Gains from Trade and Comparative Advantage

Similar documents
Factor Endowments. Ricardian model insu cient for understanding objections to free trade.

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

International Economics Lecture 2: The Ricardian Model

Introduction. Countries engage in international trade for two basic reasons:

2. Find the equilibrium price and quantity in this market.

Answer: Let y 2 denote rm 2 s output of food and L 2 denote rm 2 s labor input (so

Topic 3: The Standard Theory of Trade. Increasing opportunity costs. Community indifference curves.

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade.

Problem Set 4 - Answers. Specific Factors Models

Understand general-equilibrium relationships, such as the relationship between barriers to trade, and the domestic distribution of income.

The Dynamic Heckscher-Ohlin Model: A diagrammatic analysis

Real Exchange Rate and Terms of Trade Obstfeld and Rogo, Chapter 4

Heckscher Ohlin Model

Technology and trade I

Problem Set I - Solution

MTA-ECON3901 Fall 2009 Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson or Model

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2011 Examination. 2010/2011 Syllabus ONLY

ECON Micro Foundations

Mean-Variance Analysis

Problems. units of good b. Consumers consume a. The new budget line is depicted in the figure below. The economy continues to produce at point ( a1, b

A Closed Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model

II. Competitive Trade Using Money

14.54 International Trade Lecture 8: Ricardian Trade Model

Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #7 - Competitive Markets

Endowment differences: The Heckscher-Ohlin model

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice

Labor productivity and Comparative advantage The Ricardian model

Review of Production Theory: Chapter 2 1

Department of Economics Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Intermediate Macroeconomics

Ricardian Model. Recaps. The Concept of. Comparative Advantage. Production Possibilities Frontier

Advanced Microeconomics

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality

Money in OLG Models. Econ602, Spring The central question of monetary economics: Why and when is money valued in equilibrium?

File: Ch03; Chapter 3: The Standard Theory of International Trade

EconS Firm Optimization

ECO 445/545: International Trade. Jack Rossbach Spring 2016

Winners and Losers from Price-Level Volatility: Money Taxation and Information Frictions

General Equilibrium and Economic Welfare

Factor endowments and trade I

EconS Constrained Consumer Choice

Optimal Progressivity

ECO 352 International Trade Spring Term 2010 Week 3 Precepts February 15 Introduction, and The Exchange Model Questions

Econ Homework 4 - Answers ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS OF CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION. 1. Assume that a rm produces product x using k and l, where

1. If the consumer has income y then the budget constraint is. x + F (q) y. where is a variable taking the values 0 or 1, representing the cases not

Chapter 6. The Standard Trade Model

Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default

The Heckscher-Ohlin model

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld

Lecture Notes 1

2. David Ricardo's model explains trade based on: A) labor supply. B) technology. C) population. D) government control.

Universidad Carlos III de Madrid May Microeconomics Grade

Economics 181: International Trade Midterm Solutions

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

1 Consumer Choice. 2 Consumer Preferences. 2.1 Properties of Consumer Preferences. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 4 of the text.

Solution Problem Set #1

Lecture 4 - Theory of Choice and Individual Demand

ECON* International Trade Winter 2011 Instructor: Patrick Martin

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 1-2: Uncompensated and Compensated Elasticities; Static and Dynamic Labor Supply

Chapter 10 3/19/2018. AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND (Part 1) Objectives. Aggregate Supply

Chapter 18 - Openness in Goods and Financial Markets

The Ricardian Model. Rafael López-Monti Department of Economics George Washington University Summer 2015 (Econ 6280.

Equilibrium Asset Returns

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts

14.54 International Trade Lecture 3: Preferences and Demand

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

Microeconomics I - Midterm

International Trade

1 Multiple Choice (30 points)

Lecture 12 International Trade. Noah Williams

Factor endowments and trade I (Part A)

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

Ricardian Model part 1

This appendix discusses two extensions of the cost concepts developed in Chapter 10.

Simple e ciency-wage model

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

Specific factors and Income Distribution

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

1 Supply and Demand. 1.1 Demand. Price. Quantity. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 2 of the text.

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 7 of the text.

Topic 4: Analysis of Equilibrium.

