A Simple Approach to CAPM and Option Pricing. Riccardo Cesari and Carlo D Adda (University of Bologna)

Similar documents
1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Black-Scholes Option Pricing

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

The stochastic calculus

Introduction: A Shortcut to "MM" (derivative) Asset Pricing**

Risk Neutral Measures

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

The Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

FINANCIAL OPTIMIZATION. Lecture 5: Dynamic Programming and a Visit to the Soft Side

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Option Pricing Under a Stressed-Beta Model

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY AND OPTION PRICING

Risk Neutral Modelling Exercises

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Credit Risk and Underlying Asset Risk *

The Lognormal Interest Rate Model and Eurodollar Futures

WITH SKETCH ANSWERS. Postgraduate Certificate in Finance Postgraduate Certificate in Economics and Finance

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Subject CT8 Financial Economics Core Technical Syllabus

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing

Probability in Options Pricing

Equilibrium Asset Returns

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

HEDGING RAINBOW OPTIONS IN DISCRETE TIME

Continuous-Time Pension-Fund Modelling

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Lévy models in finance

Derivation and Comparative Statics of the Black-Scholes Call and Put Option Pricing Formulas

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE

Errata, Mahler Study Aids for Exam 3/M, Spring 2010 HCM, 1/26/13 Page 1

TEACHING NOTE 00-03: MODELING ASSET PRICES AS STOCHASTIC PROCESSES II. is non-stochastic and equal to dt. From these results we state the following:

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Basics of Asset Pricing Theory {Derivatives pricing - Martingales and pricing kernels

The Black-Scholes Model

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

Option Pricing Models for European Options

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06

An Equilibrium Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Fractional Liu Process and Applications to Finance

Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation

Valuation of performance-dependent options in a Black- Scholes framework

Hedging under Arbitrage

MORNING SESSION. Date: Wednesday, April 30, 2014 Time: 8:30 a.m. 11:45 a.m. INSTRUCTIONS TO CANDIDATES

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Semigroup Properties of Arbitrage Free Pricing Operators. John Heaney and Geoffrey Poitras

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I)

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

************* with µ, σ, and r all constant. We are also interested in more sophisticated models, such as:

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

CAPITAL BUDGETING IN ARBITRAGE FREE MARKETS

Risk Neutral Valuation

TEST OF BOUNDED LOG-NORMAL PROCESS FOR OPTIONS PRICING

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

SOME APPLICATIONS OF OCCUPATION TIMES OF BROWNIAN MOTION WITH DRIFT IN MATHEMATICAL FINANCE

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Valuation of Standard Options under the Constant Elasticity of Variance Model

Transcription:

A imple Approach to CA and Option ricing Riccardo Cesari and Carlo D Adda (University of Bologna) rcesari@economia.unibo.it dadda@spbo.unibo.it eptember, 001 eywords: asset pricing, CA, option pricing. JEL Classification: G1 Abstract. In this paper we propose a simple approach to asset valuation in terms of two characteristics, expected value and expected variability, and their distinct marginal contributions to the value of the market portfolio. The result is shown to correspond to harpe s CA. We then show that pricing in terms of characteristics (or CA) applies to any asset and in particular to option valuation. A pricing formula corresponding to Black and choles no-arbitrage option pricing is obtained under the assumption of normal asset price distributions. 1

0. Introduction Capital asset pricing model and option pricing theory: two of the best known and most important results of finance concern the pricing of assets. The first model is attributed to William harpe (1964) even if Tobin (1958), Treynor (1965), Lintner (1965) and ossin (1966) reached similar results in the same years and all of them are in debt of arkowitz (195, 1959) portfolio model. Option pricing theory, instead, stems from the seminal paper of Black and choles (1973), in which an arbitrage argument is developed to solve in a new manner the old problem of pricing option contracts 1. In both cases pricing is the relevant point at issue and two questions cannot be avoided. 1) In microeconomic theory, prices are marginal values (marginal cost and marginal utility, in equilibrium). Is the same marginal approach still valid in finance? ) Notwithstanding the apparent differences, is there a unique pricing function containing both models? As we shall see, the answer is yes to both questions. In fact, it can be shown that the pricing function of an asset can be obtained, in a two parameter, normal approach, from the marginal contributions provided by the asset in terms of risk and return. oreover, even if the two results appear quite different, a two parameter, normal approach is common to both and the two models can be obtained jointly: CA is able to price options and option prices, in a normal world, satisfies CA conditions. 1. The general mean-variance framework Let us assume that investors are interested only in risk and return, considered as the two essential characteristics or factors of single assets and portfolios. Quadratic utility or normal distribution are the alternative hypotheses used to justify the mean-variance approach. ore precisely, in our view, the first assumption is that asset prices are determined by two factors (one positive and one negative). arket prices reflect price and quantity of each factor: price times quantity summed over all characteristics gives the market price of the asset 1 Early models can be found in Cootner (ed.) (1964). New developments are collected in VV.AA. (199). ee Rubinstein (1976) and Leland (1999) for the lognormal case.

