Nonlinear Persistence and Partial Insurance: Income and Consumption Dynamics in the PSID

Similar documents
Income Dynamics and Consumption Inequality: Nonlinear Persistence and Partial Insurance

The Microeconometric Analysis of Consumption, Savings and Labour Supply

House Prices and Risk Sharing

Labor Income Dynamics and the Insurance from Taxes, Transfers, and the Family

Nonlinear household earnings dynamics, self-insurance, and welfare

Partial Insurance. ECON 34430: Topics in Labor Markets. T. Lamadon (U of Chicago) Fall 2017

Income Dynamics and Consumption Insurance

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

From Income to Consumption: Understanding the Transmission of Inequality

The Distributions of Income and Consumption. Risk: Evidence from Norwegian Registry Data

Labor Income Risk in Germany over the Business Cycle

What can we learn about household consumption expenditure from data on income and assets?

What Can a Life-Cycle Model Tell Us About Household Responses to the Financial Crisis?

How Much Insurance in Bewley Models?

How Much Consumption Insurance in the U.S.?

From Wages to Welfare: Decomposing Gains and Losses From Rising Inequality

Consumption Inequality and Family Labor Supply

Higher-Order Income Risk over the Business Cycle: A Parametric Approach

CHILDREN, TIME ALLOCATION AND CONSUMPTION INSURANCE

Family and Government Insurance: Wage, Earnings, and Income Risks in the Netherlands and the U.S.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CONSUMPTION INEQUALITY AND FAMILY LABOR SUPPLY. Richard Blundell Luigi Pistaferri Itay Saporta-Eksten

Has Consumption Inequality Mirrored Income Inequality?

Has Consumption Inequality Mirrored Income Inequality?

The implications of richer earnings dynamics. for consumption, wealth, and welfare

At any time, wages differ dramatically across U.S. workers. Some

How Much Consumption Insurance in Bewley Models with Endogenous Family Labor Supply?

A Bayesian Approach to Estimating Household Income Risk and Consumption Insurance

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk

Relating Income to Consumption Part 1

Discussion of Heaton and Lucas Can heterogeneity, undiversified risk, and trading frictions solve the equity premium puzzle?

Earnings Dynamics, Mobility Costs and Transmission of Firm and Market Level Shocks

Worker Betas: Five Facts about Systematic Earnings Risk

Characterizing Income Shocks over the Life-cycle

Reconciling Estimates of Earnings Processes in Growth Rates and Levels

Online Appendix. Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle. Not intended for publication.

Interest Rate Pass-Through: Mortgage Rates, Household Consumption, and Voluntary Deleveraging. Online Appendix

Has Consumption Inequality Mirrored Income Inequality?

Improving the Measurement of Earnings Dynamics

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS. Bounds on the Return to Education in Australia using Ability Bias

Online Appendix for The Heterogeneous Responses of Consumption between Poor and Rich to Government Spending Shocks

Labour Supply, Taxes and Benefits

The Idea. Friedman (1957): Permanent Income Hypothesis. Use the Benchmark KS model with Modifications. Income Process. Progress since then

Reconciling Estimates of Earnings Processes in Growth Rates and Levels

STUDIES ON EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF MA Title MODELS WITH HETEROGENEOUS AGENTS

The Distributional Dynamics of Income and Consumption. Carlos Diaz Alejandro Lecture. LAMES November 2008

Why is Consumption More Log Normal Than Income? Gibrat s Law Revisited

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

Consumption and Labor Supply with Partial Insurance: An Analytical Framework

Notes on Estimating Earnings Processes

CONSUMPTION INEQUALITY AND PARTIAL INSURANCE

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE IMPLICATIONS OF RICHER EARNINGS DYNAMICS FOR CONSUMPTION AND WEALTH

Euler Equations, Subjective Expectations and Income Shocks

Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions

The Cross-Sectional Implications of Rising Wage Inequality in the United States

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW MUCH CONSUMPTION INSURANCE BEYOND SELF-INSURANCE? Greg Kaplan Giovanni L. Violante

Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1

The Macroeconomic Implications of Rising Wage Inequality in the United States

Consumption, Income and Earnings Inequality in the UK

Determinants of Wage and Earnings Inequality in the United States

Household finance in Europe 1

Online Robustness Appendix to Are Household Surveys Like Tax Forms: Evidence from the Self Employed

Has Consumption Inequality Mirrored Income Inequality?

Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk

Leverage, Re-leveraging, and Household Spending

Household Finance in China

The Common Factor in Idiosyncratic Volatility:

Insurance, Redistribution, and the Inequality of Lifetime Income

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform

Simulating a progressive loan system for Spain with real labor market data

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer?

Euler Equations, Subjective Expectations and Income Shocks

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis

Towards a Micro-Founded Theory of Aggregate Labor Supply

Asymmetries in earnings, employment and wage risk in Great Britain

Progressive Taxation and Risky Career Choices

University of Toronto Department of Economics. Towards a Micro-Founded Theory of Aggregate Labor Supply

Value of a Statistical Life: Relative Position vs. Relative Age

Wage Shocks, Household Labor Supply, and Income Instability

The Insurance Role of Household Labor Supply for Older Workers: Preliminary Results

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Changes in the Distribution of Income Volatility

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform

Wage Scars and Human Capital Theory: Appendix

Uncertainty Determinants of Firm Investment

GARCH Models for Inflation Volatility in Oman

Unemployment, Consumption Smoothing and the Value of UI

Markov-Chain Approximations for Life-Cycle Models

Aging, Social Security Reform and Factor Price in a Transition Economy

The persistence of urban poverty in Ethiopia: A tale of two measurements

Improving the Measurement of Earnings Dynamics

The Financial Labor Supply Accelerator

The Distribution of Wealth and the Marginal Propensity to Consume

The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings

The marginal propensity to consume out of a tax rebate: the case of Italy

Cahier de recherche/working Paper Inequality and Debt in a Model with Heterogeneous Agents. Federico Ravenna Nicolas Vincent.

DIFFERENTIAL MORTALITY, UNCERTAIN MEDICAL EXPENSES, AND THE SAVING OF ELDERLY SINGLES

How Do Consumers Respond To Transitory Income Shocks? Reconciling Longitudinal Studies and Natural Experiments

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application

Transcription:

AEA Papers and Proceedings 28, 8: 7 https://doi.org/.257/pandp.2849 Nonlinear and Partial Insurance: Income and Consumption Dynamics in the PSID By Manuel Arellano, Richard Blundell, and Stephane Bonhomme* In this paper we highlight the important role the PSID has played in our understanding of income dynamics and consumption insurance, see for example, Krueger and Perri (26); Blundell, Pistaferri, and Preston (28), henceforth, (BPP); and Guvenen and Smith (24). In the partial insurance approach, transmission parameters are specified that link shocks to income with consumption growth. These transmission parameters can change across time and may differ across individuals reflecting the degree of insurance available. They encompass self-insurance through simple credit markets as well as other mechanisms used to smooth consumption. We explore the nonlinear nature of income shocks and describe a new quantile-based panel data framework for income dynamics, developed in Arellano, Blundell, and Bonhomme (ABB 27). In this approach the persistence of past income shocks is allowed to vary according to the size and sign of the current shock. We find that the model provides a good match with data on family earnings and on individual wages from the PSID. We confirm the results on * Arellano: CEMFI, Madrid (email: arellano@cemfi.es); Blundell: University College London, Gower Street, London (email: r.blundell@ucl.ac.uk); Bonhomme: University of Chicago, Chicago (email: sbonhomme@uchicago.edu). We would like to thank David Johnson and Karen Dynan for comments. Luigi Pistaferri and Itay Saporta-Eksten for insights on the PSID data, Magne Mogstad and Michael Graber for the estimations using the Norwegian population register data as part of the project on Labour Income Dynamics and the Insurance from Taxes, Transfers and the Family. Arellano acknowledges research funding from the Ministerio de Economía y Competitividad, Grant ECO26-79848-P. Blundell would like to thank the ESRC Centre CPP at IFS and the ERC MicroConLab project for financial assistance. Bonhomme acknowledges support from the European Research Council/ERC grant agreement n 2637. Go to https://doi.org/.257/pandp.2849 to visit the article page for additional materials and author disclosure statement(s). income dynamics using the extensive population register data from Norway. Exploiting the enhanced consumption and asset data in recent waves of the PSID, we show that nonlinear persistence has key implications for consumption insurance. The approach is used to provide new empirical measures of partial insurance in which the transmission of income shocks to consumption varies systematically with assets, the level of the shock, and the history of past shocks. I. Earnings and Consumption Dynamics A prototypical canonical panel data model of (log) family (earned) income y it is y it = η it + ε it, i =,, N, t =,, T, where y it is net of a systematic component, η it is a random walk with innovation v it, η it = η it + v it, i =,, N, t =,, T, and ε it is a transitory shock. There is good economic reasoning behind this decomposition: persistent shocks to income are more difficult to insure, especially for young families with low assets. How families cope with persistent shocks is the main focus of this research. Short-run fluctuations will matter too, of course, especially for households with low assets (or low access to liquid assets). In the partial insurance framework, consumption growth is related to income shocks, c it = ϕ t v it + ψ t ε it + ν it, i =,, N, t =,, T, where c it = c it c i, t, c it is log consumption net of a systematic component, ϕ t is the P2849.indd 2/2/8 9:5 AM

