Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Similar documents
1 Two Period Exchange Economy

3 General Equilibrium in a Competitive Market

Trade on Markets. Both consumers' initial endowments are represented bythesamepointintheedgeworthbox,since

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box

Chapter 31: Exchange

A. Introduction to choice under uncertainty 2. B. Risk aversion 11. C. Favorable gambles 15. D. Measures of risk aversion 20. E.

ECON Micro Foundations

GE in production economies

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

EconS 301 Intermediate Microeconomics Review Session #4

Consumer Theory. The consumer s problem: budget set, interior and corner solutions.

Exchange. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory. Boston College. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory (BC) Exchange 1 / 23

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

3/1/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 4: Solving the Consumer s Problem. The Story So Far. Today s Aims. Solving the Consumer s Problem

Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 2 Consumer Behaviour 2.1 THE CONSUMER S BUDGET

Economics 201B Second Half. Lecture 4, 3/18/10

Barter Exchange and Core: Lecture 2

Module 2 THEORETICAL TOOLS & APPLICATION. Lectures (3-7) Topics

EconS Constrained Consumer Choice

MODULE No. : 9 : Ordinal Utility Approach

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

Master in Industrial Organization and Markets. Spring 2012 Microeconomics III Assignment 1: Uncertainty

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

Intro to Economic analysis

Chapter 2: Gains from Trade. August 14, 2008

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

The Robinson Crusoe model; the Edgeworth Box in Consumption and Factor allocation

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October Q1. Find the equation of the production possibility curve in the following 2 good, 2 input

EconS 301 Written Assignment #3 - ANSWER KEY

(a) Ben s affordable bundle if there is no insurance market is his endowment: (c F, c NF ) = (50,000, 500,000).

Review of Production Theory: Chapter 2 1

UNIT 1 THEORY OF COSUMER BEHAVIOUR: BASIC THEMES

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Gains from Trade. Rahul Giri

Exogenous variables are determined outside a macroeconomic model. Figure 5.1 A Model Takes Exogenous Variables and Determines Endogenous Variables

ECS2601 Oct / Nov 2014 Examination Memorandum. (1a) Raymond has a budget of R200. The price of food is R20 and the price of clothes is R50.

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001)

Uncertainty in Equilibrium

Chapter 5: Utility Maximization Problems

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

Lecture Notes on The Core

Lecture 2A: General Equilibrium

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

Practice Questions for Mid-Term Examination - I. In answering questions just consider symmetric and stationary allocations!

Solutions to problem set x C F = $50:000 + x x = $50: x = 10 9 (C F $50:000)

Economics 313: Intermediate Microeconomics II. Sample Final Examination. Version 1. Instructor: Dr. Donna Feir

Answers to June 11, 2012 Microeconomics Prelim

Graphs Details Math Examples Using data Tax example. Decision. Intermediate Micro. Lecture 5. Chapter 5 of Varian

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 3

Microeconomics: General Equilibrium Analysis

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

1. Suppose a production process is described by a Cobb-Douglas production function f(v 1, v 2 ) = v 1 1/2 v 2 3/2.

Intermediate Microeconomics EXCHANGE AND EFFICIENCY BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY

Introductory to Microeconomic Theory [08/29/12] Karen Tsai

Answer: Let y 2 denote rm 2 s output of food and L 2 denote rm 2 s labor input (so

Microeconomics IV. First Semster, Course

Midterm 2 (Group A) U (x 1 ;x 2 )=3lnx 1 +3 ln x 2

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Firm s Problem. Simon Board. This Version: September 20, 2009 First Version: December, 2009.

First Welfare Theorem in Production Economies

PAPER NO.1 : MICROECONOMICS ANALYSIS MODULE NO.6 : INDIFFERENCE CURVES

2 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing

Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

U(x 1, x 2 ) = 2 ln x 1 + x 2

2. Equlibrium and Efficiency

(Note: Please label your diagram clearly.) Answer: Denote by Q p and Q m the quantity of pizzas and movies respectively.

p 1 _ x 1 (p 1 _, p 2, I ) x 1 X 1 X 2

Pauline is considering becoming a member of a CD club, which offers discounts on CDs. There is a membership fee of 100 but then each CD is only 10.

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

The endowment of the island is given by. e b = 2, e c = 2c 2.

Chapter 2 Equilibrium and Efficiency

Solutions to Assignment #2

General Equilibrium and Economic Welfare

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

THE BOADWAY PARADOX REVISITED

Tools of normative analysis

Eliminating Substitution Bias. One eliminate substitution bias by continuously updating the market basket of goods purchased.

