Economic Growth

The Solow Growth Model. Martin Ellison, Hilary Term 2017

What we ve learned so far. The Solow Growth Model. Our objectives today 2/11/2009 ECON 206 MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS. Chapter 5 (2 of 2)

Chapter 8 Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth

EC 205 Macroeconomics I

Road Map to this Lecture

IN THIS LECTURE, YOU WILL LEARN:

MACROECONOMICS. Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth MANKIW. In this chapter, you will learn. Why growth matters

Economic Growth: Extensions

macro macroeconomics Economic Growth I Economic Growth I I (chapter 7) N. Gregory Mankiw

ECONOMIC GROWTH 1. THE ACCUMULATION OF CAPITAL

Shall we play a game? Solow growth model Steady state Break-even investment Rule of 70 Depreciation Dilution

ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section

Part 1: Short answer, 60 points possible Part 2: Analytical problems, 40 points possible

ECON 302: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory (Spring ) Discussion Section Week 7 March 7, 2014

Introduction to economic growth (2)

LEC 2: Exogenous (Neoclassical) growth model

ECON Chapter 6: Economic growth: The Solow growth model (Part 1)

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

Class Notes. Intermediate Macroeconomics. Li Gan. Lecture 7: Economic Growth. It is amazing how much we have achieved.

1 The Solow Growth Model

7 Economic Growth I. Questions for Review CHAPTER

Intermediate Macroeconomics,Assignment 3 & 4

Long run economic growth, part 2. The Solow growth model

IN THIS LECTURE, YOU WILL LEARN:

Intermediate Macroeconomics,Assignment 4

). In Ch. 9, when we add technological progress, k is capital per effective worker (k = K

In this chapter, you will learn C H A P T E R National Income: Where it Comes From and Where it Goes CHAPTER 3

Lecture 2: Intermediate macroeconomics, autumn 2012

ECO 4933 Topics in Theory

Problem Set #2. Intermediate Macroeconomics 101 Due 20/8/12

9/10/2017. National Income: Where it Comes From and Where it Goes (in the long-run) Introduction. The Neoclassical model

TOPIC 4 Economi G c rowth

Technical change is labor-augmenting (also known as Harrod neutral). The production function exhibits constant returns to scale:

Problem Set 2: Answer Key

Lecture 2: Intermediate macroeconomics, autumn 2014

The neoclassical model of economic growth. Trevor Swan (1956) Give rise to the Solow Swan model

Chapter 8. Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics and Policy 10/6/2010. Introduction. Technological progress in the Solow model

Questions for Review. CHAPTER 8 Economic Growth II

Savings and Economic Growth

a) We can calculate Private and Public savings as well as investment as a share of GDP using (1):

ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section

ECON 3010 Intermediate Macroeconomics. Chapter 3 National Income: Where It Comes From and Where It Goes

The Role of Physical Capital

E-322 Muhammad Rahman CHAPTER-6

MACROECONOMICS. Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics, and Policy MANKIW. In this chapter, you will learn. Introduction

Ch.3 Growth and Accumulation. Production function and constant return to scale

Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

The Solow Model. DeÞnition 2: A balanced growth path is a situation where each variable in the model is growing at a constant rate.

Queen s University Department of Economics ECON 222 Macroeconomic Theory I Fall Term Section 001 Midterm Examination 31 October 2012

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 5

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

5. If capital lasts an average of 25 years, the depreciation rate is percent per year. A) 25 B) 5 C) 4 D) 2.5

SAMPLE EXAM QUESTIONS FOR FALL 2018 ECON3310 MIDTERM 2

So far in the short-run analysis we have ignored the wage and price (we assume they are fixed).

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

Lecture 3: National Income: Where it comes from and where it goes

Chapter 6: Long-Run Economic Growth

CHAPTER 3 National Income: Where It Comes From and Where It Goes

Macroeconomcs. Factors of production. Outline of model. In this chapter you will learn:

Ch.3 Growth and Accumulation. Production function and constant return to scale

Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

Growth 2. Chapter 6 (continued)

Long-Run Economic Growth

Check your understanding: Solow model 1

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

K and L by the factor z magnifies output produced by the factor z. Define

The Solow Model and Standard of Living

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

Final Exam - Economics 101 (Fall 2009) You will have 120 minutes to complete this exam. There are 105 points and 7 pages

Test Review. Question 1. Answer 1. Question 2. Answer 2. Question 3. Econ 719 Test Review Test 1 Chapters 1,2,8,3,4,7,9. Nominal GDP.

Economic Growth II. macroeconomics. fifth edition. N. Gregory Mankiw. PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich Worth Publishers, all rights reserved

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems I (Solutions)

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015

MACROECONOMICS. Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics, and Policy. N. Gregory Mankiw. PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich

Test Questions. Part I Midterm Questions 1. Give three examples of a stock variable and three examples of a flow variable.