EconS Micro Theory I Recitation #8b - Uncertainty II

Preview. Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics

CHAPTER 2 FOUNDATIONS OF MODERN TRADE THEORY: COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE

Chapter 2: Gains from Trade. August 14, 2008

Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies

Some Problems. 3. Consider the Cournot model with inverse demand p(y) = 9 y and marginal cost equal to 0.

Lecture 15 - General Equilibrium with Production

Universidad Carlos III de Madrid June Microeconomics Grade

Practice Questions Chapters 9 to 11

This is The Heckscher-Ohlin (Factor Proportions) Model, chapter 5 from the book Policy and Theory of International Trade (index.html) (v. 1.0).

Chapter 5. The Standard Trade Model. Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop

Transcription:

Gains from Trade and Comparative Advantage 1 Introduction Central questions: What determines the pattern of trade? Who trades what with whom and at what prices? The pattern of trade is based on comparative advantage. What are the sources of gains from trade? How are the gains distributed across countries? There are always gains from trade, and both countries will gain from trade provided the relative price under free trade di ers from both country s relative prices under autarky. How does trade alter the structure of production and returns to factors within each country? Owners of a country s relatively scarce factor (associated with the import competing sector) will lose as a result of trade, even though the country as a whole gains.

2 Ricardian Model Start with the Ricardian model, where trade occurs due to technology di erences across countries, to illustrate comparative advantage and gains from trade. Explore distribution implications in the next chapter on factor endowment models. 2.1 Assumptions Two goods: cloth C and wheat W. Two countries: home and foreign * One factor: labor L, in xed supply and immobile across countries CRS technology: a Lj units of labor produce one unit of j 2 fc; W g

2.2 Comparative Advantage (CA) Home has comparative advantage over Foreign in wheat relative to cloth, Foreign has comparative advantage over Home in cloth relative to wheat a LW a LC < a LW a LC If a country has comparative advantage in a good, that country has a lower opportunity cost of producing that good than the other country. The opportunity cost of wheat a LW =a LC is how many units of cloth a country must stop producing in order to produce one more unit of wheat.

2.3 Production Possibilities Frontier (PPF) A country s PPF describes the maximal bundles of cloth and wheat that can be produced given factor supply and technology. The labor constraint restricts the sum of labor demands, labor used making cloth a LC S C and labor used making wheat a LW S W, in each country to not exceed total labor supply L. a LC S C + a LW S W = L S C = L a LC a LW a LC S W The opportunity cost of wheat in terms of cloth appears as (absolute value of) the slope of the PPF.

2.4 World PPF The world PPF describes the maximal bundles the world can produce. Paste together the PPFs for the two countries. Kink in the middle due to di erence in opportunity costs. The kink occurs where each country is specialized in its comparative advantage good. World PPF kinks outward. Home produces wheat rst, then foreign, in accordance with each country s comparative advantage. The country with comparative advantage in wheat should start producing wheat rst because producing an additional unit of wheat there requires less sacri ce of cloth than in the other country.

2.5 Example Given the technology Cloth Wheat Home a LC = 1 a LW = 1 Foreign a LC = 2 a LW = 6 Home has comparative advantage in wheat (and Foreign in cloth) a LW a LC = 1 < 3 = 6 2 = a LW a LC Given labor endowments L = 500 and L = 600, we construct each country s PPF as in Figure 1.1. S C + S W = 500 () S C = 500 2S C + 6S W = 600 () S C = 300 S W 3S W The world PPF is drawn in Figure 1.2.

Initially, foreign specializes in cloth S C = 300, S W = 0 and any increases in wheat occur according to home s PPF (S C = 500 S W ). Once home becomes specialized in wheat (S C = 0, S W = 500), any further increases in wheat must occur according to foreign s PPF S C = 300 3S W. The numbers in the above example are not special: as long as the opportunity costs di er across countries, there exists a basis for trade. Absolute advantage is not at all important; a country could have an absolute advantage (or disadvantage) in both goods and still gain from trade.

