Individual Consequences of Occupational Decline

Similar documents
Individual Consequences of Occupational Decline

Public Employees as Politicians: Evidence from Close Elections

Economic Stimulus at the Expense of Routine-Task Jobs

Online Appendix for On the Asset Allocation of a Default Pension Fund

ON THE ASSET ALLOCATION OF A DEFAULT PENSION FUND

institution Top 10 to 20 undergraduate

Closing routes to retirement: how do people respond? Johannes Geyer, Clara Welteke

Private sector valuation of public sector experience: The role of education and geography *

Wage Inequality and Establishment Heterogeneity

Unequal Burden of Retirement Reform: Evidence from Australia

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

Ruhm, C. (1991). Are Workers Permanently Scarred by Job Displacements? The American Economic Review, Vol. 81(1):

On the Returns to Invention Within Firms: Evidence from Finland. Prepared for the AER P&P 2018 Submission

Effects of Increased Elderly Employment on Other Workers Employment and Elderly s Earnings in Japan. Ayako Kondo Yokohama National University

Changes in Economic Mobility

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer?

Public-private sector pay differential in UK: A recent update

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Estimating Average and Local Average Treatment Effects of Education When Compulsory Schooling Laws Really Matter: Corrigendum.

Financial liberalization and the relationship-specificity of exports *

The current study builds on previous research to estimate the regional gap in

Estimating Average and Local Average Treatment Effects of Education When Compulsory Schooling Laws Really Matter: Corrigendum.

Is There a Glass Ceiling in Sweden?

US Economic Outlook and Policy Challenges May 2017

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec

New Jersey Public-Private Sector Wage Differentials: 1970 to William M. Rodgers III. Heldrich Center for Workforce Development

Interest Rate Pass-Through: Mortgage Rates, Household Consumption, and Voluntary Deleveraging. Online Appendix

Online Appendix from Bönke, Corneo and Lüthen Lifetime Earnings Inequality in Germany

Can Information Change Personal Retirement Savings? Evidence from Social Security Benefits Statement Mailings. Susan Payne Carter William Skimmyhorn

Firing Costs, Employment and Misallocation

Health and the Future Course of Labor Force Participation at Older Ages. Michael D. Hurd Susann Rohwedder

The Long Term Evolution of Female Human Capital

What do we learn about redistribution effects of pension systems from internationally comparable measures of Social Security Wealth?

Web Appendix Figure 1. Operational Steps of Experiment

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva*

Supporting Information: Preferences for International Redistribution: The Divide over the Eurozone Bailouts

How exogenous is exogenous income? A longitudinal study of lottery winners in the UK

Technology and the China Shock: Evidence from France

Retirement and Unexpected Health Shocks

The Association between Children s Earnings and Fathers Lifetime Earnings: Estimates Using Administrative Data

Worker Betas: Five Facts about Systematic Earnings Risk

Internet Appendix. The survey data relies on a sample of Italian clients of a large Italian bank. The survey,

a. Explain why the coefficients change in the observed direction when switching from OLS to Tobit estimation.


The model is estimated including a fixed effect for each family (u i ). The estimated model was:

Trade Liberalization and Labor Market Dynamics

Lorem ipsum dolor sit amet, consectetur Millennial Financial Literacy and Fin-tech Use adipiscing elit, aliquam tincidunt dui.

Return dynamics of index-linked bond portfolios

The Impact of Credit Counseling on Consumer Outcomes: Evidence from a National Demonstration Program

The impact of a longer working life on health: exploiting the increase in the UK state pension age for women

Online Appendix: Revisiting the German Wage Structure

Table IA.1 CEO Pay-Size Elasticity and Increased Labor Demand Panel A: IPOs Scaled by Full Sample Industry Average

Employment Adjustments to Increased Imports: Evidence from a Developing Country

Wage flexibility of older workers and the role of institutions

Aging and the Productivity Puzzle

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE GROWTH IN SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS AMONG THE RETIREMENT AGE POPULATION FROM INCREASES IN THE CAP ON COVERED EARNINGS

A New Look at Technical Progress and Early Retirement

The Trend in Lifetime Earnings Inequality and Its Impact on the Distribution of Retirement Income. Barry Bosworth* Gary Burtless Claudia Sahm

Is Thailand s Labor Market Really Woman Friendly? Revisiting the Declining Gender Wage Gap

Labor Force Participation and the Wage Gap Detailed Notes and Code Econometrics 113 Spring 2014

Intergenerational Consequences of Wealth Inequality

Online Appendix Long-Lasting Effects of Socialist Education

LARGER BIRTH COHORT LOWERS WAGES

The Distributive Impact of Reforms in Credit Enforcement: Evidence from Indian Debt Recovery Tribunals

A Rising Tide Lifts All Boats? IT growth in the US over the last 30 years

BORROWING TO SAVE? UNINTENDED CONSEQUENCES OF AUTOMATIC ENROLLMENT

DYNAMICS OF URBAN INFORMAL

The Future of Work Public Policy Forum, Toronto

Are you prepared for retirement?