Chapter 3. A Consumer s Constrained Choice

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 2 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK!

Economics 200A part 2 UCSD Fall quarter 2010 Prof. R. Starr Mr. Ben Backes 1 FINAL EXAMINATION - SUGGESTED ANSWERS

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

If Tom's utility function is given by U(F, S) = FS, graph the indifference curves that correspond to 1, 2, 3, and 4 utils, respectively.

Lecture 4 - Utility Maximization

Intermediate public economics 5 Externalities Hiroaki Sakamoto

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK!

U(x 1. ; x 2 ) = 4 ln x 1

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality

14.54 International Trade Lecture 3: Preferences and Demand

MICROECONOMIC THEORY 1

ECONOMICS SOLUTION BOOK 2ND PUC. Unit 2

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017

Faculty: Sunil Kumar

CV and EV. Measuring Welfare Effects of an Economic Change. ECON 483 ST in Environmental Economics

Golden rule. The golden rule allocation is the stationary, feasible allocation that maximizes the utility of the future generations.

Transcription:

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics Ram Singh October 4, 015 This Write-up is available at photocopy shop. Not for circulation. In this write-up we provide intuition behind the two fundamental theorems of welfare economics and discuss their properties. An economy is defined by: the number of individuals in the economy, preference/utility function, and the endowment vector for each individual in the economy. 1 First Fundamental Theorem Consider an economy as specified in the following example: Example. Suppose the economy consists of two individuals and two goods. The utility functions are u 1 (.) = x 1 1 + x 1 for the first individual and u (.) = x 1x for the second, where x i j denotes the quantity of jth good consumed by ith individual; i = 1, and j = 1,. Let the initial endowments be e 1 (.) = (1, 1) and e (.) = (0, 1 ), respectively. Assume that individuals act as price-takers. Faced with the price vector p = (p 1, ), individual i will demand the bundle, (ˆx i 1, ˆx i ), to maximizes u i (.). That is, the demanded bundle, ˆx i = (ˆx i 1, ˆx i ), will solve: max x i {u i (x i )} (1) subject to the budget constraint p 1 x i 1 + x i = p 1 e i 1 + e i, which can be written as p.x i = p.e i. From introductory microeconomics you know that person will choose the bundle where her indifference curve is tangent to her budge line, i.e., she will demand the bundle where the slope of her indifference curve is the same as the slope of her budget line. This means that she will demand bundle (ˆx 1, ˆx ) that equates her marginal rate of substitution with the price ratio. Mathematically put, the demanded bundle (ˆx 1, ˆx ) will be such that: At (ˆx 1, ˆx ) the marginal rate of substitution for second person, MRS = x x 1 = p 1. Moreover, since the bundle will be on the budget line, i.e., she Not proof read. Please bring typos to my attention. 1

will spend all her income. Therefore, the demanded bundle (ˆx 1, ˆx ) will satisfy the following conditions:.ˆx = p 1.ˆx 1 and p 1ˆx 1 + ˆx = p 1.0 + Clearly p 1ˆx 1 =. You can verify that these equalities give us: ˆx 1 = 4p 1, and ˆx = 1 4. () That is, at positive income level, her demand for nd good is fixed at 1 4. The same logic applies to the 1st person. You can verify that for him the following holds: MRS 1 = 1, i.e., the (absolute) value of the slope of his indifference curve is 1. Moreover, by drawing his ICs and budget line you can see that for given price vector (p 1, ), his demand has the following properties: p 1 > 1 p 1 only nd good is demanded < 1 only 1st good is demanded p 1 = 1 any (x1 1, x 1 ) on the budget line can be demanded. In particular, he will demand both goods, i.e., will demand (ˆx 1 1, ˆx 1 ) >> (0, 0) if the demanded bundle (ˆx 1 1, ˆx 1 ) is such that: At (ˆx 1 1, ˆx 1 ), MRS 1 = 1 = p 1, and p 1ˆx 1 1 + ˆx 1 = p 1 + ; (3) otherwise, only one good will be demanded. In either case, the demanded bundle will lie on his budget line. You should also check that his IC will be tangent to his budget line when he demands both the goods, even though point of tangency is not unique - in that case, his IC coincide with the budget line. When he prefers to consume strictly one good, the tangency between his IC and the budget line does not hold. To sum up, we have seen that for Person 1 the utility maximizing bundle ˆx 1 = (ˆx 1 1, ˆx 1 ) lies on his budget line, which is given by: p 1 x 1 1 + x 1 = p 1 e 1 1 + e 1. For Person the utility maximizing bundle ˆx = (ˆx 1, ˆx ) lies on her budget line given by p 1 x 1 + x = p 1 e 1 + e.