2.6 Relative Prices The relative price under free trade is found at the intersection of world relative supply (step function with steps at each country s opportunity cost of wheat in terms of cloth) RS = S W + S W S C + S C = 0 : : : L=a LW L=a LW L =a LC L =a LC, P W PC : : : 1, P W PC = a LW a LC = a LW a LC and relative demand (such as D W =D C = P C =P W ). The free trade relative price lies weakly between the two autarkic relative prices. a LW a LC P W P C a LW a LC Neither country would produce wheat if the relative price of wheat were lower than both opportunity costs of wheat. Likewise neither would produce cloth if the relative price of wheat exceeded both opportunity costs (because then the relative price of cloth would be below both opportunity costs of cloth).

2.7 Production Pattern E ciency in the world economy requires that at least one country specialize in its comparative advantage good. Three di erent cases can occur depending on parameters. If relative demand is particularly strong for one of the goods, the country that does not have comparative advantage in that good may remain remain incompletely specialized, and thus free trade relative price will not differ from its autarkic relative price (opportunity cost). The failure of the free trade relative price to di er from the autarky relative price for that country eliminates the opportunity to obtain the non-comparative advantage good through trade at a lower expense than producing it directly.

2.8 Trade Possibilities Frontier (TPF) A country s TPF describes the maximal consumption bundles under free trade. The TPF is a budget constraint based on the total value of a county s production bundle at the free trade relative price. The slope of the TPF is the free trade relative price. P w P C D W + D C = P w P C S W + S C D C = S C + P w P C (S W D W )

2.9 Trade Pattern The Ricardian model predicts the direction of trade: each country exports its comparative advantage good. Regardless of the pattern of production (a country may produce both goods or just its comparative advantage good), the pattern of trade is clear. Home exports wheat and imports cloth; foreign exports cloth and imports wheat. We need knowledge of relative demand to determine the exact volume of trade.

2.10 Gains From Trade Provided (and to the extent that) the free trade relative price di ers from autarkic relative price, a country (as a whole) gains from trade. In the Ricardian model, the condition for gains from trade is equivalent to saying a country gains whenever it becomes completely specialized in its comparative advantage good. Does each individual necessarily gain? No. A system of lump-sum taxes and subsidies is required to ensure that each individual can a ord the autarkic consumption bundle if individuals are not all alike.

3 National Income 3.1 Transformation Curve De nition 1 Factor supplies and technology determine the PPF (or transformation curve) S C = T (S W ) where S C denotes the supply of cloth and S W denotes the supply of wheat. In Figure A.1, C o denotes maximal production of cloth and W o denotes maximal production of wheat. The derivative of the PPF is negative, T 0 (S W ) @S C @S W < 0, since producing more wheat requires producing less cloth.

3.2 National Income Function At world prices denoted by P j, j 2 fc; W g, with vector of prices p (P W ; P C ), national income is the sum of income from producing cloth and wheat. y = P C S C + P W S W Budget line shows combinations of (S C ; S W ) that yield a given level of income y given prices p. Maximizing y subject to the constraint S C = T (S W ) yields the rst order condition P C ds C + P W ds W = 0 Assuming an interior solution, income is maximized by producing where the slope of the budget line equals the slope of the PPF. T 0 (S W ) ds C ds W = Otherwise, produce only cloth or only wheat. P W P C (1)

Denote by w o the slope of the PPF at maximal wheat production W o. Similarly, denote by c o the slope of the PPF at maximal cloth production C o. If P W PC > w o then the budget line is steeper than the PPF everywhere and the country specializes in wheat (produces no cloth). Similarly, if P W PC < c o then the budget line is atter than the PPF everywhere and the country specializes in cloth (produces no wheat). Finally, if c o < P W PC < w o the point of production is the tangency between the PPF and the budget line and the country makes both goods.

Let S (S W ; S C ) denote the production vector. De nition 2 The National Income Function (NIF) records the highest income attainable for a country under di erent circumstances y(p; : : :) = X i P i S i = p S where outputs are optimally chosen by competitive producers, given factor prices and goods prices. For the two good case, tangency between the budget line and the transforation curve determines the optimal production point.

