Employment Effects of Reducing Capital Gains Tax Rates in Ohio. William Melick Kenyon College. Eric Andersen American Action Forum

Similar documents
Success Taxes, Entrepreneurial Entry, and Innovation. William M. Gentry and R. Glenn Hubbard * This Draft: April 30, 2004

Do Domestic Chinese Firms Benefit from Foreign Direct Investment?

Federal Tax Policy and Charitable Giving: Revisiting the 1985 Study by Charles T. Clotfelter

THE DESIGN OF THE INDIVIDUAL ALTERNATIVE

Nonprofit organizations are becoming a large and important

Grandstanding and Venture Capital Firms in Newly Established IPO Markets

Do Social Insurance Taxes Hinder Entrepreneurial Activity? *

SPECIAL REPORT. The Corporate Income Tax and Workers Wages: New Evidence from the 50 States

Venture Capital Flows: Does IT Sector Investment Diminish Investment in Other Industries

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CHARITABLE BEQUESTS AND TAXES ON INHERITANCES AND ESTATES: AGGREGATE EVIDENCE FROM ACROSS STATES AND TIME

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

Tentative Lessons from the Recent Disinflationary Effort

Does the Equity Market affect Economic Growth?

State of Oklahoma Incentive Evaluation Commission Capital Gains Deduction

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TAX EVASION AND CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION. James M. Poterba. Working Paper No. 2119

Omitted Variables Bias in Regime-Switching Models with Slope-Constrained Estimators: Evidence from Monte Carlo Simulations

An Analysis of the Effect of State Aid Transfers on Local Government Expenditures

The Relationship Between Household Size, Real Wages, and Labor Force Participation Rates of Men and Women

Comparison of OLS and LAD regression techniques for estimating beta

Capital Gains Taxes and Realizations: Evidence from a Long Panel of State-Level Data

The Stock Market Crash Really Did Cause the Great Recession

Lottery Purchases and Taxable Spending: Is There a Substitution Effect?

The Truth on Spending: How the Federal and State Governments Measure Up Heather Winnor, Elon College

Statistical Evidence and Inference

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan;

Interest groups and investment: A further test of the Olson hypothesis

TAXES AND WAGE GROWTH. William M. Gentry Williams College and NBER. and. R. Glenn Hubbard Columbia University and NBER.

Capital Gains Realizations of the Rich and Sophisticated

Transportation Performance Index. Key Findings

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CLIMATE POLICY AND VOLUNTARY INITIATIVES: AN EVALUATION OF THE CONNECTICUT CLEAN ENERGY COMMUNITIES PROGRAM

Investment and Taxation in Germany - Evidence from Firm-Level Panel Data Discussion

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK

Open Access Analysis of the Relationship Between Industry Concentration and GDP Growth: China s Property Insurance Industry

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus)

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Internet Appendix for: Does Going Public Affect Innovation?

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research. Volume Title: Tax Policy and the Economy, Volume 20

Supply and Demand of Venture Capital in the U. S.

MONEY, PRICES, INCOME AND CAUSALITY: A CASE STUDY OF PAKISTAN

Output and Unemployment

Average Earnings and Long-Term Mortality: Evidence from Administrative Data

Olivier Blanchard. July 7, 2003

The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving. James P. Dow, Jr.

Chapter 4 Level of Volatility in the Indian Stock Market

1) The Effect of Recent Tax Changes on Taxable Income

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

Investors seeking access to the bond

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality

Weekly Options on Stock Pinning

The incidence of the inclusion of food at home preparation in the sales tax base

HEALTH REFORM, HEALTH INSURANCE, AND SELECTION: ESTIMATING SELECTION INTO HEALTH INSURANCE USING THE MASSACHUSETTS HEALTH REFORM

State Taxes and Manufacturing Productivity: A Case Study of Arkansas

POLICY BRIEF: THE INTERACTION BETWEEN IRAS AND 401(K) PLANS IN SAVERS PORTFOLIOS

Exchange Rate Exposure and Firm-Specific Factors: Evidence from Turkey

The data definition file provided by the authors is reproduced below: Obs: 1500 home sales in Stockton, CA from Oct 1, 1996 to Nov 30, 1998

The Economic Impact of Right to Work Policy in West Virginia

Economic Freedom and Government Efficiency: Recent Evidence from China

Estimating the Impact of Changes in the Federal Funds Target Rate on Market Interest Rates from the 1980s to the Present Day

The Variability of IPO Initial Returns

Tax audit impact on voluntary compliance

Factors that Affect Potential Growth of Canadian Firms

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EFFECT OF FEDERAL TAX DEDUCTIBILITY ON STATE AND LOCAL TAXES AND SPENDING. Gilbert Metcalf. Working Paper No.

