Import Protection, Business Cycles, and Exchange Rates:

Similar documents
Import Protection, Business Cycles, and Exchange Rates:

Import Protection, Business Cycles, and Exchange Rates

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Emerging Economies, Trade Policy, and Macroeconomic Shocks

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Working Paper Emerging economies, trade policy, and macroeconomic shocks. Working Paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, No.

Differences in the Determinants and Targeting of Antidumping: China and India Compared

Self-Enforcing Trade Agreements: Evidence from Time-Varying Trade Policy

TEMPORARY TRADE BARRIER IMPLEMENTATION AND MARKET POWER: EVIDENCE FROM LATIN AMERICAN ECONOMIES SAMUEL KENNEY. B.S., Kansas State University, 2013

Wesleyan Economic Working Papers

IS THERE A RISK OF A CREEPING RISE IN TRADE PROTECTIONISM?

Self-Enforcing Trade Agreements

Self-Enforcing Trade Agreements: Evidence from Time-Varying Trade Policy

India: The Use of Temporary Trade Barriers

Trade Liberalization and Antidumping: Is There a Substitution Effect?

Something Fishy: Tariff vs Non-Tariff Barriers in Seafood Trade Kathy Baylis, Lia Nogueira and Kathryn Pace

Trade Liberalization and Antidumping: Is There a Substitution Effect?

China: A Sleeping Giant of Temporary Trade Barriers?

Working Paper No Trade Policy Flexibilities and Turkey: Tariffs, Antidumping, Safeguards, and WTO Dispute Settlement

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

Discussion of Beetsma et al. s The Confidence Channel of Fiscal Consolidation. Lutz Kilian University of Michigan CEPR

Trade Liberalization and Antidumping: Is There a Substitution Effect?

Tariff Liberalization and Increased Administrative Protection: Is There a Quid Pro Quo?

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Twenty-First Century Trade Policy: Pushing the Limits of International Cooperation

Causes of Anti-dumping Actions: Macroeconomics or Retaliation?

Intellectual Property-Related Preferential Trade Agreements and the Composition of Trade

Firm-specific Exchange Rate Shocks and Employment Adjustment: Theory and Evidence

How Do Countries Respond to Trade Disputes? Evidence from. Chinese Exporters

Online Appendices for

Part VII. How Successful Has Inflation Targeting Been?

The Effects of CUSFTA and NAFTA on Antidumping and Countervailing Duty Activity

Protectionism and the Business Cycle

How Different Are Safeguards from Antidumping?

Bank Lending Shocks and the Euro Area Business Cycle

Could tariffs be pro-cyclical?

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

Trade liberalization, Macroeconomic Fluctuations and Contingent Protection in Latin America 1. Universidad Torcuato Di Tella

Is Higher Volatility Associated with Lower Growth? Intranational Evidence from South Korea

Trade Policy, Agreements and Taxation of Multinationals

Do Domestic Chinese Firms Benefit from Foreign Direct Investment?

The Global Resort to Antidumping, Safeguards, and other Trade Remedies amidst the Economic Crisis

Shocks vs Structure:

Forward-Looking Exporters and Exchange Rate Pass-Through

IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY

If the Fed sneezes, who gets a cold?

The Macroeconomic Effects of Protectionism

Perhaps the most striking aspect of the current

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation

Antidumping and Retaliation Threats,

The Global Resort to Antidumping, Safeguards, and other Trade Remedies Amidst the Economic Crisis

TRADE POLICY RESEARCH AS IF THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS REALLY MATTERED

Free Trade Agreements and Trade Disputes

Does Exchange Rate Behavior Change when Interest Rates are Negative? Allaudeen Hameed and Andrew K. Rose*

Liberalization or Protection: Indian Experience in Application of Trade Remedies

Leveraging the WTO System to Get Trade Right

The Inforum LIFT Model: Analysis of Illegal Immigration

The simple monetarist model (inflation as a function of money supply growth and real GDP growth) seems to have been followed by the RBI in its

Outlook for US-China Trade & Investment

Beggar-Thy-Neighbor or Beneficial Spillover: Effect of Exchange Rates on GVC Trade

Global Trade: What s Behind the Slowdown?

