Implications of Increases in Life Expectancy for Policy

Similar documents
Corrigendum. OECD Pensions Outlook 2012 DOI: ISBN (print) ISBN (PDF) OECD 2012

Statistical annex. Sources and definitions

Low employment among the 50+ population in Hungary

American healthcare: How do we measure up?

American healthcare: How do we measure up?

PENSIONS IN OECD COUNTRIES: INDICATORS AND DEVELOPMENTS

Statistical Annex ANNEX

8-Jun-06 Personal Income Top Marginal Tax Rate,

Burden of Taxation: International Comparisons

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2016

Approach to Employment Injury (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD

10% 10% 15% 15% Caseload: WE. 15% Caseload: SS 10% 10% 15%

Work Capacity of Older Workers: Canada and the United States

HEALTH LABOUR MARKET TRENDS IN OECD COUNTRIES

Ageing and employment policies: Ireland

Annuities: a private solution to longevity risk

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2017

Decumulation debate. New Zealand Society of Actuaries Financial Services Forum 16 November 2015

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2018

Statistical Annex. Sources and definitions

OECD Report Shows Tax Burdens Falling in Many OECD Countries

The OECD s Society at a Glance Simon Chapple OECD ELS/SPD Villa Vigoni, Italy, 9-11 th March 2011

Household Financial Wealth By Selected Country

TAXATION OF TRUSTS IN ISRAEL. An Opportunity For Foreign Residents. Dr. Avi Nov

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2014

The Case for Fundamental Tax Reform: Overview of the Current Tax System

Recommendation of the Council on Tax Avoidance and Evasion

Recommendation of the Council on the Implementation of the Polluter-Pays Principle

Sources of Government Revenue across the OECD, 2015

STATISTICS. Taxing Wages DIS P O NIB LE E N SPECIAL FEATURE: PART-TIME WORK AND TAXING WAGES

Switzerland and Germany top the PwC Young Workers Index in developing younger people

COMPARISON OF RIA SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES

FCCC/SBI/2010/10/Add.1

OECD HEALTH SYSTEM CHARACTERISTICS SURVEY 2012

THE NEED FOR MORE SOCIAL SECURITY AND SECURE PENSIONS

Public Financial Management (PFMx) Module

IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY

Performance Budgeting (PB) in OECD Countries

Reporting practices for domestic and total debt securities

Private pensions. A growing role. Who has a private pension?

Glossary of Defined Terms

Health Care in Crisis

A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD, 2017

Guidance on Transfer Pricing Documentation and Country-by-Country Reporting

Pension Fund Investment and Regulation - An International Perspective and Implications for China s Pension System

Ways to increase employment

DFA Global Equity Portfolio (Class F) Quarterly Performance Report Q2 2014

Fiscal Projections in OECD Countries: What is produced and what lessons can be learned?

The Socialist Federal Republic of Yugoslavia takes part in some of the work of the OECD (agreement of 28th October 1961).

Workforce participation of mature aged women

OECD HEALTH DATA 2012 DISSEMINATION AND RESULTS. Marie-Clémence Canaud OECD Health Data National Correspondents Meeting October 12, 2012

Investing for our Future Welfare. Peter Whiteford, ANU

DFA Global Equity Portfolio (Class F) Performance Report Q2 2017

DFA Global Equity Portfolio (Class F) Performance Report Q3 2018

DFA Global Equity Portfolio (Class F) Performance Report Q4 2017

Summary of key findings

DFA Global Equity Portfolio (Class F) Performance Report Q3 2015

TAX POLICY CENTER BRIEFING BOOK. Background. Q. What are the sources of revenue for the federal government?

Third Revised Decision of the Council concerning National Treatment

Double-Taxing Capital Income: How Bad Is the Problem?

