Near-Expiry Asymptotics of the Implied Volatility in Local and Stochastic Volatility Models

Similar documents
Asymptotics of implied volatility in local volatility models

ASYMPTOTICS OF IMPLIED VOLATILITY IN LOCAL VOLATILITY MODELS. JIM GATHERAL Baruch College, CUNY. ELTON P. HSU Northwestern University

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Asymptotics beats Monte Carlo: The case of correlated local vol baskets

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

SHORT-TIME IMPLIED VOLATILITY IN EXPONENTIAL LÉVY MODELS

1 Implied Volatility from Local Volatility

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Application of large deviation methods to the pricing of index options in finance. Méthodes de grandes déviations et pricing d options sur indice

Black-Scholes Option Pricing

WKB Method for Swaption Smile

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Stochastic Differential Equations in Finance and Monte Carlo Simulations

Lecture 3. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 6

MSC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING PRICING I, AUTUMN LECTURE 6: EXTENSIONS OF BLACK AND SCHOLES RAYMOND BRUMMELHUIS DEPARTMENT EMS BIRKBECK

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque)

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

The Black-Scholes Equation

Approximation Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Weak Reflection Principle and Static Hedging of Barrier Options

Near-expiration behavior of implied volatility for exponential Lévy models

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

PDE Methods for the Maximum Drawdown

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

Path Dependent British Options

Probability in Options Pricing

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

Extrapolation analytics for Dupire s local volatility

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

MSC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING PRICING I, AUTUMN LECTURE 9: LOCAL AND STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY RAYMOND BRUMMELHUIS DEPARTMENT EMS BIRKBECK

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

CS476/676 Mar 6, Today s Topics. American Option: early exercise curve. PDE overview. Discretizations. Finite difference approximations

Probability density of lognormal fractional SABR model

Pricing of a European Call Option Under a Local Volatility Interbank Offered Rate Model

Analysis of the sensitivity to discrete dividends : A new approach for pricing vanillas

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems

BROWNIAN MOTION AND OPTION PRICING WITH AND WITHOUT TRANSACTION COSTS VIA CAS MATHEMATICA. Angela Slavova, Nikolay Kyrkchiev

Heston vs Heston. Antoine Jacquier. Department of Mathematics, Imperial College London. ICASQF, Cartagena, Colombia, June 2016

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

Calibration Lecture 4: LSV and Model Uncertainty

Stochastic Modelling in Finance

The Black-Scholes Model

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options

The Black-Scholes Model

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Lévy models in finance

Dynamic Relative Valuation

Introduction Taylor s Theorem Einstein s Theory Bachelier s Probability Law Brownian Motion Itô s Calculus. Itô s Calculus.

Finance II. May 27, F (t, x)+αx f t x σ2 x 2 2 F F (T,x) = ln(x).

Optimal exercise price of American options near expiry

ON AN IMPLEMENTATION OF BLACK SCHOLES MODEL FOR ESTIMATION OF CALL- AND PUT-OPTION VIA PROGRAMMING ENVIRONMENT MATHEMATICA

The Black-Scholes Model

Importance Sampling for Option Pricing. Steven R. Dunbar. Put Options. Monte Carlo Method. Importance. Sampling. Examples.

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

ZABR -- Expansions for the Masses

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

A Note about the Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model under Time-Varying Conditions Yi-rong YING and Meng-meng BAI

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

The stochastic calculus

Financial Risk Management

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends.