Renegotiation of Trade Agreements and Firm Exporting Decisions: Evidence from the Impact of Brexit on UK Exports

Financial Regulation, Banking Integration, and Business Cycle Synchronization

16-12 Preferential Liberalization, Antidumping, and Safeguards: Stumbling Block Evidence from Mercosur

What determines government spending multipliers?

Labor market hierarchies - The impact of labor market dualities on aggregate wage growth. Vienna, November 21, 2017

E Imports and RMB Exchange Rate Pass-Through: Marginal Cost versus Quality Change

The Time Cost of Documents to Trade

DETERMINANTS OF BILATERAL TRADE BETWEEN CHINA AND YEMEN: EVIDENCE FROM VAR MODEL

Really Uncertain Business Cycles

The Impact of U.S. Trade Agreements on Growth in Output and Labor Productivity of FTA Partner Countries

The Short- and Medium-Run Effects of Computerized VAT Invoices on Tax Revenues in China (Very Preliminary)

Preferential Liberalization, Antidumping, and Safeguards

Protectionist Dynamics: Form and Consequences. Simon J. Evenett October 2017

Measuring Economic Policy Uncertainty

Role of international trade rules in the current economic crisis

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

Estimating Trade Restrictiveness Indices

The Run for Safety: Financial Fragility and Deposit Insurance

Exchange Rate Pass-Through, Currency Invoicing and Trade Partners

Regional integration in Asia:

Economic impacts of US tariff increases and retaliations An international perspective. CPB Background Document June 2018

U.S. Trade Policy: Where is it Headed?

Publication of preliminary data on Official Development Assistance, 2011

Sanctuary Markets and Antidumping: An Empirical Analysis of U.S. Exporters

Economic impacts of US tariff increases and retaliations An international perspective. CPB Background Document November 2018

Effectiveness of macroprudential and capital flow measures in Asia and the Pacific 1

Relationships among Exchange Rates, Inflation, and Interest Rates

The effect of economic policy uncertainty on bank valuations

The Distributive Impact of Reforms in Credit Enforcement: Evidence from Indian Debt Recovery Tribunals

Does Antidumping Cause Investment and R&D? : Evidence from a developing country

PROMOTING HUMAN DEVELOPMENT IN TRADE NEGOTIATIONS: AN ACTION PLAN FOR CAMBODIA

Chinese Trade Reforms, Market Access and Foreign Competition

Summary of: Trade Liberalization, Profitability, and Financial Leverage

HOW EFFECTIVE ARE REWARDS PROGRAMS IN PROMOTING PAYMENT CARD USAGE? EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

IV. THE BENEFITS OF FURTHER FINANCIAL INTEGRATION IN ASIA

Test of an Inverted J-Shape Hypothesis between the Expected Real Exchange Rate and Real Output: The Case of Ireland. Yu Hsing 1

Progress towards Strong, Sustainable and Balanced Growth. Figure 1: Recovery from Financial Crisis (100 = First Quarter of Real GDP Contraction)

Protectionist threats. jeopardise international trade

Transcription:

Import Protection, Business Cycles, and Exchange Rates: Evidence from the Great Recession Chad P. Bown The World Bank Meredith A. Crowley Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Preliminary, comments welcome Any views expressed in this paper are personal and should not be attributed to the World Bank or the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.

Conventional wisdom: Motivation Import tariffs and other trade barriers rise during periods of macroeconomic weakness and crisis Great Depression: US Smoot-Hawley tariffs and the 193s retaliatory response by US trading partners (Irwin 211a,b) During the Great Recession? Industrialized economies: no large scale tariff hikes or quantitative restrictions on the scale of the 193s Bown (211a): substantial trade policy churning through antidumping, global safeguards, China-specific safeguards, and countervailing duties E.g., United States: 23 percent increase in the stock of trade barriers by the end of 21 relative to the pre-crisis (27) level. By 21, over 5 percent of US 6-digit Harmonized System (HS) imported products were subject to these temporary trade barriers, so this is an economically important policy