Rising Inequality in Life Expectancy by Socioeconomic Status

Long Term Reform Agenda International Perspective

Table 1: Foreign exchange turnover: Summary of surveys Billions of U.S. dollars. Number of business days

LONG-TERM PROJECTIONS OF PUBLIC PENSION EXPENDITURE

REFORMING PENSION SYSTEMS: THE OECD EXPERIENCE

Fiscal Policy in Japan

Income and Longevity: Implications for Retirement and Disability Programs

Finally arriving? Pension Reforms in Europe

Implementing ICP Recommendations Financing The Road To Prosperity. Paul Daniel Muller. President Montreal Economic Institute

Second Quarter Trading Update 9 July 2010

The Outlook for the U.S. Economy and the Policies of the New President

Investment in Health is investment in wealth: the positive dimension of healthcare K. Panagoulias, Al.President SFEE

DEMOGRAPHICS AND MACROECONOMICS

Public Pension Spending Trends and Outlook in Emerging Europe. Benedict Clements Fiscal Affairs Department International Monetary Fund March 2013

COVERAGE OF PRIVATE PENSION SYSTEMS AND MAIN TRENDS IN THE PENSIONS INDUSTRY IN THE OECD

Declaration on Environmental Policy

BETTER POLICIES FOR A SUCCESSFUL TRANSITION TO A LOW-CARBON ECONOMY

Introduction to Public Finance

Updates and revisions of national SUTs for the November 2013 release of the WIOD

DEVELOPMENT AID AT A GLANCE

2018 INTERNATIONAL CONFERENCE ON MUNICIPAL FISCAL HEALTH U.S. Tax Reform and Its Impact on State and Local Government Finance Presented by Jane L.

International comparison of poverty amongst the elderly

Programme for Government Joe Reynolds Director Programme for Government and Delivering Social Change

Rev. Proc Implementation of Nonresident Alien Deposit Interest Regulations

Pension reforms. Early birds and laggards

OECD Health Policy Unit. 10 June, 2001

Outlook Overview: OECD Countries UN LINK Conference, Bangkok October, 2009

Trade and Development Board Sixty-first session. Geneva, September 2014

Improving data on pharmaceuticals. Meeting of OECD Health Data National Correspondents 3-4 october 2011

Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to 0.4% in the third quarter of 2016

FEES SCHEDULE (COPPER / GOLD)

Priorities for Productivity and Income (PPIs) Country Results

Earnings related schemes: Design, options and experience. Edward Whitehouse

FEES SCHEDULE (SILVER/PLATINUM)

2018 Global Survey of Accounting Assumptions. for Defined Benefit Plans. Executive summary

San Francisco Retiree Health Care Trust Fund Education Materials on Public Equity

International Statistical Release

Key Issues in the Design of Capital Gains Tax Regimes: Taxing Non- Residents. 18 July 2014

Behaviour in Business A Guide to Integrity in Business Transactions

Breakdown of key aggregates at the sub-national level

Transcription:

Implications of Increases in Life Expectancy for Policy By Hilary Waldron, Social Security Administration Adapted from Waldron (2007), Trends in Mortality Differentials and Life Expectancy for Male Social Security-Covered Workers, by Socioeconomic Status, Social Security Bulletin, Vol. 67, No. 3. Waldron (2004), Heterogeneity in Health and Retirement Risk Among Early Retiree Men, ORES Working Paper, No. 105. http://www.ssa.gov/policy/authors/waldronhilary.html

Analysts frequently make policy prescriptions based on measures of improvement in average health and longevity over time. (Legislation passed in 1982 is increasing Social Security s NRA to age 67; the early retirement age remains at age 62.) o Proposals to link Social Security s full retirement age to increases in average longevity (Reform Model 3-President s Comm. to Strengthen Social Security (2001); National Commission on Retirement Policy (1999), Advisory Council on Social Security (1997), Option II). o Proposals to raise Social Security s early retirement age higher than age 62 to adjust for improvements in average health and longevity (S.825,H.R.3758,S.321,H.R.2782,H.R.3082, H.R.251, H.R.1793).

But can policy makers rely on measures of average longevity when making decisions? To determine I look at: Trends in male life expectancy by socioeconomic status Differences in health and longevity by the age at which men claim Social Security retired worker benefits.