Stochastic Volatility Effects on Defaultable Bonds

SADDLEPOINT APPROXIMATIONS TO OPTION PRICES 1. By L. C. G. Rogers and O. Zane University of Bath and First Chicago NBD

NUMERICAL METHODS OF PARTIAL INTEGRO-DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS FOR OPTION PRICE

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Financial Derivatives Section 5

Asymptotic Method for Singularity in Path-Dependent Option Pricing

Risk Neutral Pricing Black-Scholes Formula Lecture 19. Dr. Vasily Strela (Morgan Stanley and MIT)

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Extensions to the Black Scholes Model

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I)

Option Valuation with Sinusoidal Heteroskedasticity

A series representation for the Black-Scholes formula

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Computational Finance

STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY AND OPTION PRICING

Transcription:

Mathematical Finance Colloquium, USC September 27, 2013 Near-Expiry Asymptotics of the Implied Volatility in Local and Stochastic Volatility Models Elton P. Hsu Northwestern University (Based on a joint work with G. Ben Arous, J.Gatheral, P. Laurence, C. Ouyang, and T. H. Wang) First Prev Next Last Go Back Full Screen Close Quit

Black-Scholes PDE and Black-Scholes formula Consider a simplified financial market with risk-free interest rate r and a single stock with volatility σ. A call option price function C(s, t) satisfies the Black-Scholes PDE (1973) is C t + 1 2 σ2 s 2 C ss + rsc s rc = 0, (t, s) (0, T ) (0, ). with the terminal condition C(T, s) = (s K) +. The Black-Scholes equation has an explicit solution called the Black-Scholes formula. where and C BS (t, s; σ, r) = sn(d 1 ) Ke r(t t) N(d 2 ), N(d) = 1 2π d e x2 /2 dx, d 1 = log(s/k) + (r + σ2 /2)(T t) T tσ, d 2 = d 1 σ T t.

Probabilstic Model Let S t be the stock price process and B t = e rt the risk-free bond. Under the riskneutral probability, S t is described by the following stochastic differential equation ds t = S t (rdt + σdw t ). Here r is the risk-free interest rate, σ a constant volatility and W t a standard 1- dimensional Brownian motion. This equation has an explicit solution [ ( ) ] S T = S 0 exp σb T + r σ2 T. 2 The price of an European call option at the expiry T is C(S T, T ) = (S T K) +. It also has the following probabilistic representation C(t, s; σ, r) = e r(t t) E{(S T K) + S t = s}.

Dupire s local volatility model Constant volatility model is inadequate. Dupire (1994) introduced the local volatility model in which volatility depends on the stock price. The Black-Scholes PDE becomes The Black-Scholes equation is C t + 1 2 σ(s)2 s 2 C ss + rsc s rc = 0. If we make a change of variable x = log s, then the equation becomes where L = 1 2 C t + LC = 0, η(x)2 d2 dx 2 + [ r 1 2 η(x)2 ] d dx with η(x) = σ(e x ). Let p (t, x, y) be the heat kernel for t L. Then C(t, s) = 0 (e y K) + p (T t, log s, log y) dy.

Implied volatility in local volatility model If c(t, s) is the call price in the local volatility model when the stock price is s at time t, then the implied volatility ˆσ is defined implicitly by C(t, s) = C BS (t, s; ˆσ(t, s), r). The call price on the right side of the above equation is the one calculated by the classical Black-Scholes formula. Assume that the local volatility is uniformly bounded from both above and below 0 < σ σ(s) σ <. The implied volatility ˆσ(t, s) is well defined because the Black-Scholes pricing function C BS (t, s; σ, r) is an increasing function of the volatility σ: C σ = T t S 2π e d2 1 /2.

Analysis of symptotic behaviors The range of the parameters: (t, s) (0, T ) (0, ). Asymptotics: investigate the boundary behavior of the implied volatility function ˆσ(s, t): (1) near expiry: t T ; (2) deeply in the money: s ; (3) deeply out of the money: s 0. We are concerned with (1). Recall that C(t, s) = C BS (t, s, ˆσ(t, s), r) and C(T, s) = (s K) +. If s < K, both sides vanish as t T. How does ˆσ(t, s) behave when t T? First Prev Next Last Go Back Full Screen Close Quit

The nonlinear parabolic equation of Berestycki, Busca, and Florent The implied volatility function ˆσ(t, s) satisfies an quasi-linear partial differential equation: ( 2τ ˆσˆσ τ = σ 2 τ ˆσˆσ xx + σ 2 1 x ˆσ ) 2 x 1 ˆσ 4 σ2 τ 2ˆσ 2ˆσ x 2 ˆσ2 Here x = log ( se rτ /K ) and τ = T t and ˆσ(x, τ ) = ˆσ(s, t), the implied volatility in the new variables. Berestycki, Busca and Florent: (1) Asymptotics and calibration of local volatility models, Quantitative Finance, Vol. 2, 61-69 (2002)). (2) Computing the implied volatility in stochastic volatility models, Comm. Pure and Appl. Math., Vol. LVII, 1352-1373 (2004).