Empirical Methods for Corporate Finance. Panel Data, Fixed Effects, and Standard Errors

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves

Further Evidence on the Performance of Funds of Funds: The Case of Real Estate Mutual Funds. Kevin C.H. Chiang*

The Elasticity of Taxable Income During the 1990s: A Sensitivity Analysis

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Is Foreign Direct Investment Sensitive to Taxes?

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

Threshold cointegration and nonlinear adjustment between stock prices and dividends

MIT Sloan School of Management

Master of Arts in Economics. Approved: Roger N. Waud, Chairman. Thomas J. Lutton. Richard P. Theroux. January 2002 Falls Church, Virginia

Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics

Does a Bias in FOMC Policy Directives Help Predict Inter-Meeting Policy Changes? * John S. Lapp. and. Douglas K. Pearce

Yafu Zhao Department of Economics East Carolina University M.S. Research Paper. Abstract

UNDER THE U.S. WORLDWIDE TAX SYSTEM, U.S.-

The Impact of Foreign Direct Investment on the Export Performance: Empirical Evidence for Western Balkan Countries

BESSH-16. FULL PAPER PROCEEDING Multidisciplinary Studies Available online at

THE IMPORTANCE OF MEASUREMENT ERROR IN THE COST OF CAPITAL. Austan Goolsbee University of Chicago, GSB American Bar Foundation, and NBER

Yale ICF Working Paper No March 2003

In July 1991, Illinois enacted a limit on the growth rate of

Nonlinearities and Robustness in Growth Regressions Jenny Minier

CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND THE 2003 TAX CUTS Richard H. Fosberg

INFORMATION EFFICIENCY HYPOTHESIS THE FINANCIAL VOLATILITY IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC CASE

Credit Market Consequences of Credit Flag Removals *

Chapter URL:

An Empirical Research on Chinese Stock Market Volatility Based. on Garch

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

The Effect of State Taxes on the Geographical Location of Top Earners: Evidence from Star Scientists

A pril 15. It causes much anxiety, with

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

Cato Institute Policy Analysis No. 39: Indexation and the Inflation Tax

The Vasicek adjustment to beta estimates in the Capital Asset Pricing Model

ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND TAXATION: RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN THE CORPORATE TAX RATE AND THE NEW BUSINESS FORMATION IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC

GROWTH DETERMINANTS IN LOW-INCOME AND EMERGING ASIA: A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS

ONLINE APPENDIX (NOT FOR PUBLICATION) Appendix A: Appendix Figures and Tables

Transcription:

Employment Effects of Reducing Capital Gains Tax Rates in Ohio William Melick Kenyon College Eric Andersen American Action Forum June 2011

Executive Summary Entrepreneurial activity is a key driver of job creation, and entrepreneurs and their financiers are especially sensitive to capital gains taxes. As a result, a cut in the capital gains tax rate should be expected to stimulate job creation to some degree. We measure the magnitude of this effect by examining the treatment of capital gains across the 50 states over roughly the past 40 years. Our results suggest that a complete elimination of the taxation of capital gains realized by Ohio taxpayers would lead to the creation of 40,000 new jobs. Applying this estimate to proposals currently under discussion suggests a somewhat smaller effect. 1