Great Recession However, given the severity of macroeconomic shocks that took place during the Great Recession, open research questions include (1) What explains the import protection that did arise? (2) Why was the trade policy response to the Great Recession relatively mild? This paper s question What was the impact of macroeconomic fluctuations on import protection activity during the Great Recession for 5 industrialized economies? United States, Canada, European Union, Korea, Australia This paper s approach 1. We estimate models of import protection as a function of macroeconomic fluctuations prior to the crisis (1988:Q1-28:Q3) 2. We use those models to predict out-of-sample import protection activity for 28:Q4-21:Q4, which we compared to realized import protection 3. We re-estimate the models on the longer sample (through 21:Q4) and test for changes in the responsiveness of import protection to macroeconomic shocks across the two periods

Motivation based on the forms of Import Protection in use by Industrialized Economies under the WTO Figure 1. Import Protection, Real Exchange Rates, and Recessions, 1988-21 number of unique HS6 products 14 12 1 8 6 4 2 USA RXR index 12 115 11 15 1 95 9 85 1988 89 9 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 2 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 AD initiations All initiations RXR index, 1998=1 8

Figure 1. Import Protection, Real Exchange Rates, and Recessions, 1988-21 number of unique HS6 products 45 4 35 3 25 2 15 1 5 Canada RXR index 15 14 13 12 11 1 1988 89 9 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 2 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 AD initiations All initiations RXR index, 1998=1 9

Figure 1. Import Protection, Real Exchange Rates, and Recessions, 1999-21 number of unique HS6 products 1 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 European Union RXR index 12 115 11 15 1 95 9 85 1999 2 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 AD initiations All initiations RXR index, 1998=1 8

Figure 1. Import Protection, Real Exchange Rates, and Recessions, 1988-21 number of unique HS6 products 35 3 25 2 15 1 5 Korea RXR index 15 14 13 12 11 1 9 8 1989 9 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 2 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 AD initiations All initiations RXR index, 1998=1 7

Figure 1. Import Protection, Real Exchange Rates, and Recessions, 1988-21 number of unique HS6 products 35 3 25 2 15 1 5 Australia RXR index 16 15 14 13 12 11 1 9 1989 9 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 2 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 AD initiations All initiations RXR index, 1998=1 8

Historical models This paper s results Bilateral real exchange rate appreciations lead to more import protection 4 percent appreciation in the bilateral real exchange rate relative to the mean level results in a policyimposing country subjecting 6-9 percent more products to these forms of import protection Periods of foreign (trading partner) macroeconomic weakness lead to more import protection against them One standard deviation fall in foreign real GDP growth results in a policy-imposing country subjecting greater than 1 percent more products to these forms of import protection Great Recession Out-of-sample predictions: Historical models over-predict new import restrictions for 28:Q4-21:Q4 for US, Canada, and Korea and under-predict for EU and Australia Re-estimated models on data through 21:Q4, testing for crisis-period changes to import protection responsiveness to macroeconomic shocks While bilateral real exchange rate appreciations still lead to more import protection, the estimated responsiveness is smaller than historically US and other economies switched from their historical behavior and shifted implementing new import protection away from those trading partners that were contracting and toward those experiencing economic growth China-specific results A 9-2 percent appreciation of China s real bilateral exchange rate would provide it with equal treatment under US antidumping

Previous Literature 1. Theoretical models that include exceptions e.g., antidumping, safeguards, countervailing duties in trade agreements Bagwell and Staiger (199, 22, 23) self-enforcing trade agreements in the presence of shocks Brander and Krugman (1983), Knetter and Prusa (23), Crowley (211) 2. Empirical literature estimates macroeconomic influence on antidumping filings using data from the 198s and 199s Feinberg (1989) for 1982-87 US data, exchange rate depreciations lead to more AD Knetter and Prusa (23) for 198-98, US, Canada, Australia, EU exchange rate appreciations in general lead to more AD protection Irwin (25) for 1947-22 for US, evidence consistent with Knetter and Prusa (23) Our approach in addition to estimating on data extended through the 2s, also includes advances, extensions and refinements to the previous literature Detailed policy data improves measurement; inclusion of additional policies Higher frequency macroeconomic data, better address timing issues of linkages Focus on bilateral (real exchange rate and foreign GDP growth) channels that are potentially import influences on bilateral, discriminatory policies such as antidumping