Implied Volatility asymptotics - leading term Solution of the quasi-linear BBF equation has nice comparison properties. For the equation itself in this special form and for the comparison principle to hold, the use of the terminal call price function C(T, s) = (s K) + is crucial. The function ˆσ(s, t) is NOT singular near t = T. Using the comparison properties, BBF identified the leading term as t T of the leading value of the implied volatility: [ 1 K ] du 1 lim ˆσ(t, s) =. t T log K log s uσ(u, T ) This serves as the initial condition for the BBF nonlinear parabolic equation. s BBF = Berestycki, Busca, and Florent

Implied volatility expansion We expect an asymptotic expansion ˆσ(s, t) ˆσ(s, T ) + ˆσ 1 (s, T )(T t) + ˆσ 2 (s, T )(T t) 2 + for the solution of the volatility expansion. Besides ˆσ(s, T ), the first two terms ˆσ 1 (s, T ) and ˆσ 2 (s, T ) also have practical significance. Calculating ˆσ 1 (s, T ) is from the BBF nonlinear PDE is not feasible in practice. We adopt a different approach: going back to the linear parabolic equation. The new method also shows that the special form of the call function (s K) +, important for the comparison results for the nonlinear parabolic PDE, is in fact of no significance for the leading term calculation. Only the support of the function is important.

Qualitative analysis Recall that C(t, s) = 0 (e y K) + p (T t, log s, log y) dy. Since t T, the problem should be related to the short time behavior of the heat kernel. We have Varadhan s formula y)2 lim t log p (t, x, y) = d(x,, t 0 2 where d(x, y) is the Riemannian distance between x and y. In the local volatility case (one dimension) we have d(x, y) = y x dz zσ(z). Finer asymptotics of the implied volatility ˆσ(t, s) depends on more delicate but well studied asymptotic expansion of the heat kernel.

Refined implied volatility behavior - first order deviation Theorem For the implied volatility function we have ˆσ(t, s) = ˆσ(T, s) + ˆσ 1 (T, s)(t t) + O((T t) 2 ), where (due to Berestycki, Busca, and Florent) [ 1 ˆσ(T, s) = log K log s K and ˆσ(T, s) 3 [ σ(s)σ(k) ˆσ 1 (T, s) = (log K log s) 2 log + r ˆσ(T, s) s du uσ(u) K s ] 1 [ ] ] 1 σ 2 (u) 1 du ˆσ 2. (T, s) u

Special case: r = 0 The first order correction is given by ˆσ 1 (T, s) = ˆσ(T, s) 3 (log K log s) 2 log σ(s)σ(k). ˆσ(T, s) This case was obtained by Henry-Labordere using a heuristic argument (in the manner of theoretical physics).

Observations (1) The first order deviation ˆσ 1 (T, s) of the implied volatility ˆσ(t, s) depends only on the extremal values σ(s) and σ(k) of the local volatility function and a certain averaged deviation of the local volatility from its expected leading value ˆσ(T, s). This means that the first order deviation is numerically stable with respect to the local volatility function σ(s), which in practice cannot be calibrated very precisely. (2) Further analysis shows that further higher order derivatives of ˆσ(t, s) at expiry are not as stable, i.e., they will be sensitive to the derivatives of the local volatility.

Basic approach We have and C(t, s) = C(t, s) = C BS (t, s, ˆσ(t, s), r) 0 (e y K) + p (T t, log s, log y) dy. (1) Find the expansion of the heat kernel p(τ, x, y) as τ 0. (2) Use the heat kernel expansion to calculate the expansion of C(t, s). (3) Use the explict Black-Scholes formula to expand C BS. (4) Equate the two expansions and extra the information on ˆ(t, s).