Introduction Few would dispute the notion that entrepreneurship is a key to economic growth (See, for example, Baumol, Litan and Schramm (2007)) and there is a substantial body of theory and evidence, summarized in Gentry (2010), that links entrepreneurial activity to the taxation of capital gains. Researchers have documented a variety of ways in which reductions in capital gains tax rates make it easier for entrepreneurs to conduct business, whether the reductions mitigate the asymmetric taxing of profits as opposed to losses (Gentry (2010)), lower the cost of capital obtained through initial public offerings (Guenter and Willenborg (1999)) or reduce distortions associated with firms remaining privately held to avoid taxes (Calvacanti and Erosa (2007)). Given the strong link between capital gains taxation and entrepreneurial behavior, policy makers have often reduced capital gains tax rates to spur economic activity, in particular investment and job creation. Unfortunately, the literature has not kept pace with policy, offering little guidance on the magnitude of gains in investment or employment that might be expected from a cut in capital gains tax rates. We partially fill this void by providing empirical evidence on the change in employment that might be expected from a reduction in capital gains tax rates. By exploiting the difference in capital gains tax rates across the fifty states, as well as the fact that nearly a dozen states changed their tax rates on capital gains during the last decade, we are able to come up with a robust estimate regarding the effects of capital gains tax rates on job creation. We find conclusive evidence that high capital gains taxes reduce job creation, and estimate that Ohio s proposed legislation that would eliminate the tax entirely for most of the state s taxpayers would be expected to create roughly 40,000 jobs. I. Capital Gains Taxation and Economic Activity Following the changes in the federal taxation of capital gains during the 1980s, much empirical academic work focused on the relationship between capital gains tax rates and revenues. That literature is nicely summarized by Bogart and Gentry (1995) who find, in agreement with most other authors, that reductions in capital gains tax rates do not lead to increases in capital gains tax revenues. Their work is 2

important in that they are the first to use variations in the tax treatment of capital gains across states to help identify the effects of changes in capital gains tax rates. Other authors have made use of the variation in states treatment of capital gains to answer broader questions regarding the effect of capital gains rate cuts on economic activity. Gompers and Lerner (1998) find that entrepreneurial activity is sensitive to the taxation of capital gains. In particular, they find that a reduction in capital gains tax rates is associated with an increase in venture capital funding in a state consistent with the hypothesis that a lower capital gains tax rate encourages entrepreneurs to obtain venture capital funding to start their businesses. Gentry (2010) updates and confirms these findings. It does appear that the tax treatment of capital gains is an important factor in entrepreneurial activity. Gentry and Hubbard (2003) find that asymmetries in taxation are important considerations in whether individuals become self-employed or actively manage a business. Cullen and Gordon (2007) argue that cutting the capital gains tax rate would encourage entrepreneurial activity. Finally, Gentry (2010) uses the Federal Reserve s triennial Survey of Consumer Finance dataset to document the importance of actively managed business assets in household portfolios. Previous work based on IRS data on capital gains realizations, for example Auerbach (2007), gave the impression that entrepreneurial assets are a small part of the capital gains tax base. Gentry (2010 page 14) documents that this in fact is not the case, since Total unrealized capital gains on active business assets are almost six times larger than the total unrealized capital gains on directly-held stock. Clearly, there is scope for tax policy to influence entrepreneurial decision making. Somewhat surprisingly, there are no attempts of which we are aware to relate changes in the taxation of capital gains to job creation. We take two approaches in an initial effort to understand capital gains taxation and employment. First, we construct a careful statistical exercise that takes advantages of state variation in the treatment of capital gains, a la Bogart and Gentry (1995), Gompers and Lerner (1998) and Gentry (2010), to identify the effect of a cut in the capital gains tax rate on employment. Second, as an informal cross-check, we simply compare employment in states that offer preferential 3

treatment for capital gains to those that do not. Both methods yield consistent results suggesting that a reduction in capital gains tax rates will boost employment. II. Formal Regression Analysis To conduct our formal analysis we need a measure of the capital gains tax rate by state for a number of years. There are two gold standard datasets available for this purpose. The first makes use of the work of Bakija (2009) while the second is taken from the TAXSIM model hosted at the National Bureau of Economic Research and described in Feenberg and Coutts (1993). Bakija calculates the combined federal and state capital gains tax rate faced by a taxpayer with income greater than 200,000 constant 2007 dollars for each state for every year from 1969 through 2007. The data from TAXSIM is an update of the method used by Gompers and Lerner (1998) to calculate the combined capital gains tax rate from 1978 through 2009 based on taxpayers with more than 500,000 in constant dollars of income. 1 For the years of overlap, the two methods report capital gains tax rates that are quite similar, differing on average by less than 0.63 percentage points. To the two tax rate variables we also add variables measuring private employment by state from 1969 through 2009 and total population by state from 1969 through 2009. Table 1 presents summary statistics for the dataset. Private employment in the 50 states and the District of Columbia averages a bit more than 2.1 million in our sample. As measured by the TAXSIM data, combined state and federal capital gains tax rates range from a low of 15.35 percent in the nine states that did not tax income in 2008 and 2009 to a high of 39.20 percent in New York in 1977. Our regression specification is given by equation (1) 1 ln PrivEmp ln Pop CapGainRate Y s i, t 0 1 i, t 2 i, t t t i i, t t 1 where represents the change in the variable from the preceding year, i indexes the i th state and t indexes the t th year and Yt is a dummy variable that takes the value 1 in year t and 0 otherwise. That is, in T 1 Details on this TAXSIM calculation are available at http://www.nber.org/~taxsim/state-rates/. 4

