Recent Advances in Fractional Stochastic Volatility Models

Similar documents
Fractional Stochastic Volatility Models

Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management

Rough Heston models: Pricing, hedging and microstructural foundations

How persistent and regular is really volatility? The Rough FSV model. Jim Gatheral, Thibault Jaisson and Mathieu Rosenbaum. Monday 17 th November 2014

How to hedge Asian options in fractional Black-Scholes model

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Pricing and hedging with rough-heston models

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

Lecture 2: Rough Heston models: Pricing and hedging

Rough volatility models

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

A Weighted-fractional model. to European option pricing

King s College London

Stochastic Volatility Modeling

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

Beyond the Black-Scholes-Merton model

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes

A new approach for scenario generation in risk management

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

Stochastic Volatility

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Value at Risk and Self Similarity

Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing?

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque)

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

Volatility. Roberto Renò. 2 March 2010 / Scuola Normale Superiore. Dipartimento di Economia Politica Università di Siena

Heston vs Heston. Antoine Jacquier. Department of Mathematics, Imperial College London. ICASQF, Cartagena, Colombia, June 2016

How to hedge Asian options in fractional Black-Scholes model

Optimum Thresholding for Semimartingales with Lévy Jumps under the mean-square error

The stochastic calculus

Variance Reduction for Monte Carlo Simulation in a Stochastic Volatility Environment

Modeling via Stochastic Processes in Finance

Parametric Inference and Dynamic State Recovery from Option Panels. Torben G. Andersen

S t d with probability (1 p), where

Two and Three factor models for Spread Options Pricing

Continous time models and realized variance: Simulations

AD in Monte Carlo for finance

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Calibration Lecture 4: LSV and Model Uncertainty

Counterparty Credit Risk Simulation

Remarks on rough Bergomi: asymptotics and calibration

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Estimation of dynamic term structure models

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

Model Estimation. Liuren Wu. Fall, Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College. Liuren Wu Model Estimation Option Pricing, Fall, / 16

Parametric Inference and Dynamic State Recovery from Option Panels. Nicola Fusari

Asian Options under Multiscale Stochastic Volatility

On modelling of electricity spot price

Stochastic calculus Introduction I. Stochastic Finance. C. Azizieh VUB 1/91. C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance

Stochastic Modelling Unit 3: Brownian Motion and Diffusions

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

Probability in Options Pricing

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information

Conditional Density Method in the Computation of the Delta with Application to Power Market

Exploring Volatility Derivatives: New Advances in Modelling. Bruno Dupire Bloomberg L.P. NY

Optimal Kernel Estimation of Spot Volatility of SDE

King s College London

Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson. Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson

Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery

Non-semimartingales in finance

Sensitivity Analysis on Long-term Cash flows

Option Pricing Models for European Options

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

Stochastic Volatility Effects on Defaultable Bonds

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.pr] 23 Nov 2017

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

(1) Consider a European call option and a European put option on a nondividend-paying stock. You are given:

Insiders Hedging in a Stochastic Volatility Model with Informed Traders of Multiple Levels

Posterior Inference. , where should we start? Consider the following computational procedure: 1. draw samples. 2. convert. 3. compute properties

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

Credit Risk : Firm Value Model

Bruno Dupire April Paribas Capital Markets Swaps and Options Research Team 33 Wigmore Street London W1H 0BN United Kingdom

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

2 Control variates. λe λti λe e λt i where R(t) = t Y 1 Y N(t) is the time from the last event to t. L t = e λr(t) e e λt(t) Exercises

Asymptotic Methods in Financial Mathematics

Analytical formulas for local volatility model with stochastic. Mohammed Miri

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

Quadratic hedging in affine stochastic volatility models

ARCH and GARCH models

Introduction to Sequential Monte Carlo Methods

Pricing Variance Swaps under Stochastic Volatility Model with Regime Switching - Discrete Observations Case

Option Pricing and Calibration with Time-changed Lévy processes

Monte Carlo Simulations

Sparse Wavelet Methods for Option Pricing under Lévy Stochastic Volatility models

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

Modelling financial data with stochastic processes

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis

Short-Time Asymptotic Methods in Financial Mathematics

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Introduction to Financial Mathematics

Transcription:

Recent Advances in Fractional Stochastic Volatility Models Alexandra Chronopoulou Industrial & Enterprise Systems Engineering University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign IPAM National Meeting of Women in Financial Mathematics April 28, 2017

Stochastic Volatility {S t ; t [0, T ]}: Stock Price Process ds t = µs t dt + σ(x t ) S t dw t, σ( ) is a deterministic function and X t is a stochastic process. Assumption: X t is modeled by a diffusion driven by noise other than W. Log-Normal: dx t = c 1 X t dt + c 2 X t dz t, Mean Reverting OU: dx t = α (m X t) dt + β dz t, Feller/Cox Ingersoll Ross (CIR): dx t = k (ν X t) dt + v X t dz t.