Heat kernel asymptotics Denote the transition density of X by p (τ, x, y). Then we have the following expansion as τ 0 p X (τ, x, y) u [ 0(x, y) e d2 (x,y) 2τ 1 + H n (x, y)τ ]. n 2πτ d(x, y) = y x du η(u). n=1 H n are smooth functions of x and y and [ u 0 (x, y) = η 1 2(x)η 3 2(y) exp 12 y (y x) + x ] r η 2 (v) dv. (e.g., see S. A. Molchanov, Diffusion processes and Riemannian geometry, Russian Math. Surveys, 30, no. 1 (1975), 1-63.)

The leading term of the call price in a local volatility model Introduce the new variables τ = T t x = log s. Consider the case x < log K. For the rescaled call price function v(τ, x) = C(t, s) we have as τ 0, [ ( ) η(log K) 2 v(τ, x) = Ku 0 (x, log K) + O(τ )] d(x, log K) τ 2 K)2 d(x,log e 2τ. 2πτ

Asymptotic behavior of the classical Black-Scholes pricing function Let V (τ, x; σ, r) = C BS (t, e x ; σ, r) be the classical Black-Scholes call price function. Then we have as τ 0, V (τ, x; σ, r) 1 Kσ 3 τ 3/2 2π (ln K x) 2 exp [ The remainder satisfies exp (ln K x)2 2τ σ 2 R(τ, x; σ, r) C τ 5/2 exp [ ln K x 2 ] [ + + R(τ, x; σ, r). ] (ln K x)2 2τ σ 2, ] r(ln K x) σ 2 where C = C(x, σ, r, K) is uniformly bounded if all the indicated parameters vary in a bounded region.

Last step Equate the two expansions v(τ, x) = V (τ, x; ˆσ(t, s), r) and extract the first two terms in the asymptotic expansion for ˆσ(t, s). Summary The implies volatility function is the solution of a nonlinear parabolic equation ( 2τ ˆσˆσ τ = σ 2 τ ˆσˆσ xx + σ 2 1 x ˆσ ) 2 x 1 ˆσ 4 σ2 τ 2ˆσ 2ˆσ x 2 ˆσ2 with the boundary condition ˆσ(T, s) = [ 1 log K log s K s du uσ(u) ] 1. By exploring the connection with the heat kernel expansion, we are able to find the first order deviation of the implied volatility from its leading value.

Stochastic volatility models Stochastic volatility model: S 1 t ds t = r dt + σ(s t, y t ) dw 1 t, dy t = θ(y t ) dt + ν(y t ) d W t. Here W t = (Wt 1, W t ) = (Wt 1, W t 2,, W t n ) is a linear transform of the standard Brownian motion. Let Z t = (S t, y t ) be the combined stock-volatility process. The generator L of Z is a second order subelliptic operator. L determines a Riemannian geometry. A large number of stochastic volatility models lead to hyperbolic geometry (e.g., SABR models). A similar result holds for the implied volatility: ˆσ(T, Z 0 ) = ln S 0 ln K d(z 0, H K ), where d(z 0, H K ) is the Riemannian distance of Z 0 = (S 0, y 0 ) to the hypersurface H K = {s = K}. First order deviation ˆσ 1 (T, Z 0 ) requires a detailed geometric analysis of the hypersurface H K.

Brownian Motion on a Manifold: Rolling with slipping... Source: Anton Thalmaier First Prev Next Last Go Back Full Screen Close Quit

Stochastic Volatility Model Localized Calculation Illustration i:r'#ht.n:,{ \. i,l"t nell*/,irt" \^b-+ */fft*trw L szk 't Z;= 0",/r, efil*, ^ ( 9 ru*i,,n ouo{ ^ ',;tk W) tth,*,,,r, ft*,a* ft ^ df,#. nuu. //,/.f

THANK YOU! First Prev Next Last Go Back Full Screen Close Quit