PART II CLASSICAL THEORY. Chapter 3: National Income: Where it Comes From and Where it Goes 1/64

The Solow Growth Model

Chapter 3. National Income: Where it Comes from and Where it Goes

ECON 385. Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory II. Solow Model With Technological Progress and Data. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls UNIVERSITY OF LONDON

SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 5

The Facts of Economic Growth and the Introdution to the Solow Model

ECON 256: Poverty, Growth & Inequality. Jack Rossbach

Chapter 6 Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow 53

Lecture notes 2: Physical Capital, Development and Growth

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

Chapter 6: Long-Run Economic Growth

Economics 202A Suggested Solutions to the Midterm

202: Dynamic Macroeconomics

004: Macroeconomic Theory

Macroeconomics. Review of Growth Theory Solow and the Rest

(S-I) + (T-G) = (X-Z)

Transcription:

The Solow Growth Model

Model Background The Solow growth model is the starting point to determine why growth differs across similar countries it builds on the Cobb-Douglas production model by adding a theory of capital accumulation developed in the mid-1950s by Robert Solow of MIT, it is the basis for the Nobel Prize he received in 1987 the accumulation of capital is a possible engine of long-run economic growth

Building the Model: goods market supply We begin with a production function and assume constant returns. Y=F(K,L) so zy=f(zk,zl) By setting z=1/l we create a per worker function. Y/L=F(K/L,1) So, output per worker is a function of capital per worker. We write this as, y=f(k)

Building the Model: goods market supply The slope of this function is the marginal product of capital per worker. MPK = f(k+1) f(k) y MPK = change change in in y k y=f(k) It tells us the change in output per worker that results when we increase the capital per worker by one. Change in k Change in y k

Building the Model: goods market demand We begin with per worker consumption and investment. (Government purchases and net exports are not included in the Solow model). This gives us the following per worker national income accounting identity. y = c+i Given a savings rate (s) and a consumption rate (1 s) we can generate a consumption function. c = (1 s)y which makes our identity, y = (1 s)y + I rearranging, i = s*y so investment per worker equals savings per worker.

Steady State Equilibrium The Solow model long run equilibrium occurs at the point where both (y) and (k) are constant. These are the endogenous variables in the model. The exogenous variable is (s).

Steady State Equilibrium By substituting f(k) for (y), the investment per worker function (i = s*y) becomes a function of capital per worker (i = s*f(k)). To augment the model we define a depreciation rate (d). To see the impact of investment and depreciation on capital we develop the following (change in capital) formula, dk = i dk substituting for (i) gives us, dk = s*f(k) dk

The Solow Diagram graphs the production function and the capital accumulation relation together, with K t on the x-axis: Investment, Depreciation At this point, dkt = syt, so Capital, Kt

The Solow Diagram: When investment is greater than depreciation, the capital stock increases The capital stock rises until investment equals depreciation: At this steady state point, dk = 0 Investment, depreciation Depreciation: d K Investment: s Y Net investment K0 K* Capital, K

Suppose the economy starts at K 0 : Investment, Depreciation The red line is above the green at K0: Saving = investment is greater than depreciation at K0 So Kt > 0 because Since Kt > 0, Kt increases from K0 to K1 > K0 K0 K1 Capital, Kt

Now imagine if we start at a K 0 here: Investment, Depreciation At K0, the green line is above the red line Saving = investment is now less than depreciation So Kt < 0 because Then since Kt < 0, Kt decreases from K0 to K1 < K0 K1 K0 Capital, Kt

We call this the process of transition dynamics: Transitioning from any K t toward the economy s steady-state K*, where K t = 0 and growth ceases Investment, Depreciation No matter where we start, we ll transition to K*! At this value of K, dkt = syt, so K* Capital, Kt

Changing the exogenous variable - savings We know that steady state is at the point where s*f(k)=dk s*f(k*)=dk* Investment, Depreciation dk s*f(k) What happens if we increase savings? This would increase the slope of our investment function and cause the function to shift up. This would lead to a higher steady state level of capital. Similarly a lower savings rate leads to a lower steady state level of capital. s*f(k*)=dk* k* k ** s*f(k) k

We can see what happens to output, Y, and thus to growth if we rescale the vertical axis: Investment, Depreciation, Income Y* Saving = investment and depreciation now appear here Now output can be graphed in the space above in the graph We still have transition dynamics toward K* So we also have dynamics toward a steady-state level of income, Y* K* Capital, Kt

The Solow Diagram with Output At any point, Consumption is the difference between Output and Investment: C = Y I Investment, depreciation, and output Output: Y Y* Y0 Consumption Depreciation: d K Investment: s Y K0 K* Capital, K

Conclusion The Solow Growth model is a dynamic model that allows us to see how our endogenous variables capital per worker and output per worker are affected by the exogenous variable savings. We also see how parameters such as depreciation enter the model, and finally the effects that initial capital allocations have on the time paths toward equilibrium. In the next section we augment this model to include changes in other exogenous variables; population and technological growth.