Stylized Fact: Volatility Persistence

ACF of S&P 500 Returns2

Stochastic Process with Long Memory Long-memory If {X t } t N is a stationary process and there exists H ( 1 2, 1) such that Corr(X t, X 1 ) lim t c t 2 2H = 1 then {X t } has long memory (long-range dependence). Equivalently, { Long Memory: t=1 Corr(X t, X 1 ) =, when H > 1/2 Antipersistence: t=1 Corr(X t, X 1 ) <, when H < 1/2

Stochastic Process with Long Memory Long-memory If {X t } t N is a stationary process and there exists H ( 1 2, 1) such that Corr(X t, X 1 ) lim t c t 2 2H = 1 then {X t } has long memory (long-range dependence). Equivalently, { Long Memory: t=1 Corr(X t, X 1 ) =, when H > 1/2 Antipersistence: t=1 Corr(X t, X 1 ) <, when H < 1/2

Fractional Stochastic Volatility Model Log-Returns: {Y t, t [0, T ]} dy t = (r σ t 2 ) 2 dt + σ t dw t. where σ t = σ(x t ) and X t is described by: dx t = α (m X t ) dt + β db H t B H t is a fractional Brownian motion with Hurst parameter H (0, 1). X t is a fractional Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process (fou).

Fractional Stochastic Volatility Model Log-Returns: {Y t, t [0, T ]} dy t = (r σ t 2 ) 2 dt + σ t dw t. where σ t = σ(x t ) and X t is described by: dx t = α (m X t ) dt + β db H t B H t is a fractional Brownian motion with Hurst parameter H (0, 1). X t is a fractional Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process (fou).

Fractional Brownian Motion Definition A centered Gaussian process B H = {B H t, t 0} is called fractional Brownian motion (fbm) with selfsimilarity parameter H (0, 1), if it has the following covariance function E ( B H t B H s and a.s. continuous paths. ) 1 { = t 2H + s 2H t s 2H}. 2 When H = 1 2, BH is a standard Brownian motion.

Fractional Brownian Motion Definition A centered Gaussian process B H = {B H t, t 0} is called fractional Brownian motion (fbm) with selfsimilarity parameter H (0, 1), if it has the following covariance function E ( B H t B H s and a.s. continuous paths. ) 1 { = t 2H + s 2H t s 2H}. 2 When H = 1 2, BH is a standard Brownian motion.

0 200 400 600 800 1000 circfbm Path - N=1000, H=0.3 circfbm Path - N=1000, H=0.5 ans -1.0-0.5 0.0 0.5 ans -0.8-0.6-0.4-0.2 0.0 0.2 0 200 400 600 800 1000 time time circfbm Path - N=1000, H=0.7 circfbm Path - N=1000, H=0.95 ans -0.2 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 ans 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 1.2 0 200 400 600 800 1000 0 200 400 600 800 1000 time time

Properties of FBM The increments of fbm, {B n B n 1 } n N, are stationary, i.e. E[(B n B n 1 ) (B n+h B n+h 1 )] = γ(h). H selfsimilar, i.e. c H (B n B n 1 ) D (B c n B c(n 1) ) dependent When H > 1, the increments exhibit long-memory, i.e. 2 E [B 1 (B n B n 1)] = +. When H < 1 2, the increments exhibit antipersistence, i.e. E [B 1 (B n B n 1)] < +.

Properties of FBM The increments of fbm, {B n B n 1 } n N, are stationary, i.e. E[(B n B n 1 ) (B n+h B n+h 1 )] = γ(h). H selfsimilar, i.e. c H (B n B n 1 ) D (B c n B c(n 1) ) dependent When H > 1, the increments exhibit long-memory, i.e. 2 E [B 1 (B n B n 1)] = +. When H < 1 2, the increments exhibit antipersistence, i.e. E [B 1 (B n B n 1)] < +.

Properties of FBM The increments of fbm, {B n B n 1 } n N, are stationary, i.e. E[(B n B n 1 ) (B n+h B n+h 1 )] = γ(h). H selfsimilar, i.e. c H (B n B n 1 ) D (B c n B c(n 1) ) dependent When H > 1, the increments exhibit long-memory, i.e. 2 E [B 1 (B n B n 1)] = +. When H < 1 2, the increments exhibit antipersistence, i.e. E [B 1 (B n B n 1)] < +.