2 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 28 transmission of persistent shocks v it, and ψ t the transmission of transitory shocks; the ν it are taste shocks, assumed to be independent across periods. BPP show identification and efficient estimation using GMM. They also allow for measurement error and extend to MA() transitory shocks. The parameters ϕ t and ψ t link the evolution of consumption inequality to income inequality. They indicate the degree of partial insurance, and will differ by age, assets, and human capital. For example, using a linearized approximation to a simple benchmark intertemporal consumption model, Blundell, Low, and Preston (23) show ϕ t = ( π it ) and ψ t = ( π it ) γ Lt, Assets where π it it Assets it + Human Wealth and γ Lt is the it annuity value of a temporary shock to income for an individual aged t retiring at age L. For the PSID, estimates of ( π it ) typically average at around.82. BPP estimate a partial insurance coefficient ϕ of.642 (.9). This represents excess insurance relative to ( π it ). They document higher values for samples without college education, for older cohorts, and for low wealth samples. This linearized partial insurance framework provides key insights on the distributional dynamics of income and consumption. However, it rules out the nonlinear transmission of shocks and restricts interactions in consumption responses. II. Nonlinear The aim in the new work on nonlinear persistence is to step back from the standard panel data model of income dynamics and take a different track: develop an alternative approach in which the impact of past shocks can be altered by the size and sign of new shocks. The framework allows unusual shocks to wipe out the memory of past shocks. Additionally the future persistence of a current shock will depend on future shocks. We will see that the presence of unusual shocks matches the data well and has a key impact on consumption and saving decisions over the life cycle. In this framework we maintain the factor structure for log income but allow η it to follow a general first-order Markov process. Denoting the τ th conditional quantile of η it given η i, t as Q t ( η i, t, τ), we specify η it = Q t (η i,t, u it ), where (u it η i,t, η i,t 2, ) ~ Uniform(, ), and ε it has zero mean, independent over time. The conditional quantile functions Q t ( η i, t, u it ) and the marginal distributions F ε t can all be age specific. This framework allows for quite general nonlinear dynamics of income, allowing a general form of conditional heteroscedasticity, skewness, and kurtosis. To see this, consider the following measure of persistence: ρ t ( η i, t, τ) = Q t ( η i, t, τ), η which measures the persistence of η i, t when, at age t, it is hit by a shock u it that has rank τ. This measures the persistence of histories, which may depend on both the level of earnings ( η it ) and the percentile of the shock (τ). Below we show strong evidence for such nonlinearities in persistence. III. An Empirical Model for Consumption To motivate the specification of consumption we use a standard life-cycle incomplete markets model. Let c it and a it denote log-consumption and assets (beginning of period) net of age dummies. We model consumption in levels and leave the nonlinear rule flexible. Our empirical specification is based on c it = g t ( a it, η it, ε it, ν it ), t =,, T, where ν it are independent across periods, and g t is a nonlinear, age-dependent function, monotone in ν it ; ν it may be interpreted a taste shifter that increases marginal utility. This consumption rule is consistent, in particular, with the standard life-cycle model. ABB derive conditions under which g is nonparametrically identified. The first-order Markov assumption can be generalized to Markov ( p), with any fixed p (although this requires larger T ). P2849.indd 2 2/2/8 9:5 AM