Model Background As mentioned, the Solow growth model allows us a dynamic view of how savings affects the economy over time. We also learned about the steady state level of capital. Now, we assume policy makers can set the savings rate to determine a steady state level of capital that maximizes consumption per worker. This is known as the golden rule level of capital (k* gold )

Building the Model: We begin by finding the steady state consumption per worker. From the national income accounts identity, y = c + i we get c = y i We want steady state c so we substitute steady state values for both output (f(k*)) and investment which equals depreciation in steady state (dk*) giving us c*=f(k*) dk* f(k*),dk* dk* f(k*) Because, consumption per worker is the difference between output and investment per worker we want to choose k* so that this distance is maximized. This is the golden rule level of capital k* gold c* gold k* gold k* A condition that characterizes the golden rule level of capital is Below k* gold, MPK = d increasing k* increases c* Above k* gold, increasing k* reduces c*

Building the Model: While the economy moves toward a steady state it is not necessarily the golden rule steady state. Any increase or decrease in savings would shift the sf(k) curve and would result in a steady state with a lower level of consumption. f(k*),dk* dk* f(k*) s gold f(k*) s gold f(k*) k* k* gold To reach the golden rule steady state The economy needs the right savings rate.

The Transition to the Golden Rule Steady State Suppose an economy starts with more capital than in the golden rule steady state. This causes an immediate increase in consumption and an equal decrease in investment. Output, y Over time, as the capital stock falls, output, Consumption, c consumption, and investment Investment, i fall. The new steady state has a higher level of consumption than the initial steady state. t 0 At t 0, the savings rate is reduced. Time

The Transition to the Golden Rule Steady State Suppose an economy starts with less capital than in the golden rule steady state. This causes an immediate decrease in consumption and an equal increase in investment. Output, y Over time, as the capital stock grows, output, consumption, and investment increase. The new steady state has a higher level of consumption than the initial steady state. Consumption, c Investment, i t 0 At t 0, the savings rate is increased. Time

Conclusion In this section we used our knowledge that savings affects the steady state and chose the savings rate to maximize consumption per worker. This is known as the golden rule level of capital (k* gold ) In the next section we augment this model to include changes in other exogenous variables; population and technological growth.

Model Background As mentioned, the Solow growth model allows us a dynamic view of how savings affects the economy over time. We learned about the steady state level of capital and how a golden rule steady state level of capital can be achieved by setting the savings rate to maximize consumption per worker. We now augment the model to see the effects of population growth and technological progress.

Steady State Equilibrium By expanding our model to include population growth our model more closely resembles the sustained economic growth observable in much of the real world. To see how population growth affects the steady state we need to know how it affects the accumulation of capital per worker. When we add population growth (n) to our model the change in capital stock per worker becomes dk = i (d+n)k As we can see population growth will have a negative effect on capital stock accumulation. We can think of (d+n)k as breakeven investment or the amount of investment necessary to keep capital stock per worker constant. Our analysis proceeds as in the previous presentations. To see the impact of investment, depreciation, and population growth on capital we use the (change in capital) formula from above, dk = i (d+n)k substituting for (i) gives us, dk = s*f(k) (d+n)k

Steady State Equilibrium with population growth At the point where both (k) and (y) are constant it must be the case that, dk = s*f(k) (d+n)k = 0 or, s*f(k) = (d+n)k this occurs at our equilibrium point k*. capital stock per worker shrinks. Investment Break-even Investment s*f(k*)=(d+n)k* Like depreciation, population growth is one reason why the Break-even investment (d+n)k s*f(k) Investment k* k At k* break-even investment equals investment.

The impact of population growth Suppose population growth changes from n 1 to n 2. This shifts the line representing population growth and depreciation upward. Investment Break-even Investment An increase in n (d+n 2 )k (d+n 1 )k At the new steady state k 2 * capital per worker and output per worker are lower s*f(k) The model predicts that economies with higher rates of population growth will have lower levels of capital per worker and lower levels of income. reduces k* k 2 * k 1 * k

The efficiency of labour We rewrite our production function as Y=F(K,L*E) where E is the efficiency of labour. L*E is a measure of the number of effective workers. The growth of labour efficiency is g. Our production function y=f(k) becomes output per effective worker since y=y/(l*e) and k=k/(l*e) With this augmentation dk is needed to replace depreciating capital, nk is needed to provide capital to new workers, and gk is needed to provide capital for the new effective workers created by technological progress.

