Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures

Similar documents
4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Lecture Notes on Discrete-time Finance. Chuanshu Ji

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

No-arbitrage Pricing Approach and Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

European Contingent Claims

( 0) ,...,S N ,S 2 ( 0)... S N S 2. N and a portfolio is created that way, the value of the portfolio at time 0 is: (0) N S N ( 1, ) +...

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

Introduction to Financial Mathematics and Engineering. A guide, based on lecture notes by Professor Chjan Lim. Julienne LaChance

Compulsory Assignment

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Arbitrage Pricing. What is an Equivalent Martingale Measure, and why should a bookie care? Department of Mathematics University of Texas at Austin

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

CHAPTER 2 Concepts of Financial Economics and Asset Price Dynamics

Forward Risk Adjusted Probability Measures and Fixed-income Derivatives

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

CLAIM HEDGING IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Lecture 1 Definitions from finance

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO. Faculty of Mathematics and Natural Sciences

To have a concrete example in mind, suppose that we want to price a European call option on a stock that matures in six months.

Mean-Variance Hedging under Additional Market Information

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

Portfolio Choice. := δi j, the basis is orthonormal. Expressed in terms of the natural basis, x = j. x j x j,

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Help Session 2. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Two Equivalent Conditions

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance -

Forward Risk Adjusted Probability Measures and Fixed-income Derivatives

3. The Discount Factor

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

4 Option Futures and Other Derivatives. A contingent claim is a random variable that represents the time T payo from seller to buyer.

2 The binomial pricing model

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

A1: American Options in the Binomial Model

A Note on the No Arbitrage Condition for International Financial Markets

Citation: Dokuchaev, Nikolai Optimal gradual liquidation of equity from a risky asset. Applied Economic Letters. 17 (13): pp

4. Mathematical Finance in Discrete Time

Class Notes on Financial Mathematics. No-Arbitrage Pricing Model

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

3 Stock under the risk-neutral measure

Mathematical Finance in discrete time

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

CONSISTENCY AMONG TRADING DESKS

Finance: Lecture 4 - No Arbitrage Pricing Chapters of DD Chapter 1 of Ross (2005)

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited

Hedging and Pricing in the Binomial Model

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

2.1 A General Discrete-Time Market Model

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights?

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting.

One-Period Valuation Theory

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

Follow links for Class Use and other Permissions. For more information send to:

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

Financial Mathematics. Christel Geiss Department of Mathematics University of Innsbruck

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia

Pricing Kernel. v,x = p,y = p,ax, so p is a stochastic discount factor. One refers to p as the pricing kernel.

CHAPTER 2: STANDARD PRICING RESULTS UNDER DETERMINISTIC AND STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATES

Practice of Finance: Advanced Corporate Risk Management

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 3

Math 6810 (Probability) Fall Lecture notes

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Lecture Notes 1

ON THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ASSET PRICING. Dedicated to the memory of G. Kallianpur

X ln( +1 ) +1 [0 ] Γ( )

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach

Hedging Basket Credit Derivatives with CDS

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 10: Introduction to Game Theory 2

10.1 Elimination of strictly dominated strategies

Arbitrage and Pricing Theory

1 No-arbitrage pricing

Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

Some Computational Aspects of Martingale Processes in ruling the Arbitrage from Binomial asset Pricing Model

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE.

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

Transcription:

Lecture 3 Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures Several important concepts were illustrated in the example in Lecture 2: arbitrage; risk neutral probability measures; contingent claims such as call options; two different ways to price a contingent claim. Now begin our general studies on these topics. Lecture 3 contains two fundamental theorems of asset pricing. Theorem 3.1 concerns the equivalence between no arbitrage and existence of risk neutral probability measures; and Theorem 3.2 concerns the equivalence between market completeness and uniqueness of the risk neutral measure. We will demonstrate the valuation of a contingent claim by replicating portfolios or taking conditional expectations with respect to a risk neutral probability measure (or called an equivalent martingale measure). An arbitrage opportunity is said to exist if there is a self-financing strategy h whose value function satisfies (a) V (0) = 0; (b) V (T ) 0; (c) P (V (T ) > 0) > 0. Although a smart investor may seek and grab such a riskless way of making a profit, it would only be a transient opportunity. Once more investors and traders jump in to share the free lunch, prices of the securities would change immediately. Hence the old equilibrium would break down and be replaced by a new equilibrium, i.e. arbitrage opportunities would vanish. That is why we assume no arbitrage. It is also an implication of the efficient market hypothesis. Example 3.1 In the example in Lecture 2, suppose the constant interest rate is 8%. Then an arbitrage opportunity can be found easily. Just do nothing at t = 0 and t = 1, and short sell a number of shares of the stock (if allowed) at t = 2, deposit the proceeds in the bank account, close the short position at T = 3 (buy back the same number of shares of the stock and return them). This enables the investor to make a net profit at T = 3. (Convince yourself this strategy is self-financing and creates an arbitrage.) Example 3.2 Let the interest rate equal 7%. The situation is similar to but slightly more interesting than Example 3.1. Try to find an arbitrage strategy. 1

In general, it is not always easy to check directly whether an arbitrage opportunity exists. A useful criterion is given via equivalent martingale measures. Assume the framework in Section 2.1. A stochastic process X = {X(t), t = 0, 1,..., T } is called a martingale under a probability measure Q and with respect to a filtration F, if the conditional expectation E Q (X(t) F t 1 ) = X(t 1) t = 1,..., T. Sometimes we call X a Q-martingale. Theorem 3.1 (First Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing) No arbitrage there is a probability measure Q with Q(ω) > 0 ω Ω, such that every discounted price process Sn = {Sn(t), t = 0, 1,..., T } is a Q-martingale, n = 1,..., N. Such a measure Q is called an equivalent martingale measure (EMM). We follow the approach due to Harrison and Pliska given in their seminal paper (1981, Stoch. Proc. and Their Appl. 11, 215-260). Proof of sufficiency = This is an easy direction. It suffices to verify that {G (t)} is Q-martingale [so is {V (t)} by (2.11). Note that by (2.9), for every t = 1,..., T, the conditional expectation under Q is E [ G (t) F t 1 = N n=1 E [h n (t) S n(t) F t 1 = N n=1 h n (t) E [ S n(t) F t 1 The second equality follows from that h n is predictable, and the third equality is due to that S n is a martingale. It is useful to realize that for each n, the process X n (t) = t u=1 h n (u) S n(u) is also a martingale, as a result of the transform from the martingale {Sn(t)} via the predictable process h n. Proof of necessity = A contingent claim is a random variable Y that represents the payoff at time T from a seller (short position) to a buyer (long position). Recall that the sample space Ω = {ω 1,..., ω K }. Hence the set of possible values Y (ω 1 ),..., Y (ω K ) of a contingent claim Y can be considered as an element in IR K. Let G = {Y IR K, Y = G (T ) for some trading strategy h}; 2

A = {Y IR K, Y 0 and Y (ω) > 0 for some ω Ω}; and G = {Z IR K, Y Z = 0 Y G}. Note that G is a linear subspace of IR K (why?), and G is its orthogonal complement. A is the (closed) first quadrant (excluding the origin). No arbitrage implies G A =. Furthermore, let W = {Y IR K, Y 0, Y 1 +... + Y K = 1}, which is a closed convex subset of A. It follows from the Separating Hyperplane Theorem that there exists λ G such that λ Y > 0 for all Y W. (See Pliska s book p14 for further detail.) This implies λ(ω) > 0 for all ω Ω. Define a probability measure Q(ω) = λ(ω) ω λ(ω ), ω Ω. It follows from Q G that for any predictable process h, [ N T E Q n=1 t=1 Hence for every n and any predictable process h n, E Q [ T t=1 This implies that every Sn is a Q-martingale (why?). Notes: (a) The above λ is called a state price vector. More on this later. (b) Q is called an EMM because Q is equivalent to P, i.e. for every ω Ω, Q(ω) > 0 if and only if P (ω) > 0. 3.2 Risk neutral valuation of contingent claims and market completeness A contingent claim Y introduced in Section 3.1 is a contract between a seller and a buyer. Since the seller promises to pay the buyer the amount Y at time T, the buyer normally pays some money to the seller at a certain time t < T, when they make the agreement. 3