exactly as in a restaurant the total bill is the sum of price times quantity of all choices from the menu. How can we measure the two factors, return and risk, for a given security? Our second assumption states that the relevant quantity of each factor is a marginal quantity: respectively, the marginal increase in return and the marginal increase in risk provided by a marginal unit of the asset added to the market (total) portfolio. Therefore, assets are priced at the margin with respect to their contribution to expected return (mean) and expected risk (variance). In symbols, over a given time horizon T, let be a no dividend asset (a random variable representing the asset s cash flow at T) with mean E(), variance Var() and current price. Let be the market portfolio and 1 and be the current prices of the two factors, return and risk. The current price of a quantity g of the asset is given by: g = 1 marginal expected return - marginal expected risk where: marginal expected return = E(+g)- E() = g E() marginal expected risk=var(+g)-var() = g Var()+gCov(,) so that, simplifying: = 1 E() - (gvar()+cov(,)) and letting the quantity g go to 0: [1.1] = 1 E() - Cov(,) It is easy to show that this equation for any asset is the CA. roposition 1: Equation [1.1] is the CA. roof: Divide both members by and by 1 and then subtract 1 and rearrange, obtaining: 3

[1.] E( ) 1 Cov 1= 1+ ( 1, 1) 1 1 where the covariance properties Cov(+a,+b)=Cov(,) and Cov(,b)=bCov(,) for constants a and b have been used. Define the rate of return of the no dividend asset as the random variable: [1.3] R = 1 and note that if the asset has a sure, fixed value 1 at the horizon (i.e. it is a risk free zero coupon discount bond) then Cov(,)=0 and: [1.4] = 1 so that the price of the first characteristics is the present value of one unit of money to be received for certain at the future date and the risk free rate is: R 1 = 1 ubstituting in [1.] we have: [1.5] E( R ) = R + Cov ( R, R ) x For the market portfolio: E( R ) = R + Var ( R ) that is: [1.6] E( R ) R Var( R ) = to be substituted in [1.5] obtaining: 4

Cov( R, R ) x [1.7] E( R ) = R + ( E( R ) R ) Var( R ) Cov( R, R ) Writing β, equation [1.7] is the CA in usual Var( R ) form. Q.E.D. In terms of prices, from [1.1]: [1.8] = E() - Var() and therefore: [1.9] E E ( ) = ( ) Var( ) Cov(, ) Equation [1.1] or equivalently [1.9] is the basic valuation equation of any security. It is interesting to note that, writing, without loss of generality: ρ T t [1.10] E( ) = e and 1= e ( ) r( T t ) for any security equation [1.1] has two representations: [1.11a] = e -r(t-t) [ e ρ(t-t) - Cov(,)/ ] and [1.11b] = e -r(t-t) [ e r(t-t) ]= e -r(t-t) E $ ( ) In the first one, the current price is given by the future expected value E(), obtained using the natural expected rate of growth ρ, riskadjusted through the covariance term and discounted at the risk-free rate. In the second one, the same current price is given by a future expected value E $ ( ), simply obtained using the risk-free growth rate r instead of ρ, discounted at the risk-free rate. We say that, in this case, the risk adjustment is not in the process but in the probabilities ( risk neutral probabilities ). 5