3.3 NIF Properties Consider xing the price of cloth P C and varying the price of wheat P W. How national income changes depends upon the pattern of production. If P W < c o P C, the country produces no wheat so national income y(p; : : :) = P C C o is una ected. @y(p; : : :) @P W = 0; @2 y(p; : : :) @P 2 W = 0; P W < c o P C If P W > w o P C, the country produces only wheat so national income y(p; : : :) = P W W o increases with price of wheat. @y(p; : : :) @P W = W o ; @2 y(p; : : :) @P 2 W = 0; P W > w o P C

If c o P C < P W < w o P C, the country produces both goods and national income increases with price of wheat at an increasing rate. The derivative of the NIF with respect to the price of wheat P W equals the supply of wheat. Di erentiating the NIF with respect to the price of wheat and using the property that optimization in production requires that the slope of the PPF equal ratio of prices (1), an Envelope theorem, " @y(p; : : :) ds = S W + P C ds C + P W W @P W dp W dp {z W } 0 = S W > 0 so national income increases in the price of wheat. #

Since production of wheat increases with the price of wheat, national income increases at an increasing rate. @ 2 y(p; : : :) @P 2 W = @S W @P W > 0 In Figure A.2, the slope of y shows production of wheat S W since national income is plotted against the price of wheat. In autarky, what is produced is the same as what is consumed S W = D W, so the point of production where national income is maximized for at the autarky prices is also the point of consumption.

3.4 Ricardian Model Revisited What does the NIF look like in the Ricardian model? Recall that the PPF is linear in the Ricardian model. Maximal production of cloth is C o = a, maximal production of wheat is W o = and the (absolute LC value L a LW of the) slope of the PPF equals a LW a LC = c o = w o. The prices of wheat c o P C and w o P C that were distinct points above and below the autarky price of wheat collapse to the autarky price of wheat. L

As in Figure A.3, the NIF is a horizontal line until the price of wheat exceeds P A W = a LW a LC P C when the country switches from specializing in cloth to specializing in wheat. For prices of wheat above the autarky price P W > P A W, the NIF increases at a constant rate with the price of wheat all resources are allocated to wheat production so there can be no further increase in wheat production as the price of wheat rises. The kink means that at the critical price, any pattern of production yields the same income so that the slope of the NIF is unde ned.

4 National Expenditure 4.1 National Expenditure Function We assume the existence of community indi erence curves u(d C ; D W ). Total expenditure is sum of expenditures on cloth and wheat E = P C D C + P W D W where D C is consumption of cloth and D W is consumption of wheat.

Minimizing E subject to the constraint of providing at least a chosen level of utility (such as autarky), u (D C ; D W ) u A, or equivalently, maximizing utility for a chosen level of expenditure, yields rst order condition P C dd C + P W dd W = 0 so expenditure is minimized by consuming where slope of budget line equals slope of indi erence curve as in Figure A.4. dd C dd W = P W P C (2) De nition 3 The National Expenditure Function (NEF) records the minimum expenditure required to achieve a chosen level of utility for various prices E(p; u) = X i P i D i = p D are optimally chosen by con- where consumption D i sumers.

4.2 NEF Properties The partial derivative with respect to prices gives quantity consumed (envelope theorem) due to (2) @E(p; u) dd = D W + P C dd C + P W W @P W dp W dp W = D W > 0 " Furthermore, the expenditure function is concave in price @ 2 E(p; u) @P 2 W = @D W @P W < 0 because consumers substitute toward the cheaper good as the price of a good rises. # Expenditure increases as price increases but at a decreasing rate as in Figure A.5.

4.3 Autarkic Equilibrium The autarky equilibrium in the economy is given by the tangency of the NIF and the NEF. yielding an au- Consider an autarkic price of wheat PW A tarkic level of utility u A. National expenditure needed to achieve autarkic level of utility is E(p; u A ). National income is y(p; : : :). National income equals national expenditure at autarky prices y(p A ; : : :) = E(p A ; u A ) Quantity supplied equals the quantity demanded S A = D A

4.4 Free Trade Equilibrium Let u T represent the level of utility under free trade. Two conditions need to be satis ed in a free trade equilibrium: national income equals national expenditure in each country y(p T ; : : :) = E(p T ; u T ) y (p T ; : : :) = E (p T ; u T ) and the market for each good clears at the world level (world demand equals world supply). S + S = D + D

4.5 Gains From Trade Revisiting Figure A.5, for the autarky price of wheat P W = PW A, income equals expenditure y = E since autarkic supply equals autarkic demand S A = D A. Due to the curvature of the national expenditure and national income functions, national income exceeds national expenditure y > E for all prices di ering from the autarky price P W 6= P A W. Whenever free trade price di ers from autarky, national income is more than enough to yield autarkic level of utility. The gains are larger the more the price di ers from its autarkic level. A country can increase its utility by trading and thus gains from trade at the national level.