Estimation procedure and data Estimate counts of products subject to new investigations under TTBs Negative binomial regression model with trading partner fixed effects Panel data: For each policy-imposing economy, start with 138 observations, panel (it) of policy-imposing economy trade policy actions against trading partner i (15 top countries) in quarter t (1988:Q1-21:Q4) Dependent variable: Count of 6-digit Harmonized System (HS) products subject to new TTB investigations per trading partner per quarter Common definition across investigations, countries, policies, time Trade policy data is carefully constructed from Temporary Trade Barriers Database (Bown, 211) Explanatory variables: Bilateral real exchange rate, end of period [USDA Economic Research Service] Domestic real GDP growth, annualized [IFS, OECD and national sources] Foreign real GDP growth, annualized [IFS, OECD and national sources] Implementation of lag-structure for explanatory variables: Three lags (t-1, t-2, t-3) for each explanatory variable; AIC and BIC model selection tests most consistently prefer use of three lags (though not without exception) so we use three lags throughout for consistency

Results: Historical Model Estimates Prior to the Crisis Table 2. Negative Binomial Model Estimates of Country Use of Import Protection, 1988:Q1-28:Q3 Dependent variable: Count of products initiated under either all temporary trade barrier policies or AD policy only Explanatory variables USA AD only USA All policies Bilateral real exchange rate 22.798*** 34.556*** (4.93) (5.64) Domestic real GDP growth.985.921 (.29) (1.43) Foreign real GDP growth.942**.94*** (2.12) (3.62) Time trend.974***.972*** (5.61) (6.9) Foreign country effects yes yes Observations 192 192 Number of trading partners 15 15 Notes: Distributed lag model with three lags of quarterly data for each of the explanatory variables of interest. Incidence Rate Ratios (IRRs) of long-run effects reported in lieu of coefficient estimates, with t-statistics in parentheses. Model includes a constant term whose estimate is suppressed. ***, **, and * indicate statistically significant at the 1 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively Interpretation As is conventional in these count models, we report Incidence Rate Ratios (IRRs) and t- statistics (in parentheses) of the test of no effect which corresponds to an IRR of 1. IRR estimate > 1 is positive effect; IRR estimate < 1 is negative effect

Historical Model: How large (economically) are these effects? Exercise 1. Evaluate the model at the means of the data to establish the baseline 2. Ceteris paribus, document the impact on the import protection response for a one standard deviation shock to each explanatory variable, introduced quarter-by-quarter

25 2 15 1 5 Historical Model: How large (economically) are these effects? Q Q1 Q2 Q3 25 2 15 1 5 USA: AD only Import Protection Index (Q=1) Bilateral RXR Appreciation Domestic RGDP Contraction Foreign RGDP Contraction USA: All policies 25 2 15 1 5 Import Protection Index (Q=1) 25 2 15 1 5 USA 1. After 3 quarters, a 4% real appreciation of the US dollar is associated with 76 percent more products subject to AD (Table 2, first column) 91 percent more products subject to import protection overall (second column) 2. Negative Shock to foreign GDP growth is associated with 54-16 percent more import protection 3. Negative Shock to US GDP growth is associated with 4-22 percent more import protection per partner Q Q1 Q2 Q3 Bilateral RXR Appreciation Domestic RGDP Contraction Foreign RGDP Contraction

Results: Historical Model Estimates Prior to the Crisis Table 2. Negative Binomial Model Estimates of Country Use of Import Protection, 1988:Q1-28:Q3 Explanatory variables Dependent variable: Count of products initiated under either all temporary trade barrier policies or AD policy only USA USA CAN CAN EU EU KOR KOR AUS AUS AD All AD All AD All AD All AD All only policies only policies only policies only policies only policies Bilateral real exchange rate 22.798*** 34.556*** 18.586* 15.749* 22.624*** 1.7 21.768* 32.158**.92.885 (4.93) (5.64) (1.82) (1.92) (2.94) (.6) (1.92) (2.28) (.19) (.23) Domestic real GDP growth.985.921 1.264** 1.246** 1.19.34***.992 1.84.868***.87*** (.29) (1.43) (2.34) (2.42) (.13) (7.73) (.13) (1.43) (3.74) (3.69) Foreign real GDP growth.942**.94***.899*.917* 1.14 1.22.95.89.976.983 (2.12) (3.62) (1.94) (1.76) (.29) (.4) (1.14) (1.49) (1.3) (.73) Time trend.974***.972***.977***.991.959***.943*** 1.4*** 1.33***.977***.979*** (5.61) (6.9) (2.62) (1.17) (3.26) (4.13) (4.16) (3.61) (6.55) (5.93) Foreign country effects yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes Observations 192 192 192 192 585 585 852 852 129 129 Number of trading partners 15 15 15 15 15 15 12 12 15 15 Notes: Distributed lag model with three lags of quarterly data for each of the explanatory variables of interest. Incidence Rate Ratios (IRRs) of long-run effects reported in lieu of coefficient estimates, with t-statistics in parentheses. Model includes a constant term whose estimate is suppressed. ***, **, and * indicate statistically significant at the 1 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively. EU data for 1999:Q1-28:Q3 only.