The Impact of a $15 Minimum Wage on Hunger in America

Routine Tasks and Recovery from Mass Layoffs

Changes in the Experience-Earnings Pro le: Robustness

The Impact of the Default Investment Decision on Participant Deferral Rates: Managed Accounts vs Target-Date Funds

Unequal Burden of Retirement Reform: Evidence from Australia

An Analysis of Public and Private Sector Earnings in Ireland

APPENDIX to Pyramidal Ownership and the Creation of New Firms

Aging and the Productivity Puzzle

Mining closures, gender, and employment reallocations: the case of UK coal mines

Data Appendix. A.1. The 2007 survey

Average Earnings and Long-Term Mortality: Evidence from Administrative Data

Unemployment, Consumption Smoothing and the Value of UI

Decentralization of Public Education: Does Everyone Benefit?

WEALTH INEQUALITY AND HOUSEHOLD STRUCTURE: US VS. SPAIN. Olympia Bover

Strictness of Tax Compliance Norms: A Factorial Survey on the Acceptance of Inheritance Tax Evasion in Germany

While real incomes in the lower and middle portions of the U.S. income distribution have

Demographic and Economic Outlook for Michigan and Its Counties to 2045:

Do Domestic Chinese Firms Benefit from Foreign Direct Investment?

Who is internationally diversified? Evidence from the 401(k) plans of 296 firms*

The labor market in South Korea,

The Role of APIs in the Economy

Pension Wealth and Household Saving in Europe: Evidence from SHARELIFE

Center for Demography and Ecology

ECO671, Spring 2014, Sample Questions for First Exam

Wealth at the End of Life: Evidence on Estate Planning and Bequests

A Lost Generation? Young Families after the Great Recession

Household Income Distribution and Working Time Patterns. An International Comparison

Exploring differences in financial literacy across countries: the role of individual characteristics, experience, and institutions

1. Logit and Linear Probability Models

Estimating the Effects of Minimum Wage

Public economics: Income Inequality

Transcription:

Individual Consequences of Occupational Decline Per-Anders Edin, Georg Graetz, Sofia Hernnäs (Uppsala) Guy Michaels (LSE) [Very preliminary and incomplete] 2018 ASSA Annual Meeting, Philadelphia

Outline Introduction Data Results

New machines enter the labor market In November 2017 Waymo s driverless minivans started roaming the streets of Phoenix, Arizona, with engineers in their back seats Meanwhile in London, an artificial intelligence program beat human lawyers in using basic information to predict whether a Financial Ombudsman would allow claims in miss-selling cases Research question What are the consequences for individual workers when technology reduces demand for their occupation? Study Swedish workers who in 1985 worked in occupations that subsequently (22 years) declined due to (unanticipated) technological change

What is at stake? Displaced workers & their families wellbeing Potential for further rise in inequality Implications for human capital investments when people expect long lives but worry about technological replacement Implications for the state: taxation, redistribution, retirement, design of education for young people and training for older ones Those who lose may not go down quietly, causing political turmoil

Literature: winners & losers from technological change Autor (2015) argues that technology will also create jobs; Caselli & Manning (2017) maintain that some workers will win out in previous work (Graetz & Michaels 2015) we find gains from robot use But some jobs will be lost. Estimates for the upcoming decades range from 10% (Arntz et al. 2016) to 50% (Frey & Osborne, 2017) Evidence on effects of trade on individuals (Autor et al. 2014), and on mass layoffs (Jacobson et al. 1993) But technology is trickier. Following Autor et al. (2003), the literature has focused on tasks (routine vs non-routine) Cortes (2016) studies this using panel data on task categories (broad occupation groups) Evidence on detailed occupations is limited, not much using panel data