Q1: What is the appropriate time t value of this contingent claim Y? Is it well-defined? Assume no arbitrage. A contingent claim Y is said to be marketable or attainable if there exists a self-financing trading strategy h whose value at T satisfies V (T ) = Y. In this case, h is said to replicate or generate Y. Q2: Under what conditions on the market, every contingent claim is marketable? The next two subsections answer Q1 and Q2 respectively. 3.2.1 Law of one price and risk neutral valuation principle The law of one price is said to hold if there do not exist two trading strategies, say h and h with corresponding value processes denoted by {V (t)} and {V (t)}, such that V (T ) = V (T ) but V (t) V (t) for some t < T. In other words, if the law of one price holds, then there is no ambiguity about the time t value of any marketable claim at any time t. Proposition 3.1 No arbitrage = the law of one price holds. Proof By Theorem 3.1, there is an EMM Q such that all discounted price processes Sn, n = 1,..., N, thus the discounted value process {V (t)}, are Q-martingales. Hence Proposition 3.1 follows (why?). The converse of Proposition 3.1 is not necessarily true. Example 3.3 Revisit Example 3.2. With r 07, the equation (2.13) yields q = 1. In this case, there is a degenerate probability measure Q defined on Ω with Q(ω 1 ) = 1 and Q(ω k ) = 0 for all k 1. Note that Q is not an EMM. But we can still use the equation (2.14) to obtain all values. More generally, the law of one price remains true (why?). Exercise 3.1 Construct another counterexample in a single period model (T = 1). The following principle is the basis for asset pricing. Risk neutral valuation principle: Assuming no arbitrage, the time t value of a marketable contingent claim Y is equal to V (t), the time t value of the portfolio that replicates Y. Moreover, V (t) = E Q [Y/B(T ) F t, t = 0, 1,..., T (3.1) for any EMM Q. Exercise 3.2 Justify this principle. 4

3.2.2 Complete markets The example in Lecture 2 illustrates that for a given contingent claim Y, its marketability can be checked by solving a system of linear equations, step by step backwards. Such a tedious procedure is worthwhile because it yields a replicating portfolio when Y is marketable. Instead of dealing with each individual claim, an alternative approach is to define complete markets: a market is said to be complete if every claim in the market is attainable. A general criterion is: Theorem 3.2 (Second Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing) An arbitrage-free market is complete there is a unique EMM Q. Proof = Assuming completeness, every contingent claim Y satisfies Y = V (T ) for some selffinancing strategy h. Suppose Q 1 and Q 2 are two EMMs with the corresponding expectations denoted by E 1 ( ) and E 2 ( ). E 1 [Y/B(T ) = E 1 V (T ) = E 1 V (0) = V (0), (3.2) where the second equality is due to that {V (t)} is a Q 1 -martingale, and the last equality follows from F 0 = {, Ω}. By the same token, E 2 [Y/B(T ) = V (0). (3.3) Hence E 1 [Y/B(T ) = E 2 [Y/B(T ). This implies Q 1 = Q 2 since Y is arbitrary. = Assume the market is arbitrage-free but incomplete, and let C be the set of all marketable contingent claims. Note that C is a linear subspace of IR K. Thus there exists a contingent claim Y C, with respect to the inner product (X, Y ) = E Q (XY ) on IR K where Q is an EMM. Define Then Q (ω) = [ 1 + Y (ω) 2 sup ω Ω Y (ω) (i) Q is a probability measure since E Q Y = 0; (ii) Q (ω) > 0 ω and Q Q; Q(ω), ω Ω. (3.4) (iii) Q is an EMM because for every n and any predictable process h n, E Q [ T t=1 Exercise 3.3 Construct an example of arbitrage-free but incomplete single period model. 5