Historical Model: How large (economically) are these effects? 25 2 15 1 5 Q Q1 Q2 Q3 2 18 16 14 12 1 8 6 4 2 Canada: AD only Import Protection Index (Q=1) Bilateral RXR Appreciation Domestic RGDP Contraction Foreign RGDP Contraction Canada: All policies Q Q1 Q2 Q3 25 2 15 1 5 Import Protection Index (Q=1) 2 18 16 14 12 1 8 6 4 2 Canada 1. After 3 quarters, a 4% real appreciation of the Canadian dollar is associated with 64 percent more products subject to AD (Table 2, first column) 59 percent more products subject to import protection overall (second column) 2. Negative Shock to foreign GDP growth is associated with 87-114 percent more import protection Bilateral RXR Appreciation Domestic RGDP Contraction Foreign RGDP Contraction

Historical Model: How large (economically) are these effects? 3 25 2 15 1 5 European Union: AD only Import Protection Index (Q=1) Q Q1 Q2 Q3 3 25 2 15 1 5 European Union 1. After 3 quarters, a 4% real appreciation of the Euro is associated with 67 percent more products subject to AD (Table 2, first column) Bilateral RXR Appreciation Domestic RGDP Contraction Foreign RGDP Contraction 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 European Union: All policies Import Protection Index (Q=1) 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 Q Q1 Q2 Q3 Bilateral RXR Appreciation Domestic RGDP Contraction Foreign RGDP Contraction

Historical Model: How large (economically) are these effects? 18 16 14 12 1 8 6 4 2 Q Q1 Q2 Q3 25 2 Korea: AD only Import Protection Index (Q=1) Bilateral RXR Appreciation Domestic RGDP Contraction Foreign RGDP Contraction Korea: All policies 18 16 14 12 1 8 6 4 2 Import Protection Index (Q=1) 25 2 Korea 1. After 3 quarters, a 4% real appreciation of the South Korean won is associated with 68 percent more products subject to AD (Table 2, first column) 79 percent more products subject to import protection overall (second column) 2. Negative Shock to foreign GDP growth is associated with 66-82 percent more import protection 15 15 1 1 5 5 Q Q1 Q2 Q3 Bilateral RXR Appreciation Domestic RGDP Contraction Foreign RGDP Contraction

Historical Model: How large (economically) are these effects? 16 14 12 1 8 6 4 2 Australia: AD only Import Protection Index (Q=1) 16 14 12 1 8 6 4 2 Australia 1. Negative Shock to Australia s GDP growth is associated with 43-44 percent more import protection per partner Q Q1 Q2 Q3 Bilateral RXR Appreciation Domestic RGDP Contraction Foreign RGDP Contraction 16 14 12 1 8 6 4 2 Australia: All policies Import Protection Index (Q=1) 16 14 12 1 8 6 4 2 Q Q1 Q2 Q3 Bilateral RXR Appreciation Domestic RGDP Contraction Foreign RGDP Contraction

Out of Sample Prediction based on the Historical Model: How much import protection was expected to arise and how does it compare to the realized response? Exercise 1. Take the historical model estimates of Table 2/Table 4 2. Predict out-of-sample import protection response for 28:Q4-21:Q4 based on realized shocks to bilateral real exchange rates, domestic GDP growth, foreign GDP growth taking place during the Great Recession 3. Compare this to actual, realized import protection taking place during 28:Q4-21:Q4