This result is a simplified, static version of the equivalent martingale measure theorem of dynamic asset pricing (e.g. Duffie, 199). roposition : The valuation equation [1.1] has two equivalent representations: [1.11a] = e -r(t-t) E(- (-E())/ ) and [1.11b] = e -r(t-t) E $ ( ) where E(.) is the expectation under the natural probability measure and E $ (.) is the expectation under the risk-adjusted (risk-neutral) probability measure. roof: ee above.. ricing options in the mean-variance framework Let C=max(0, -) be the final value of an European call option written on a no dividend asset with future price, with strike price and maturity T. According to [1.1] the price of C is given by: [.1] Call = 1 E(C) - Cov(C,) and we shall show that, under normality, equation [.1] is the Black and choles option price. In order to do this, we have first to calculate the Black and choles price in the case of normal distributions. Lemma 1: Let be a normal variable, N(µ, ), with density n(.). Then: ( µ ) µ E( C) E(max( 0, )) = exp( ) + ( µ )( 1 )) π where u) is the integral of the standard normal density φ up to u. 6

roof: E(max( 0, )) = sn( s) dx n( s) ds then calculate the first integral as: ( s µ + µ ) sn( s) ds = + + 1 ( s µ ) exp( π ( s µ ) + µ [exp( )] + µ ( 1 )) π µ and note that the second one is 1 ). Q.E.D. ) ds = Lemma : Let (t) be the Gaussian diffusion process solution of the stochastic differential equation: [.] d( t) = ( A( t) + a) dt + dw( t) ( t ) = 0 0 with A,a, constant and W(t) standard brownian motion. Then: A ( t t a [.3] t e A e A t t t 0 ) ( 0 ) e A ( t v) ( ) = + ( ) + dw ( v 0 1 ) t0 and the conditional distribution of (T) given (t) is: a [.4] T t N t e A e A ( T t) A ( T t) A e A ( T t) ( ) ( ) ( ( ) + ( 1), ( 1)) roof: ee Arnold (1974), p.159. roposition 3: Let (t) be the price of a no dividend asset with dynamics: [.5] d( t) = µ ( t, ) dt + dw( t) and let C(t, ) be the price of an European call option maturing at time T t+τ with strike price. 7

Then: [.6] rτ exp( rτ) $ ( ( t) e ) rτ ( t) e C( t, ) = exp( ) + (( t) e )( 1 π $ $ $ = (exp( rτ) 1) r rτ )) r being the continuously compounded instantaneous riskless rate. roof: Writing C for the first partial derivative, C( t, ), and C for the second partial derivative, the value V of an arbitrage portfolio being long C unit of the underlying asset and short one unit of the call is: [.7] V(, C)=C -C By Ito lemma the dynamics of the call price C(,t) and the arbitrage portfolio (which is linear in and C) are given by: [.8] dc=c d+c t dt+½c dt [.9] dv=v d+v C dc = C d-dc = -C t dt-½c dt Given that V is instantaneously riskless it must gain the riskless rate: [.10] dv=rvdt=r(c -C)dt so that, combining [.9] and [.10] we obtain the problem: ½C + C r + C t -Cr = 0 d(t) = µ(,t)dt + dw(t) C(,T)=max(0, (T)-) Writing: r d ( t ) = rdt + µ ( dt + dw( t)) rdt + dz( t) where Z(t) is, by Girsanov theorem, a standard brownian motion in a different space, the problem is now the following: 8

½C + C r + C t -Cr = 0 d(t) = rdt + dz(t) C(,T)=max(0, (T)-) whose solution has the stochastic representation in terms of conditional expectations $ E t (Friedman, 1975 p.147) in the probability space induced by Z(t) (risk-neutral probability space): C(, t) = E$ (max( 0, ( T) ) exp( rτ )) t Noting that by lemma with A=r and a=0: [.11] ( T) ( t) N(( t)exp( rτ), $ ) $ (exp( rτ) 1) r we have, from lemma 1 the required result. Q.E.D. 3. Equivalence of CA and option pricing in the normal case. The same valuation result can be obtained using the CA formula [.1]. Lemma 3: If (,) are jointly normal with density: 1 1 s E n( s, m) exp( ( ) [( ( ) = ) π 1 ρ 1 ρ,. ρ. ( s E( )) ( m E( )) m E( ) + ( ) ] then the conditional distribution of s is given by: s N( E( ) + ρ ( s E( )), ( 1 ρ )),, roof: ee ress (197), p. 69. 9