VOL. 8 NONLINEAR PERSISTENCE AND PARTIAL INSURANCE 3 The consumption responses to η and ε are ϕ t (a, η, ε) = E [ g t ( a, η, ε, ν ) η ], ψ t (a, η, ε) = E [ g t ( a, η, ε, ν ) ε ], where ϕ t (a, η, ε) and ψ t (a, η, ε) reflect the transmission of the persistent and transitory earnings components, respectively. They generalize the partial insurance coefficients of BPP. Similar techniques can be used in the presence of advance information, consumption habits, and in cases where the consumption rule depends on lagged η, or when η follows a second-order Markov process, see Section 3 in ABB. The framework allows for additional, unobserved heterogeneity in earnings and consumption. Households can also differ in their initial productivity η and initial assets. IV. Data and Estimation The PSID went through a redesign in the late 99s, introducing new consumption and asset modules. Since 999 it collects some 7 percent of consumption expenditures, and more than 9 percent since 25. We use the sum of food at home, food away from home, gasoline, health, transportation, utilities, etc. We also make use of the more detailed asset data, see Blundell, Pistaferri, and Saporta-Eksten (26). For comparison we use family earnings data from administrative records in the Norwegian population registers, see Blundell, Graber, and Mogstad (25). 2 The results we present on the PSID use data from the 999 29 surveys. Assets holdings are the sum of financial assets, real estate value, pension funds, and car value, net of mortgages and other debt. Income y it are residuals of log total pretax household labor earnings on a set of demographics cohort and calendar time dummies, family size and composition, education, race, and state dummies. Log consumption c it is also a residual, using the same set of 2 The Norwegian results are part of the project on Labor Income Dynamics and the Insurance from Taxes, Transfers and the Family. See ABB Appendix C. demographics as for earnings. Following BPS, we select married male heads aged between 25 and 59. We focus on a subsample of 792 households. The conditional quantile function for the permanent income factor η it, given η i, t, is specified as Q t ( η t, τ) = Q( η t, ag e t, τ) K = a Q k (τ) φ k ( η t, ag e t ), k= where φ k, k =,,..., K, are polynomials (Hermite). Similarly for ε it, etc. The consumption (log) function, g( a t, η t, ε t, ag e t ), is specified as a flexible polynomial in assets, permanent income factor, the transitory shock and age, g t is additive in ν it. Estimation takes place in two steps, see ABB for details. The first step recovers estimates of the income parameters. The second step recovers estimates of the consumption parameters, given an estimate of the income parameters. The estimation algorithm alternates between draws of latent variables from candidate posteriors and quantile regressions using those draws, see also Arellano and Bonhomme (26). V. Empirical Results Figure provides our initial evidence for nonlinear income dynamics. It presents estimates of the average derivative of the conditional quantile function of y it given y i, t with respect to y i, t for both the PSID in panel A, and the Norwegian register data in panel B. These are evaluated at percentiles of the shock τ shock and at a value of y i, t that corresponds to the τ init percentile of the distribution of y i, t. The estimates in Figure display distinct and systematic nonlinearity. The persistence of income shocks is much lower for large negative (positive) shocks for high (low) initial incomes. The results for the PSID are confirmed in panel B for the Norwegian data. Turning to the income model, Figure 2, panel A provides estimates of the average derivative of the conditional quantile function of the persistent income factor η it on η i, t with respect to η i, t, evaluated at percentile τ shock and at a value of η i, t that corresponds to the τ init percentile of the distribution of η i, t. The estimates AQ P2849.indd 3 2/2/8 9:5 AM

4 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 28 Panel A. log earnings in the PSID data Panel A. Persistent component η it.2.8.6.8.6.8.6.2.8.6.8.6.8.6 Panel B. log earnings in the Norwegian administrative data Panel B. Earnings, nonlinear model.2.8.6.8.6.8.6 Figure. Quantile Autoregressions Notes: Residuals y it of log pretax household labor earnings, Age 25 6 999 29 (United States), Age 25 6 25 26 (Norway). Estimates of the average derivative of the conditional quantile function of y it given y i,t with respect to y i,t. Quantile functions are specified as third-order Hermite polynomials. Source: Arellano, Blundell, and Bonhomme (27).2.8.6.8.6 Figure 2. Nonlinear.6.8 Notes: PSID data. Panel A shows estimates of the average derivative of the conditional quantile function of η it on η i,t with respect to η i,t, based on estimates from the nonlinear earnings model. Panel B is based on data simulated according to our nonlinear earnings model with parameters set to their estimated values. Source: Arellano, Blundell, and Bonhomme (27) are evaluated at mean age in the sample. Panel B in Figure 2 is based on data simulated according to our nonlinear earnings model with parameters set to their estimated values. It shows a close accordance with the persistence in the PSID income data, see panel A of Figure. Moving to the estimated consumption model, Figure 3 displays the average derivative of the conditional mean of c it given y it, a it, and ag e it with respect to y it, evaluated at values of a it and ag e it corresponding to their τ assets and τ age percentiles, and averaged over the values of y it. It shows consumption responses vary systematically with age and assets and in a way that accords with standard life-cycle theory. It also shows a clear accordance between the consumption model and data. Finally, we provide preliminary evidence that the nonlinear persistence we have uncovered in family earnings data is also evident in hourly P2849.indd 4 2/2/8 9:5 AM