It is useful to draw the two budget lines in the Edgeworth box. Start with the budget line for person, i.e., p 1 x 1 + x = p 1 e 1 + e. We can re-write this equality as: p 1 e 1 + e = p 1 x 1 + x, i.e., p 1 e 1 + e = p 1 (e 1 1 + e 1 x 1 1) + (e 1 + e x 1 ). The second equality follows from the fact that within the Edgeworth box, for each allocation (x 1, x ), we have x 1 1 + x 1 = e 1 1 + e 1, and x 1 + x = e 1 + e. After canceling the common terms on both sides, the above budget line for person can be written as: 0 = p 1 (e 1 1 x 1 1) + (e 1 x 1 ), i.e., p 1 x 1 1 + x 1 = p 1 e 1 1 + e 1, which is the budget line for the 1 person. Therefore, the Edgeworth box the two budget lines coincide! The budget line will pass through the initial endowment point marked as x 0 in Figure 1. This means that the utility maximizing bundles for Person 1 and Person, i.e., bundles ˆx 1 = (ˆx 1 1, ˆx 1 ) and ˆx = (ˆx 1, ˆx ), will lie on the same (budget) line! Moreover, the IC of person will be tangent to this line. The IC of person 1 will also be the tangent to his line if he demand both goods in positive qualities. Next, let us try to find out the equilibrium for this economy. The demanded bundles ˆx 1 and ˆx can form an equilibrium allocation only if ˆx 1 1 + ˆx 1 = e 1 1 + e 1, and ˆx 1 + ˆx = e 1 + e, i.e., only if the total demand of each good equals its supply. 1 Moreover, from () note that as long as both prices are positive, the second person will demand only 1/4 units of the second good. So, in equilibrium, person 1 must demand exactly 3/4 units of the second good. Also, if the second person demand 1 unit of the first good, then we should have = 4p 1. However, = 4p 1 implies that > p 1, but then person demands only the first good. So, total demand will exceed the total supply, which cannot be an equilibrium. Therefore, in equilibrium the demand for first good by person must be strictly less than one unit. This means that person 1 should demand strictly positive quality of the first good. To sum up, in equilibrium, person 1 must demand both goods in positive quantity. But, this can happen only if the price vector p = (p 1, ) is such 1 This also means that (ˆx 1, ˆx ) is an allocation in the Edgeworth box. Alternatively, if an allocation is not a WE, then it cannot be an allocation in the Edgeworth box (check this). 3

that p 1 = 1. I leave it to you to verify that for any price vector p = ( 1, ) such that p 1 1, the total demand (as derived above) cannot be equal to total supply. Let us take (p 1, ) = (1, ). Now the budget line has slope equal to 1/. It is marked as BB in Figure 1. You can check that at such prices under any price vector p = (p 1, ) is such that p 1 = 1: For 1st person, the demanded (utility maximizing) bundle ˆx 1 = (ˆx 1 1, ˆx 1 ) = (1/, 3/4). The For nd person, the demanded (utility maximizing) bundle ˆx = (ˆx 1, ˆx ) = (1/, 1/4) Therefore, for the price vector such that p 1 = 1, the allocation (ˆx1, ˆx ), where ˆx 1 = (1/, 3/4) and ˆx = (1/, 1/4), satisfies the following properties: 1. ˆx 1 maximizes utility for 1st person subject to x 1 1 + x 1 = e 1 1 + e 1.. ˆx maximizes utility for nd person subject to x 1 + x = e 1 + e. 3. ˆx 1 1 + ˆx 1 = e 1 1 + e 1 = 1 and ˆx 1 + ˆx = e 1 + e = 1. Therefore, the allocation (ˆx 1, ˆx ), where ˆx 1 = (1/, 3/4) and ˆx = (1/, 1/4), along with (p 1, ) = (1, ) is a Walrasian (competitive) equilibrium. The equilibrium allocation is marked by point ˆx in Figure 1. Furthermore, for these three properties, note the following: 1 Implies: At ˆx 1 = (1/, 3/4), the IC of person 1 is tangent to her budget line. Implies: ˆx = (1/, 1/4), IC of person is tangent to his budget line. We know that both of the demanded bundles, i.e., ˆx 1 and ˆx lie on the same line. (Why?) Therefore, the ICs of person 1 and are tangent to the same (budget) line. 3 Implies: The demanded bundles, i.e., ˆx 1 and ˆx coincide. Why? That is the ICs of person 1 and are tangent to the same (budget) line and at the same point; which means that the ICs are tangent to each other. That is, at allocation ˆx = (ˆx 1, ˆx ) we have MRS 1 = MRS = p 1. The first equality implies that the equilibrium allocation ˆx = (ˆx 1, ˆx ) is Pareto Optimum. Remark 1 In the above example we have demonstrated that Walrasian equilibrium can exist even when all of the preferences are not strictly quasi-concave. Moreover, it shows that for strictly increasing preferences, a Walrasian equilibrium is Pareto optimum. That is, (ˆx 1 (p), ˆx (p)) cannot be an allocation in the Edgeworth box (check this). 4