E( ) Lemma 4: Cov( C, ) = Cov(, )( 1 )) roof: Cov( C, ) = E[( C E( C))( E( )] = R R R + [max( 0, ) E( C)]( E( )) n( s, m) dsdm = E( C)( E( )) n( s) n( m s) dsdm + R ( E( C))( E( )) n( s) n( ms) dsdm = E( C)[ ( E( )) n( ms) dm] n( s) ds + + R ( s E( C))[ ( E( )) n( m s) dm] n( s) ds But from the previous lemma: E( E( ) s) = ρ ( s E( )), so that: R Cov( C, ) = E( C) ρ ( s E( )) n( s) ds +, ρ ρ,, + ( s E( C)) ρ, ( s E( )) n( s) ds = + ( s )( s E( )) n( s) ds = + + [ ( s E( )) n( s) ds + ( E( ) ) ( s E( )) n( s) ds] For the first integral: 10

( s E( )) d exp( + + ) ( s E( )) n( s) ds = ( s E( )) ds = π ds by int egration by parts: ( s E( )) + E( ) [( s E( )) exp( )] + ( 1 )) = π ( E( )) E( ) ( E( )) exp( ) + ( 1 )) π For the second integral: ( s E( )) d exp( + + ) ( s E( )) n( s) ds = ds = π ds ( s E( )) ( E( )) [exp( )] + = exp( ) π π so that: ( E( )) Cov( C, ) = ρ [ ( E( )) exp(, ) + π ρ E( ) ( E( )) ( 1 )) + ( E ( ) ) exp( )] = π E( ) ( 1 )), roposition 4: The CA option price is the Black and choles option price under the natural probability measure. roof: From CA: 11

= E( C) Cov( C, ) = Call ( E()) E() [ exp( ) + ( E() )( 1 ))] π E() Cov(, )( 1 )) But, from Lemma 1 and roposition : = E( C) Cov( C, ) = E$ ( C ) = Call rτ $ ( ( t) e ) rτ ( t) e exp( ) + (( t) e )( 1 π $ $ rτ )) which is the Black and choles price [.6]. Q.E.D. 4. Conclusion In these years the proliferation of financial asset of many types has been enormous. This paper tries to explore whether the apparent multiplicity of rights and obligations may be tackled through one simple valuation approach. In a Gaussian world asset prices are obtained through the valuation of two basic characteristics, expected value and variance. We have shown that the valuation formula agrees both with the CA and the Back and choles no-arbitrage pricing of options. Extension to non-normal distributions is in our research agenda. 1

References Arnold, L. (1974), tochastic differential equations: theory and applications, New York, Wiley Black F. and choles. (1973), The pricing of options and corporate liabilities, Journal of political economy, 81, 637-654 Cootner,. H. (ed.) (1964), The random character of stock market prices, Cambridge (a), it ress Duffie D. (199), Dynamic asset pricing theory, rinceton, rinceton University ress Friedman A. (1975), tochastic differential equations and applications, vol. 1, New York, Academic ress Leland H. E. (1999), Beyond mean-variance: performance measurement in a nonsymmetrical world, Financial Analysts Journal, 1, 7-36 Lintner, J. (1965), The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets, Review of Economics and tatistics, 47, 13-37 arkowitz, H. (195), ortfolio selection, Journal of Finance, 7, 77-91 arkowitz, H. (1959), ortfolio selection: efficient diversification of investments, New Haven, Yale University ress ossin, J. (1966), Equilibrium in a capital asset market, Econometrica, 34, 768-783 ress,. J. (197), Applied multivariate analysis, New York, Holt, Rinehart and Winston Rubinstein,. (1976), The valuation of uncertain income streams and the pricing of options, The Bell Journal of Economics and anagement cience, 7, 407-45 13

harpe, W. F. (1964), Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk, Journal of Finance, 19, 45-44 Tobin, J. (1958), Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk, Review of economic studies, 5, 65-86 Treynor, J. (1965), How to rate management of investment funds, Harvard business review, 43, 63-75 VV.AA. (199), From Black-choles to black holes. New frontiers in options, London, Risk agazine Ltd 14