VOL. 8 NONLINEAR PERSISTENCE AND PARTIAL INSURANCE 5 Panel A. PSID data, by assets and age Panel A. Wages, PSID Consumption response.5.3..6.8 Percentile τ age.8.6 Percentile τ assets.2.8.6.8.6.8.6 Panel B. Nonlinear model, by assets and age Panel B. component η it Consumption response.5.3..6 Percentile τ age.8.8.6 Percentile τ assets.2.8.6.8.6.6.8 Figure 3. Consumption Responses to y it Note: Estimates from PSID of the average derivative of the conditional mean of c it given y it, a it, and age it with respect to y it, evaluated at values of a it and age it corresponding to their τ assets and τ age percentiles, and averaged over the values of y it. Source: Arellano, Blundell, and Bonhomme (27) wage data. Figure 4, panel A, presents estimates of nonlinear persistence in PSID male hourly earnings. Panel B provides the estimates of the average derivative of the conditional quantile function of the component η from the nonlinear model. These results show an important role for unusual shocks and nonlinear persistence in hourly wage data, suggesting nonlinear persistence may be a key feature for life-cycle models of family labor supply. Figure 4. Nonlinear, Hourly Wages Notes: Log male hourly wages, Age 3 6 PSID 999 29 (United States). Estimates of the average derivative of the conditional quantile function. Source: Authors calculations VI. Summary and Conclusions We have outlined a new framework for income dynamics and the nonlinear transmission of income shocks to consumption. We have exploited important new measurements for consumption and assets in the PSID. We have also shown the complementarities between big administrative data, e.g., Norwegian registers, and purpose-designed panel surveys, like the PSID. P2849.indd 5 2/2/8 9:5 AM

6 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 28 A Markovian permanent-transitory model of household income, which reveals asymmetric persistence of unusual shocks, is shown to accord well with the persistence of income in the PSID and in Norwegian register data. An age-dependent nonlinear consumption rule as a function of assets, permanent income, and transitory income is also applied to the PSID and shown to generate new empirical measures of the degree of partial insurance. We also find nonlinearities in the dynamics of individual male wages in the PSID, suggesting a role for nonlinear persistence in dynamic family labor supply, e.g., Blundell, Pistaferri, and Saporta-Eksten (26) and Heathcote, Storesletten, and Violante (24). In future work it would be useful to examine firm-tofirm transitions, the role of housing equity, and the importance of health and other (partially insured) shocks. A final word to the PSID: congratulations at 5 and looking forward to the next 5 years! REFERENCES Arellano, Manuel, and Stéphane Bonhomme. 26. Nonlinear Panel Data Estimation via Quantile Regressions. Econometrics Journal 9 (3): C6 94. Arellano, Manuel, Richard Blundell, and Stéphane Bonhomme. 27. Earnings and Consumption Dynamics: A Nonlinear Panel Data Framework. Econometrica 85 (3): 693 734. Blundell, Richard, Michael Graber, and Magne Mogstad. 25. Labor Income Dynamics and the Insurance from Taxes, Transfers, and the Family. Journal of Public Economics 27: 58 73. Blundell, Richard, Hamish Low, and Ian Preston. 23. Decomposing Changes in Income Risk Using Consumption Data. Quantitative Economics 4 (): 37. Blundell, Richard, Luigi Pistaferri, and Ian Preston. 28. Consumption Inequality and Partial Insurance. American Economic Review 98 (5): 887 92. Blundell, Richard, Luigi Pistaferri, and Itay Saporta-Eksten. 26. Consumption Inequality and Family Labor Supply. American Economic Review 6 (2): 387 435. Guvenen, Fatih, and Anthony A. Smith. 24. Inferring Labor Income Risk and Partial Insurance from Economic Choices. Econometrica 82 (6): 285 29. Heathcote, Jonathan, Kjetil Storesletten, and Giovanni L. Violante. 24. Consumption and Labor Supply with Partial Insurance: An Analytical Framework. American Economic Review 4 (7): 275 26. Krueger, Dirk, and Fabrizio Perri. 26. Does Income Inequality Lead to Consumption Inequality? Evidence and Theory. Review of Economic Studies 73 (): 63 93. P2849.indd 6 2/2/8 9:5 AM

AUTHOR QUERIES 7 AUTHOR, PLEASE ANSWER ALL QUERIES (numbered with AQ in the margin of the page). AQ# Question Response. The sentence beginning Similarly for... is incomplete. P2849.indd 7 2/2/8 9:5 AM