We can easily extend the analysis to N-person and M-good economy. Now, for given price vector p = (p 1,..., p M ) the bundle demanded by person i, ˆx i = (ˆx i 1, ˆx i,..., ˆx i M ), will solve: max{u i (x i )} (4) x i subject to the budget constraint p 1 x i 1 + x i +... + p M x i M = p 1e i 1 + e i +... + p M e i M, i.e., subject to p.x i = p.e i. For a well behaved utility function, person i will equate her MRS between goods k and l with the price ratio for these goods, i.e., at the demanded bundle the following will hold: MRS i kl = p k p l, (5) for all goods k, l = 1,..., M. Since all individuals are price-takers, (5) gives us: MRS i kl = MRS k kl = p k p l, (6) for all individuals i, j = 1,..., N and for all goods k, l = 1,..., M. Assume that total demand is equal to total supply of each good - that is, the demanded bundles is an equilibrium allocation. Now, the first equality in (6) implies that the equilibrium is a Pareto optimum allocation. This result is known as the First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics. Formally it is stated as follows. Theorem 1 Consider an exchange economy (u i, e i ) i N. If u i is strictly increasing for all i = 1,.., N, then every Walrasian/Competitive equilibrium allocation is Pareto optimum. For proof refer to our class room discussion. In the class we have proved actually a stronger claim. We have shown that W ((u i, e i ) i N ) C((u i, e i ) i N ). That is, every WE/Competitive equilibrium is in the Core. This, of course, means that every WE equilibrium is Pareto optimum. Second Fundamental Theorem Let us revert to the economy as described in the example in the earlier section. You can check that at the equilibrium allocation (x 1 = (1/, 3/4), x = (1/, 1/4)), the first person gets a utility equal to and the second person s utility is 1/8. Suppose, we want to improve welfare of the second person. How can we do so using the market mechanism? Alternatively, the question is: Can we use the market mechanism to arrive at a more egalitarian (socially desirable) allocation? Specifically, consider an allocation, say (y 1, y ) where y 1 = (1/4, 5/8) and y = (3/4, 3/8). You can check that at this allocation the individual is strictly better off than at the above equilibrium allocation. Moreover, MRS 1 = MRS, so the allocation is Pareto optimum. See Figures 1 and. Can we induce it as Walrasian equilibrium? Yes, we can. The Second Fundamental Theorem is helpful in answering these questions. There are at least three different ways to achieve the objective. 5