Methodology: measuring occupational decline due to technological change Use understudied data from US Occupational Outlook Handbook (OOH); allows us to identify declining occupations check if decline is due to technological replacement distinguish b/w anticipated and unanticipated declines For now: take all occupations declining by more than 25 percent from 1984-2017. Later: technology, anticipation. Match US occupational info to study Swedish micro data Numerous advantages of longitudinal micro data No equivalent to OOH in Sweden but we confirm that the OOH-based measure predicts occupational decline in Sweden

What can we learn? Examine effect on (22 year) career earnings and employment of those aged 25-40 in 1985 Many more outcomes of interest (early retirement, health) TBC Study heterogeneity by education (later also gender, cognitive and non-cognitive skills, geography) Econometric implementation y i,1985 2007 = βd i + x i γ + ε i D i 1{i works in soon-to-be-declining occupation in 1985} OLS for now, but will also consider matching (individuals) or synthetic controls (occupations) Cluster standard errors by occupation (level of variation of treatment)

Preview of what we find 1. When comparing observationally similar workers, no evidence of differential cumulative employment or earnings can rule out income losses of more than five percent of average cumulative earnings 2. This is despite the fact that workers starting out in declining occupations are much less likely to remain in their initial occupation 3. When looking at college workers, do see meaningful income losses associated with starting in a declining occupation this may be related to a decline in the value of occupation-specific human capital Our measure of decline does strongly predict occupational employment growth in Sweden. We also find similar results using actual employment growth and the routine index as explanatory variables. Results are preliminary we need to refine our measure of decline

Outline Introduction Data Results

Methodology: measuring occupational decline due to technological change Use understudied data from US Occupational Outlook Handbook (OOH) details Every two years they provide detailed snapshot of occupations and predict employment change for subsequent decade Match data for the 400 occupations from 1986-1987 OOH into the 2017 OOH [For timing, also use intervening editions of OOH (1996-7 & 2006-7) TBC] Calculate %-change in employment by occupation To mitigate measurement error we focus on declines of 25% or more in employment and on occupations that vanished Later, restrict attention to cases where OOH predictions from 1986 (or 1996 or 2006) mention potential for technology to reduce labor demand; also distinguish anticipated/surprise declines

Use US occupational info to study Swedish individual data We match OOH information into Swedish occupations in 1985 Advantages of longitudinal micro data rich information on individual characteristics controls can study selection into and out of occupations can look at heterogeneity (who gains, who loses) can control for industry to absorb other shocks (e.g. trade shocks and change in demand) Can use OOH predictions to focus on unanticipated changes in occupational employment due to tech change No equivalent to OOH in Sweden, but occupational employment trends in Europe very similar to US in general (Goos et al. 2014, Adermon & Gustavsson 2015) we confirm that the OOH-based measure predicts occupational decline in Sweden

Swedish population-level micro data Earnings, employment status, industry, education, geography 1970, 1975, 1980, annually 1985-2013 Wage rates annually 1985-2013 (sample) Occupation every five years 1960-1990, annually (sample) 1996-2013 classifications change, not always easy to map Test scores from military enlistment exams males, birth cohorts 1955-1985

Outline Introduction Data Results

Occupational decline in US (OOH) predicts occupational decline in Sweden (1) (2) (3) Declining -0.61-0.60-0.64 (0.12) (0.13) (0.15) Employment share 1985-0.49 1.76 (2.88) (3.43) Education controls R-squared 0.11 0.11 0.18 Notes: Regressions are weighted by Swedish 1985 employment shares. The dependent variable is the difference in the log of number of people employed in each 3-digit (SSYK) occupation between 2007 and 1985 (weighted mean: -0.01, standard deviation: 0.6). Declining is the fraction of employment in a declining sub-occupation within each 3-digit occupation in 1985. Sub-occupations have been classified as declining using the Occupational Outlook Handbooks. Education controls indicates that the fractions of workers with a given education level (seven categories) are controlled for. The number of observations is 273. Robust standard errors in parentheses.

Baseline (1985) characteristics for workers in subsequently declining occupations (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Female Age Compuls. High school College Income Constant 0.46 33.1 0.26 0.59 0.15 195.9 (0.035) (0.078) (0.019) (0.022) (0.020) (4.77) Declining 0.081 0.024 0.046 0.037-0.082-13.2 (0.10) (0.14) (0.028) (0.034) (0.031) (9.05) R-squared 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 Notes: The sample includes all individuals who were born between 1945 and 1960 and who were employed in 1985. Outcomes are measured in 1985. The number of observations is 1,336,721. Robust standard errors, clustered by occupation, in parentheses.