Great Recession: Out-of-Sample Prediction and Comparison number of unique HS6 products 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 USA 28: Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 29: Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 21: Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Predicted (Total=233) Actual (Total=94) 1. Historical model over-predicts import protection by 15 percent more products overall for 28:Q4-21:Q4. 2. Delay / Shifting of import protection response from expected 28:Q4-29:Q1 surge to realized 29:Q3 spike 3. How did the import protection responsiveness of policymakers to macroeconomic shocks change during the crisis? Next: Re-estimate the model on longer time series of data (through 21:Q4) and test for differential effects across periods

Results: Historical vs. Crisis Estimates Table 4. Differential Impacts on Policy Response during the Great Recession Dependent variable: Count of products initiated under all temporary trade barrier policies Explanatory Variables USA Bilateral real exchange rate, 1988:Q1-28:Q3 32.46*** (5.63) Bilateral real exchange rate, 28:Q4-21:Q4 15.439*** (4.17) [Test statistic] [2.31]*** Domestic real GDP growth, 1988:Q1-28:Q3.924 (1.38) Domestic real GDP growth, 28:Q4-21:Q4.727** (1.96) [Test statistic] [1.92] Foreign real GDP growth, 1988:Q1-28:Q3.892*** (4.1) Foreign real GDP growth, 28:Q4-21:Q4 1.187** (2.1) [Test statistic] [11.81]*** Time trend.971*** (6.25) Foreign country effects yes Observations 1224 Number of trading partners 15 Interpretation: USA 1. Even during the crisis a real appreciation of the US dollar is associated with more import protection However, the smaller IRR indicates the US was less responsive to appreciations relative to historical period 2. Foreign GDP growth: a switch in behavior more import protection likely against trading partners that are growing is different from historically, when import protection was more likely against those with macroeconomic weakness During the crisis, very few partners were growing so there was less US import protection overall Similar patterns for Canada and the European Union

Great Recession: Out-of-Sample Prediction and Comparison number of unique HS6 products 18 16 14 12 1 8 6 4 2 28: Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Canada 29: Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 21: Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Predicted (Total=63) Actual (Total=19) Historical model over-predicts import protection by 23 percent more products overall for 28:Q4-21:Q4.

Great Recession: Out-of-Sample Prediction and Comparison number of unique HS6 products 45 4 35 3 25 2 15 1 5 28: Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 European Union 29: Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 21: Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Predicted (Total=6) Actual (Total=84) 1. Historical model under-predicts import protection by 29 percent fewer products overall for 28:Q4-21:Q4. 2. Delay / Shifting of import protection response from expected 29:Q1 surge to realized 21:Q2 spike

Great Recession: Out-of-Sample Prediction and Comparison number of unique HS6 products 4 35 3 25 2 15 1 5 28: Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Korea 29: Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 21: Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Predicted (Total=114) Actual (Total=3) Historical model over-predicts import protection by 3698 percent more products overall for 28:Q4-21:Q4.

Table 4. Differential Impacts on Policy Response during the Great Recession Dependent variable: Count of products initiated under all temporary trade barrier policies Explanatory Variables USA CAN EU, KOR AUS Bilateral real exchange rate, 1988:Q1-28:Q3 32.46*** 1.9* 8.964** 37.33**.63 (5.63) (1.74) (2.21) (2.4) (.94) Bilateral real exchange rate, 28:Q4-21:Q4 15.439*** 5.52 6.653* 1.83.568 (4.17) (1.22) (1.87) (.2) (1.1) [Test statistic] [2.31]*** [7.18]*** [2.32] [.8] [.13] Domestic real GDP growth, 1988:Q1-28:Q3.924 1.242** 1.36 1.84.866*** (1.38) (2.43) (.25) (1.44) (3.63) Domestic real GDP growth, 28:Q4-21:Q4.727**.577 1.38 1.98 1.173 (1.96) (1.48) (.34) (.5) (.46) [Test statistic] [1.92] [3.96]** [.] [.2] [.75] Foreign real GDP growth, 1988:Q1-28:Q3.892***.913**.985.893.985 (4.1) (1.91) (.35) (1.47) (.63) Foreign real GDP growth, 28:Q4-21:Q4 1.187** 1.265 1.164.63 1.21 (2.1) (1.56) (1.62) (.55) (.44) [Test statistic] [11.81]*** [4.64]** [3.18]* [.17] [.55] Time trend.971***.99.964*** 1.33***.977*** (6.25) (1.25) (2.94) (3.68) (6.29) Foreign country effects yes yes yes yes yes Observations 1224 1224 717 957 1161 Number of trading partners 15 15 15 12 15 Notes: Distributed lag model with three lags of quarterly data for each of the explanatory variables of interest. Incidence Rate Ratios (IRRs) of long-run effects reported in lieu of coefficient estimates, with t-statistics in parentheses. Model includes a constant term whose estimate is suppressed. ***, **, and * indicate statistically significant at the 1 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively. AUS and EU estimates based on dependent variable of antidumping policy only. EU pre-crisis data for 1999:Q1-28:Q3 only.