Previous Literature First half of the 20 th century: mortality differentials by socioeconomic status narrowed sometime between 1900 and the 1930s or 1940s (Antonovsky(1967), Kitagawa and Hauser(1973), Pamuk (1985)). 2 nd half of the 20 th century: mortality differentials by socioeconomic status widened from around the 1950s or 1960s through the 1990s (Feldman(1989), Pappas(1993), Preston and Elo (1995), Singh and Siahpush (2002), Waldron (2004)).

My Sample Birth cohorts 1912-1941 Deaths at ages 60-89 (in years 1972-2001) Men in SSA s active Continuous Work History 1% Sample (longitudinal earnings data) matched to SSA death data I measure the average of each man s non-zero earnings from ages 45 through 55. About 15% of sample dropped because they had no earnings from ages 45-55. This means my sample is expected to be selectively healthier than the general population. Divided men into two groups for analysis: top and bottom half of lifetime earnings distributions for each man s birth cohort. Compared odds of death by age and year of birth for the bottom half of the earnings distribution vs the top half (discrete-time logistic regressions).

Table 1. Odds Ratios (confidence intervals) for the bottom half of the earnings distribution vs the top half Deaths occuring at ages: 60 to 64 65 to 69 70 to 74 75 to 79 80 to 84 85 to 89 Years of birth 1912-1915 1.27 (1.19--1.35)* 1.24 (1.17-1.31)* 1.20 (1.13--1.26)* 1.13 (1.07--1.19)* 1.09 (1.03--1.15)* 0.94 (0.88--1.00)** 1916-1919 1.51 (1.42--1.62)* 1.36 (1.29--1.44)* 1.34 (1.27--1.41)* 1.20 (1.14--1.27)* 1.05 (0.99-1.11) n.a 1920-1923 1.50 (1.40--1.60)* 1.40 (1.32--1.48)* 1.34 (1.27--1.41)* 1.31 (1.24--1.38)* n.a. n.a 1924-1927 1.51 (1.41--1.62)* 1.53 (1.44--1.63)* 1.48 (1.41--1.57)* n.a. n.a n.a 1928-1931 1932-1935 1.71 (1.59--1.84)* 1.75 (1.62--1.89)* 1.61 (1.51--1.71)* n.a. n.a n.a n.a 1.73 (1.59--1.88)* n.a n.a n.a n.a 1936-1938 1.84 (1.68--2.03)* n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a Source: Author's calculations on a matched 2001 CWHS.

Cohort life expectancy projections To estimate cohort life expectancies, mortality differentials by socioeconomic status must be projected into the future. The younger the birth cohort, the more years of life must be projected. Projection assumes the mortality patterns observed for the last third of the twentieth century continue for the next thirty years. Projects the widening of mortality risk by birth cohort and the narrowing of mortality risk by age observed empirically into the future The discrete-time logistic regression equation follows the following form: dead (coded as 1 or 0) = intercept + B1(age) + B2(year of birth) + B3(age*year of birth) + B4(earnings dummy) + B5(age*earnings dummy) + B6(year of birth*earnings dummy) + B7(age*year of birth*earnings dummy) + error term.

Chart 3. Cohort life expectancy at age 65 (and 95 percent confidence intervals) for male Social Security covered workers, by selected birth years and earnings group Years of life expectancy at age 65 23 22 21 20 19 18 17 16 15 14 Earnings in top half of distribution Earnings in bottom half of the distribution 1912 1917 1922 1927 1932 1937 1941 Year