The first option is to engage in direct transfer of goods/endowments from person 1 to person so as to reach the above allocation, (y 1, y ), as a competitive equilibrium outcome. (The land reforms is one possible way of direct transfer of endowments). For the purpose, define the transfer vector é = (é 1, é ) such that: For all i = 1, y i = e i + é i. After the transfer, individual i will end up with vector y i as the new endowment. In Figure, this would mean that the endowment point shifts from e 0 to the point marked as y. It can be easily seen that to achieve the purpose, we need to transfer 3/4 units of first good from person 1 to person, and 1/8 units of second good from person to person 1. That is, the transfer vectors are: é 1 = ( 3/4, 1/8) and é = (3/4, 1/8). Next, we want to be sure that the new endowment vector, (y 1, y ), with y 1 = (1/4, 5/8) and y = (3/4, 3/8), is a competitive equilibrium; otherwise, in equilibrium the economic agents will end up consuming bundles different from what we want them to consume. However, the vector (y 1, y ) can be achieved as a competitive equilibrium allocation. Note that at the allocation (y 1, y ) as defined above, we have MRS 1 = MRS = 1/. So, if we choose a price vector (p 1, ) such that p 1 = 1, at allocation (y1, y ) as defined above, the following will hold MRS 1 = MRS = p 1. In fact, you can verify that for a price vector (p 1, ) such that p 1 = 1, say ( 1, ) = (1, ), the allocation (y 1, y ) as defined above, satisfies all the condition of a competitive equilibrium. Therefore, the allocation (y 1, y ) along with the price vector (p 1, ) = (1, ) constitute a Walrasian equilibrium. Note that when price vector is (p 1, ) = (1, ), the budget line has slope of p 1 and it passes through the allocation point (y 1, y ). (Take a note of how we have found, the equilibrium price vector.) Therefore, one option to achieve any Pareto optimum allocation as competitive equilibrium is to directly transfer the endowments so that the new endowment vector (after transfer) is the same as the desired allocation. However, we may not have complete flexibility in transfer of endowments so as to move all the way to the desired allocation. For example, if one of the endowment is human capital then it is not possible to transfer it across individuals. The second option is to engage in partial transfer of endowments so as to reach any point on the budget line that has slope of p 1 and passes through desired allocation (y 1, y ). Note that we have taken the budget line as under the first option for improving welfare of the second person. Assume that only the first endowment is directly transferable. Now, consider the following transfers: é 1 = ( 1/, 0) and é = (1/, 0). The result will be new endowment vectors (1/,1/) for person 1 and (1/,1/) for person. In Figure 3, it means shift of endowment point e 0 to the point marked as e 1. Note that the new endowment vector is a point on the budget line considered in 6

the first case above (, i.e., Figure ). Since (p 1, ) = (1, ), we know that at allocation desired allocation (y 1, y ) as defined above, the following will hold: MRS 1 = MRS = p 1. Hence, the allocation (y 1, y ), y 1 = (1/4, 5/8) and y = (3/4, 3/8), emerges as a unique competitive equilibrium along with price vector (p 1, ) = (1, ). As an exercise, you can consider the case when only the second endowment is transferable. If you consider the following transfers: é 1 = (0, 1/4) and é = (0, 1/4) and take (p 1, ) = (1, ) as the price vector, you will find that the allocation (y 1, y ), y 1 = (1/4, 5/8) and y = (3/4, 3/8), is still a unique competitive equilibrium! Is it possible to achieve the desirable allocation, even if none of the endowments is directly transferable? Yes, it is. The third option involves cash transfers. Note that when the price vector is p = (p 1, ) = (1, ), the transfer vectors considered above, é 1 = ( 1/, 0) and é = (1/, 0) entail a transfer of purchasing power equal to 1/ from person 1 to person. It turns out that if keep the prices to be p = (p 1, ) = (1, ), cash transfer will lead to the same outcome. Consider a transfer of T i to the ith individual. Choose T 1 = 1 and T = 1 Compared to the initial situation, such transfers clearly change the budget sets for the two individuals - it expands the budget set of person but shrinks that of person 1. As a result, in equilibrium person will consume (x 1, x ) such that: MRS = x x 1 = p 1, and (the new) budget constraint holds, i.e., p 1 x 1 + x = p 1.0 +. 1 + T. That is, her demanded bundle satisfies:.x = p 1.x 1 and p 1 x 1 + x = p 1.0 +. 1 + T. See Figure 4. You can check that the unique solution to s problem is (x 1, x ) = (3/4, 3/8). Similarly, you can verify that person 1 will demand y 1 = (1/4, 5/8). Yet again, the allocation (y 1, y ), y 1 = (1/4, 5/8) and y = (3/4, 3/8), along with price vector (p 1, ) = (1, ) is a unique competitive equilibrium! As an exercise, choose any other Pareto optimal allocation for the above economy. Following any the above approach, you can show that the chosen allocation can be achieved as competitive allocation through suitable transfers. This result is actually the Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics. 7

Theorem If u i is continuous, strictly increasing, and strictly quasi-concave for all i = 1,.., N, then any Pareto optimum allocation, y = (y 1,..., y N ), such that y i >> 0, can be achieved as competitive equilibrium with suitable transfers. That is, y = (y 1,..., y N ) is a WE with suitable transfer. With suitable transfers, market can achieve any of the socially desirable allocation as competitive equilibrium. Question 1 We have demonstrated the claim in the second fundamental theorem can hold even if the utility functions are not strictly quasi-concave for all i = 1,.., N. However, the statement of the theorem requires u i to be strictly quasi-concave for all i = 1,.., N, along with continuity and monotonicity for all functions. Why? 8