4.6 Comparative Advantage By the gains from trade, utility under free trade exceeds utility under autarky. Thus, the minimum expenditure required to reach the free trade level of utility at autarkic prices is higher than the minimum expenditure required to reach the autarkic level of utility at autarkic prices E(p A ; u T ) E(p A ; u A ) The expenditure function shifts up as in Figure A.6, yielding two intersections of the expenditure and the income functions.

At point B to the right of the tangency at point A, the slope of the y curve exceeds the slope of the E curve so the supply of wheat exceeds the demand of wheat and the country exports wheat X W S W D W > 0 Also, the national income y curve is steeper at point B than at point A so the supply of wheat S W has risen. At point C to the left of the tangency at point A, the slope of the E curve exceeds the slope of the y curve so the demand of wheat exceeds the supply of wheat and the country imports wheat M W D W S W > 0 Similarly, the national income y curve is atter at point C than at point A so the supply of wheat S W has fallen.

Whichever country exports wheat, the other country must be importing wheat (by the world demand equals world supply condition for a free trade equilibrium). Thus, if the home country is at an equilibrium such as point B where PW T > P W A, the foreign country must be at an equilibrium such as point C where PW T < P W A. Since the two countries share a common free trade price, by transitivity the free trade price must be in between the two autarky prices P A W > P T W > P A W so tangency of NIF and NEF under autarky for the home country lies to the left of the tangency under autarky for the foreign country. Thus, comparing the autarky prices predicts the pattern of trade: the country with the lower autarky price of wheat exports wheat under free trade.

For two countries and two goods, comparative advantage dictates: The free trade price lies between the two autarkic prices. Each country exports the good for which it has a lower autarkic price than the other country. Each country experiences a rise in the price of its comparative advantage good in the move from autarky to free trade. Each country expands the production of its comparative advantage good in the move from autarky to free trade.

4.7 General Gains from Trade Let p T denote the vector of free trade prices, S T and S A denote the free trade and autarkic vectors of output produced and let D A be the autarkic consumption vector. National income is higher at the free trade price when free trade supply is chosen than were the autarky supply chosen instead p T S T = y(p T ; : : :) p T S A The quantities supplied must equal the quantities demanded in autarky (by the de nition of an autarkic equilibrium) S A = D A Therefore, substituting autarkic demand for autarkic supply, national income is su cient to purchase the autarkic consumption bundle at free trade prices. p T S T p T D A Thus, the country gains from trade.

4.8 General Comparative Advantage Due to gains from trade, free trade must yield at least the autarkic level of utility p A D T E(p A ; u A ) = y(p A ; ) = p A S A (3) But the autarkic supplies must yield higher income at autarkic prices than the free trade supplies p A S A p A S T (4) Consequently, producing the free trade supplies would not yield enough income to a ord the free trade consumption bundle at autarky prices p A D T p A S T p A (D T S T ) 0 But under free trade, value of imports must equal that of exports p T (D T S T ) = 0

Proposition 4 A country s imports are positively correlated with lower trade prices relative to autarky: (p A p T )(D T S T ) 0: The same logic for the foreign country implies (p A p T )(D T S T ) 0 Since home country imports equal foreign country exports (D T S T ) = (S T D T ) (p T p A )(D T S T ) 0 Proposition 5 Imports are positively correlated with lower foreign autarkic prices relative to domestic: (p A p A )(D T S T ) 0: Finally, autarky supply is optimal at autarky prices p A S A = y(p A ; ) p A S T! p A S A S T 0 and free trade supply is optimal at free trade prices p T S T = y(p T ; ) p T S A! p T S T S A 0

Proposition 6 Output reductions are positively correlated with lower trade prices relative to autarky: (p A p T )(S A S T ) 0: General conclusion: Although comparative advantage may not hold on a commodity by commodity basis, it holds on average in a multi-commodity environment.