Table 9. Male period life expectancy in 2000 in years by country and age Males at age 60 Males at age 65 Males at age 80 Iceland 22.2 Iceland 18.1 Mexico 8.7 Japan 21.4 Japan 17.5 Iceland 8.4 U.S. 4th Q 21.3 U.S. 4th Q 17.0 Japan 8.0 Switzerland 20.9 Australia 16.9 Canada 7.8 Australia 20.8 Canada 16.9 Australia 7.6 Canada 20.7 Switzerland 16.9 France 7.6 Sweden 20.7 Mexico 16.8 United States (OECD) 7.6 U.S. 3rd Q 20.5 France 16.7 New Zealand 7.4 France 20.4 Sweden 16.7 Switzerland 7.4 Italy 20.4 Italy 16.5 Italy 7.3 New Zealand 20.3 New Zealand 16.5 Spain 7.3 Spain 20.3 Spain 16.5 U.S. 1st Q 7.2 Mexico 20.2 U.S. 3rd Q 16.5 United States (OCACT) 7.2 Norway 20.0 United States (OECD) 16.3 Sweden 7.1 United States (OECD) 19.9 Austria 16.0 Austria 7.0 Austria 19.7 Norway 16.0 Germany 7.0 United States (OCACT) 19.4 United States (OCACT) 15.8 U.S. 3rd Q 7.0 Germany 19.4 Germany 15.7 United Kingdom 6.9 United Kingdom 19.4 United Kingdom 15.7 Denmark 6.8 Belgium 19.3 Belgium 15.5 U.S. 4th Q 6.8 Finland 19.2 Finland 15.5 Belgium 6.7 Luxembourg 19.2 Luxembourg 15.5 Norway 6.7 Netherlands 19.1 Netherlands 15.3 Finland 6.6 Portugal 19.0 Portugal 15.3 U.S. 2nd Q 6.6 Denmark 18.9 Denmark 15.2 Luxembourg 6.5 U.S. 2nd Q 18.7 U.S. 2nd Q 15.0 Poland 6.5 Ireland 18.4 U.S. 1st Q 14.7 Netherlands 6.4 U.S. 1st Q 18.0 Ireland 14.6 Portugal 6.4 Czech Republic 17.0 Czech Republic 13.7 Czech Republic 6.1 Poland 16.7 Poland 13.6 Ireland 6.1 Slovak Republic 15.9 Slovak Republic 12.9 Slovak Republic 6.1 Turkey 15.9 Hungary 12.7 Hungary 6.0 Hungary 15.5 Turkey 12.6 Turkey 5.3 Source: Copyright OECD HEALTH DATA 2004, 1st edition. United States estimates for male Social Security covered worker earnings quartiles and SSA's OACT estimates, based on the intermediate assumptions of the 2004 Trustees Report, added by the author.

Male birth cohorts 1908-1931, surviving to age 65, years of death 1973-1997 Social Security data matched to Census data shows that who retire early are in poorer health and die sooner than men who retire at the Full Retirement Age. Mortality risk by age of retirement is a gradient, even after controlling for earnings, education, and race (i.e. variables correlated with economic/non-health reasons for early retirement). Odds of dying, relative to AGE65 retirement Before economic/demog. controls After economic/demog. controls Econ/demog controls AGE62A 1.43* AGE62A 1.33* Earn1 1.19* vs. top 25th% AGE62B 1.29* AGE62B 1.20* Earn2 1.07 vs. top 25th% AGE63 1.23* AGE63 1.16* Earn3 1.11* vs. top 25th% AGE64 1.15* AGE64 1.10** < H.S. 1.35* vs. college grad. H.S. grad 1.15* vs. college grad. African-American 1.19* vs. all other races Source: ORES WP 105, Tables 14, 16.

Conclusions This research suggests there may be too much heterogeneity in the U.S. population to use average health and longevity as a meaningful policy variable. Policy proposals based on average longevity assumptions could have unexpected results. Low earners have a higher risk of poor health and death than high earners and are more likely to claim benefits early; however high earners who claim benefits early also have higher mortality risk than low earners claiming benefits at age 65. Claiming behavior may be rational claimers could be acting in their own best interest in terms of longevity expectations. Unlike the conventional wisdom held by some proponents of raising the EEA, I do not observe a bimodal distribution (a small group in poor health and a homogenous majority in good health). Instead I observe gradients in health and mortality. Gradients suggest proposals to make policy changes based on average longevity gains and then target a severely disadvantaged group to ease the policy change could be based on an inaccurate reading of the spread of health and mortality outcomes within the U.S. population.