Steady State Equilibrium with population growth and technological progress At the point where both (k) and (y) are constant it must be the case that, dk = s*f(k) (d+n+g)k = 0 or, s*f(k) = (d+n)k this occurs at our equilibrium point k*. Like depreciation and population growth, the labour augmenting technological progress rate causes the capital stock per worker to shrink. s*f(k*)=(d+n)k* Investment Break-even Investment Break-even investment (d+n+g)k s*f(k) Investment At k* break-even investment equals investment. k* k

The impact of technological progress Suppose the worker efficiency growth rate changes from g 1 to g 2. This shifts the line representing population growth, depreciation, and worker efficiency growth upward. At the new steady state k 2 * capital per worker and output per worker are lower. The model predicts that economies with higher rates of worker efficiency growth will have lower levels of capital per worker and lower levels of income. Investment Break-even Investment An increase in g k 2 * reduces k* (d+n+g 2 )k (d+n+g1 )k k 1 * s*f(k) k

Effects of technological progress on the golden rule With technological progress the golden rule level of capital is defined as the steady state that maximizes consumption per effective worker. Following our previous analysis steady state consumption per worker is c* = f(k*) (d + n + g)k* To maximize this MPK = d + n + g or MPK d = n + g That is, at the Golden Rule level of capital, the net marginal product of capital MPK d, equals the rate of growth of total output, n+g.

Steady State Growth Rates in the Solow Model with Technological Progress Variable Symbol Steady-State Growth Rate Capital per effective worker k=k/(e*l) 0 Output per effective worker y=y/(e*l)=f(k) 0 Output per worker Y/L=y*E g Total output Y=y(E*L) n+g

Conclusion In this section we added changes in two exogenous variables (population and technological growth) to the Solow growth model. We saw that in steady state output per effective worker remains constant, output per worker depends only on technological growth, and that Total output depends on population and technological growth.

Strengths and Weaknesses of the Solow Model The strengths of the Solow model are: 1. It provides a theory that determines how rich a country is in the long run. 2. The principle of transition dynamics allows for an understanding of differences in growth rates across countries. The weaknesses of the Solow model are: 1. It focuses on investment and capital, while the much more important factor of TFP is still unexplained. 2. It does not explain why different countries have different investment and productivity rates. 3. The model does not provide a theory of sustained long-run economic growth.

The Model Summarized Production The production function: - has constant returns to scale in capital and labor - has an exponent of less than 1 (let s say one-third on capital) decreasing returns to capital Variables are time subscripted they may potentially change over time Output can be used for either consumption (C t ) or investment (I t ): Y t = C t + I t Capital Accumulation the capital stock next year equals the sum of the capital started with this year plus the amount of investment undertaken this year minus depreciation Depreciation is the amount of capital that wears out each period ~ 10 percent/year Labor the amount of labor in the economy is given exogenously at a constant level, L Investment the amount of investment in the economy is equal to a constant investment rate, s, times total output, Y I t = s Y t Total output is used for either consumption or investment therefore, consumption equals output times the quantity one minus the investment rate C t = (1 - s) Y t

Summary 1. The starting point for the Solow model is the production model with constant returns to scale in capital and labor with a diminishing marginal product of capital 2. The capital stock is the sum of past investments. The capital stock today consists of machines and buildings that were bought over the last several decades.

3. The goal of the Solow model is to deepen our understanding of economic growth, but in this it s only partially successful. The fact that capital runs into diminishing returns means that the model does not lead to sustained economic growth. As the economy accumulates more capital, depreciation rises one-for-one, but output and therefore investment rise less than one-for- one because of the diminishing marginal product of capital. Eventually, the new investment is only just sufficient to offset depreciation, and the capital stock ceases to grow. Output stops growing as well, and the economy settles down to a steady state.

4. There are two major accomplishments of the Solow model. First, it provides a successful theory of the determination of capital, by predicting that the capital-output ratio is equal to the investment-depreciation ratio. Countries with high investment rates should thus have high capital-output ratios, and this prediction holds up well in the data.

5. The second major accomplishment of the Solow model is the principle of transition dynamics, which states that the farther below its steady state an economy is, the faster it will grow. While the model cannot explain long-run growth, the principle of transition dynamics provides a nice theory of differences in growth rates across countries. Increases in the investment rate or total factor productivity can increase a country s steady-state position and therefore increase growth, at least for a number of years. These changes can be analyzed with the help of the Solow diagram.

6. In general, most poor countries have low TFP levels and low investment rates, the two key determinants of steady-state incomes. If a country maintained good fundamentals but was poor because it had received a bad shock, we would see it grow rapidly, according to the principle of transition dynamics. CHAPTER 5 The Solow Growth Model