China-specific Concerns, Controls, and Exercise Potential Estimation Concerns Since 21, these forms of import protection are disproportionately applied to imports from China (see Bown, 21, for an explanation) Bown (211): for the entire stock of all accumulated barriers in place, those against China ranged from a low of 21 percent (United States) to a high of 44 percent (Australia) in 29, up from a range of only 8 percent (United States) to 2 percent (Korea) in 1997 Exercise 1. Interact explanatory variables with China or non-china interaction terms to test for a differential impact of China 2. We can also use this to examine the relationship between US-China real exchange rates and import protection Data for China/non-China: China s products face three times as many new trade barriers per quarter relative to the sample average for non-china US-China bilateral real exchange rate is only half as volatile as US- non-china bilateral real exchange rate in the data Challenge for identification Careful interpreting size and magnitude of IRRs

Table 6. China versus Other Targets, 1988:Q1-21:Q4 Dependent variable: Count of products initiated under all temporary trade barrier policies Explanatory Variables USA USA Bilateral real exchange rate, non-china 45.76*** 77.13*** (6.93) (7.18) Bilateral real exchange rate, China 13.673*** 4.672 (2.78) (.33) [Test statistic] [2.2] [.35] Domestic real GDP growth, non-china.939.934 (1.4) (1.51) Domestic real GDP growth, China.863.863 (.87) (.92) [Test statistic] [.23] [.22] Foreign real GDP growth, non-china.955**.926*** (1.96) (2.79) Foreign real GDP growth, China.878.882 (.92) (.93) [Test statistic] [.34] [.12] Time trend, non-china.963***.962*** (8.67) (8.55) Time trend, China 1.9 1.7 (.51) (.38) [Test statistic] [6.41]** [5.78]** Foreign country effects no yes Observations 1224 1224 Trading partners 15 15 Interpretation: USA Note: Even though point estimates not statistically different from one another, interpret magnitudes as if they were 1. IRR of 46 for non-china is evidence that a 4 percent appreciation of the dollar (a one standard deviation shock on the non-china sample) is a 5 percent increase in protection 2. IRR of 14 for China is evidence that a 1.9 percent appreciation of the dollar (a one standard deviation shock on the China sample) is a 28 percent increase in protection However, a 4 percent appreciation in the US bilateral real exchange rate with respect to China would lead to a 72 percent more protection Final Thought Experiment: What would it take for China to have received normal treatment? Model implies that a 9-2 percent appreciation of the Chinese real exchange rate against the dollar during this period would reduce` the new import protection against China (from the prediction at the means of the data) to the prediction for the other countries at the means of that subsample of data

Historical models Conclusions Bilateral real exchange rate appreciations lead to more import protection 4 percent appreciation in the bilateral real exchange rate relative to the mean level results in a policyimposing country subjecting 6-9 percent more products to these forms of import protection Periods of foreign (trading partner) macroeconomic weakness lead to more import protection against them One standard deviation fall in foreign real GDP growth results in a policy-imposing country subjecting greater than 1 percent more products to these forms of import protection Great Recession Out-of-sample predictions: Historical models over-predict new import restrictions for 28:Q4-21:Q4 for US, Canada, and Korea and under-predict for EU and Australia Re-estimated models on data through 21:Q4, testing for crisis-period changes to import protection responsiveness to macroeconomic shocks While bilateral real exchange rate appreciations still lead to more import protection, the estimated responsiveness is smaller than historically US and other economies switched from their historical behavior and shifted implementing new import protection away from those trading partners that were contracting and toward those experiencing economic growth China-specific results A 9-2 percent appreciation of China s real bilateral exchange rate would provide it with equal treatment under US antidumping