this specification the change in private employment in a state for a given year is driven by changes in population in that state and year, changes in the capital gains tax rate in that state and year, and unspecified U.S. economy-wide developments in that year. The coefficient of interest is 2, where a negative value would indicate that a cut in the capital gains tax rate would increase private employment. We use a difference specification to avoid any problems with non-stationary variables and we allowed for up to three lags on each of the variables before arriving at this preferred specification. The log-linear specification is standard in the literature in part as it offers a natural interpretation of how a percentage point change in the capital gains tax rate translates into a percentage change in the variable of interest, in our case employment. We do not include many control variables as the main point of the regression is not to provide a complete explanation of the evolution of private employment but rather to focus on the effect of the capital gains tax rate on employment. The absence of control variables is only problematic if an omitted variable happens to be highly correlated with the changes in the capital gains tax rate. Given the inclusion of dummy variables for each year and a choice as to the treatment of the individual state effects, the s i, we do not think the estimate for 2 is likely to suffer from omitted variables bias. When estimating equation (1), we must decide how to treat the term s i. In a fixed effects estimation, this term captures the unique, time-invariant features of state i, for example its geography, its history of policies and regulation and so on. In a random effects estimation s i is treated as part of a composite error-term along with it, - a random perturbation that is shared by all years observed for a given state. Finally, in a pooled Ordinary Least Squares estimation, s i is ignored. Fixed effects estimation estimates each state s si in order to control for possible correlation between si and the capital gains tax rate in state i that might bias the estimate of 2. Random effects estimation accounts for the correlation across time in a state s error term, treating si as an unknown random perturbation that cannot be estimated but that is shared in common across all years for a given state. 5

The top panel of Table 2 presents estimates for 2 from equation 1 across all three treatments and using both the Bajika and TAXSIM tax rates. In all cases, standard errors are calculated using methods that are robust to clustering by state. As can be seen, the estimate of 2 is remarkably consistent regardless of the estimation method or capital gain tax rates used. Statistical significance is largest for the Bakija given its longer sample. The uniformity of results is reassuring, providing a measure of confidence in the findings. The bottom panel of Table 2 then translates these estimated coefficients on capital gains tax rates into estimated numbers of new jobs created in Ohio if the state tax on capital gains were completely eliminated, that is dropped from the current 5.9 percent to 0.0 percent. These estimates are determined by the log-linear specification in equation (1). We envision the capital gains rate falling by 5.9 percentage points, multiply this decrease by the estimated 2 coefficient, and then translate the effect from the change in the natural logarithm of employment to the change in employment. Reading across the last row in the bottom panel of Table 2 we arrive at the conclusion that exempting capital gains from the Ohio income tax would likely increase private employment in Ohio by somewhere in the neighborhood of 40,000 jobs. Given current private employment in Ohio of over 5.5 million, this amounts to a 0.7 percent increase in private employment. III. Informal Numerical Analysis As a cross-check on the formal econometric analysis, we also compare the evolution of private employment over the past 20 years in states with preferential capital gains treatment to those states with no preferential treatment, excluding those states that do not tax income. That is, we split the incometaxing states and the District of Columbia into groups based on whether or not they taxed capital gains as regular income or gave them special breaks and then averaged normalized employment (1990 = 100) for the two groups in each year. As can be seen in Figure 1, private employment has grown much more rapidly in the nine states providing preferential capital gains treatment [AR, HI, MT, NM, ND, RI, SC, VT, and WI] than in the other 33 income-taxing states. Ohio s employment history is also shown; unfortunately it lags behind both the state averages. Obviously, this informal method does not offer the 6