Individual-level outcomes for Swedish workers: cumulative employment and income A. Cumulative years employed 1986-2007 (mean: 18.74) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Declining -0.08-0.06 0.18 0.18-0.03 0.29 (0.13) (0.14) (0.12) (0.12) (0.11) (0.10) B. Cumulative real income ( 000 2014 SEK) 1986-2007 (mean: 5,267) Declining -511-357 24 19-827 -47 (265) (166) (110) (75) (240) (66) C. Percentile rank in cumulative real income (mean: 50.5) Declining -3.3-1.7 1.7 1.2-6.7 0.5 (3.1) (1.7) (1.1) (0.6) (2.8) (0.5) Female & cohort dummies Education dummies Income in 1985 Industry dummies Notes: Declining is an indicator for working in an occupation in 1985 that is classified as declining subsequently. Income in 1985 indicates that the level of income (panels A, B) or the percentile rank (panel C) in 1985 is controlled for. The sample includes all individuals who were born between 1945 and 1960 and who were employed in 1985. The number of observations is 1,336,721. Robust standard errors, clustered by occupation, in parentheses.

Individual-level outcomes for Swedish workers: probability of remaining in the same occupation (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) A. Probability of working in same 3-digit occuaption in 2007 as in 1985 (mean: 0.42) Declining -0.16-0.16-0.16-0.16-0.10-0.10 (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.03) (0.03) B. Probability of working in same 2-digit occuaption in 2007 as in 1985 (mean: 0.50) Declining -0.08-0.09-0.08-0.08-0.03-0.04 (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.02) (0.02) C. Probability of working in same 1-digit occuaption in 2007 as in 1985 (mean: 0.55) Declining -0.07-0.08-0.06-0.06-0.03-0.03 (0.02) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.02) (0.02) Female & cohort dummies Education dummies Income in 1985 Industry dummies Notes: Declining is an indicator for working in an occupation in 1985 that is classified as declining subsequently. The sample includes all individuals who were born between 1945 and 1960, who were employed in 1985, and who were sampled in the Wage Structure Statistics in 2007 (results for cumulative employment and income are very similar for this sample to those for the population). The number of observations is 658,429. Robust standard errors, clustered by occupation, in parentheses.

Results for income: heterogeneity by education A. At most compulsory schooling (1) (2) (3) Declining 258 147 107 (101) (62) (53) Observations 353,558 353,558 353,558 B. High school Declining -120 30-51 (139) (61) (49) Observations 803,226 803,226 803,226 C. College Declining -1,023-329 -548 (387) (169) (190) Observations 179,937 179,937 179,937 Female & cohort dummies Education dummies & income Industry dummies Notes: The dependent variable is cumulative real income 1986-2007 in thousand SEK with 2014 as base year (mean: 5,267). Robust standard errors, clustered by occupation, in parentheses.

Discussion & conclusion Aim to provide first evidence on long-run effects of occupational replacement by technology at individual level Preliminary results show no strong evidence for adverse effects on average can rule out losses of more than five percent of average cumulative earnings But occupational stability does appear to be adversely affected Some evidence for heterogeneity perhaps surprisingly, high educated seem to suffer more We will use military test scores to investigate if there is negative selection within the college group

«a. 3J<+'. - Occupational Outlook Handbook U.S. Department of Labor Bureau of Labor Statistics April 1986 1986-87 Edition Bulletin 2250 Digi ti ze d for FR ASER ht tp :/ /fra rase ser. stlo uisf ed.org rg/ Fe de ra l Rese serve Bank of St. Loui s

OOH (1986-87) on technological replacement Bank tellers The number of bank tellers is expected to increase more slowly than the average for all occupations through the mid-1990 s because of the increasing use of automatic teller machines and other electronic equipment. Bookkeepers and accounting clerks The volume of business transactions is expected to grow rapidly, with a corresponding increase in the need for financial and accounting records. However, the need for bookkeepers, who maintain these records, will not increase nearly as fast because of the increasing use of computers to record, store, and manipulate data. Precision assemblers The effect of automation on precision assembler employment will depend on how rapidly and extensively new manufacturing technologies are adopted. Certainly, not all precision assemblers can be replaced efficiently by automated processes. Robots are expensive and a large volume of work is required to justify their purchase.