controls or the measures of statistical reliability as in our formal method, but it does provide a nice crosscheck or reality check to our employment estimate. The statistical work would have little credibility had it been the case that private employment grew more slowly in states that provided capital gains preferences. IV. Calibrating to Current Proposals The estimates shown in Table 2 are predicated on the complete elimination of the taxation of capital gains in Ohio. However, policy proposals currently under discussion are more complicated, involving limits on the size of the capital gain that is exempt from taxes as well as restrictions on the uses to which the capital gains realization are put. These subtleties make it even more difficult to estimate the impact of the changes on private employment in Ohio. Tabulations from the 2007 Survey of Consumer Finance presented in Gentry (2010) show that the mean unrealized capital gain for households with active business assets (his definition of entrepreneurs) amounts to roughly $730,000 with a median unrealized gain of $45,000. This large discrepancy between the mean and median values suggests some very large unrealized capital gains, likely well above the proposed $10 million threshold. 2 While home bias in portfolios may be commonplace across international borders, it is unlikely that investors have much of a home bias across state borders. This suggests that the restrictions on the use to which the realized capital gains may be put will also likely bind. Clearly any prudent approach would trim the employment effects found in Table 2. 2 Unfortunately, Gentry (2010) does not provide any data on the distribution of the unrealized capital gains. 7

References Bakija, Jon (2009) Documentation for a Comprehensive Historical U.S. Federal and State Income Tax Calculator Program mimeo Williams College Department of Economics. Available at: http://web.williams.edu/economics/papers/bakijadocumentation_inctaxcalc.pdf Baumal, William J., Robert E. Litan, and Carl J. Schramm (2007) Good Capitalism, Bad Capitalism, and the Economics of Growth and Prosperity New Haven CT, Yale University Press Bogart, William T. and William M. Gentry (1995) Capital Gains Taxes and Realizations: Evidence from Interstate Comparisons Review of Economics Statistics 77(2) pp. 267-82. Cavalcanti, Ricardo de O. and Andres Erosa (2007) A Theory of Capital Gains Taxation and Business Turnover Economic Theory 32 pp. 477-496. Cullen, Julie Berry and Roger H. Gordon (2007) Taxes and Entrepreneurial Risk-taking: Theory and Evidence for the United States Journal of Public Economics 91(7-8) pp. 1479-1505 Feenberg, Daniel and Elisabeth Coutts (1993) "An Introduction to the TAXSIM Model" Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 12(1) pp. 189-94. Gentry, William M (2010) Capital Gains Taxation and Entrepreneurship mimeo, Williams College Department of Economics, November Gentry, William M. and R. Glenn Hubbard (2004) Entrepreneurship and Household Saving Advances in Economic Analysis and Policy 4(1) article 8. Available at : http://www/bepress.com/bejeap/advances/vol4/iss1/art8 Gompers, Paul A. and Josh Lerner (1998) What Drives Venture Capital Fundraising? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, pp. 149-204 Guenter, David and Michael Willenborg (1999) Capital Gains Tax Rates and the Cost of Capital for Small Businesses: Evidence From the IPO Market Journal of Financial Economics pp. 385-408. 8

Figure 1 9

Table 1 Descriptive Statistics Observations Average Std. Deviation Minimum Maximum State Private Employment 2091 2169092 2489562 72272 18013866 State Population 2091 4928771 5456232 296000 36961664 Combined State and Federal 1683 26.03 5.78 15.35 39.20 Capital Gains Tax Rate (TAXSIM) Combined State and Federal Capital Gains Tax Rate (Bakija) 1989 25.25 5.19 17.05 36.84 Table 2 Estimation Results and Job Estimate Bakija Tax Rates TAXSIM Tax Rates Fixed Random Pooled Fixed Random Pooled Effects Effects OLS Effects Effects OLS Coefficient -0.00128-0.00127-0.00130-0.00115-0.00104-0.00103 t-statistic -1.90-1.79-1.73-1.37-1.23-1.16 Significance Level 6.4% 7.4% 8.4% 17.7% 21.7% 24.7% Observations 1938 1938 1938 1581 1581 1581 Change in Ohio Tax Rate -5.9-5.9-5.9-5.9-5.9-5.9 Percentage Change in Private 0.76% 0.75% 0.77% 0.68% 0.62% 0.61% Employment New Jobs 41998 41639 42722 37631 34130 33785 10