Properties of FBM The increments of fbm, {B n B n 1 } n N, are stationary, i.e. E[(B n B n 1 ) (B n+h B n+h 1 )] = γ(h). H selfsimilar, i.e. c H (B n B n 1 ) D (B c n B c(n 1) ) dependent When H > 1, the increments exhibit long-memory, i.e. 2 E [B 1 (B n B n 1)] = +. When H < 1 2, the increments exhibit antipersistence, i.e. E [B 1 (B n B n 1)] < +.

Properties of FBM The increments of fbm, {B n B n 1 } n N, are stationary, i.e. E[(B n B n 1 ) (B n+h B n+h 1 )] = γ(h). H selfsimilar, i.e. c H (B n B n 1 ) D (B c n B c(n 1) ) dependent When H > 1, the increments exhibit long-memory, i.e. 2 E [B 1 (B n B n 1)] = +. When H < 1 2, the increments exhibit antipersistence, i.e. E [B 1 (B n B n 1)] < +.

Properties of FBM It has a.s. Hölder-continuous sample paths of any order γ < H. Its 1 H -variation on [0, t] is finite. In particular, fbm has an infinite quadratic variation for H < 1/2. When H 1 2, BH t is not a semimartingale.

Properties of FBM It has a.s. Hölder-continuous sample paths of any order γ < H. Its 1 H -variation on [0, t] is finite. In particular, fbm has an infinite quadratic variation for H < 1/2. When H 1 2, BH t is not a semimartingale.

Properties of FBM It has a.s. Hölder-continuous sample paths of any order γ < H. Its 1 H -variation on [0, t] is finite. In particular, fbm has an infinite quadratic variation for H < 1/2. When H 1 2, BH t is not a semimartingale.

Stochastic Integral wrt fbm Pathwise Riemann-Stieltjes integral, when H > 1/2. (Lin; Dai and Heyde). Stochastic calculus of variations with respect to a Gaussian process. (Decreusefond and Üstünel; Carmona and Coutin; Alòs, Mazet and Nualart; Duncan, Hu and Pasik-Duncan and Hu and Oksendal). Pathwise stochastic integral interpreted in the Young sense, when H > 1/2 (Young; Gubinelli). Rough path-theoretic approach by T. Lyons.

Fractional Stochastic Volatility Model { ( ) dy t = r σ2 (X t) 2 dt + σ(x t ) dw t, dx t = α (m X t ) dt + β dbt H Some Properties Hölder continuity: Hölder continuous of order γ, for all γ < H. Self-similarity: Self-similar in the sense that {B H ct ; t R} D {c H B H t ; t R}, c R This property is approximately inherited by the fou, for scales smaller than 1/α.

Fractional Stochastic Volatility Model Hurst Index Model H > 1/2 Long-Memory SV: persistence ACF Decay dt 2H 2 H < 1/2 Rough Volatility: anti-persistence ACF Decay dt H H = 1/2 Classical SV

Long Memory Stochastic Volatility Models Comte and Renault (1998) Comte, Coutin and Renault (2010) C. and Viens (2010, 2012) Gulisashvili, Viens and Zhang (2015) Guennoun, Jacquier, and Roome (2015) Garnier & Solna (2015, 2016) Bezborodov, Di Persio & Mishura (20176) Fouque & Hu (2017)

Rough Stochastic Volatility Models Gatheral, Jaisson, and Rosenbaum (2014) Bayer, Friz, and Gatheral (2015) Forde, Zhang (2015) El Euch, Rosenbaum (2016, 2017)

Related Literature Willinger, Taqqu, Teverovsky (1999): LRD in the stock market Bayraktar, Poor, Sircar (2003): Estimation of fractal dimension of S&P 500. Björk, Hult (2005): Fractional Black-Scholes market. Cheriditio (2003): Arbitrage in fractional BS market. Guasoni (2006): No arbitral under transaction cost with fbm.

Research Questions 1 Option Pricing 2 Statistical Inference 3 Hedging

Option Pricing

Option Pricing In practice, we have access to discrete-time observations of historical stock prices, while the volatility is unobserved. Two-steps 1 Estimate the empirical stochastic volatility distribution. Through adjusted particle filtering algorithms. 2 Construct a multinomial recombining tree to compute the option prices.

Option Pricing In practice, we have access to discrete-time observations of historical stock prices, while the volatility is unobserved. Two-steps 1 Estimate the empirical stochastic volatility distribution. Through adjusted particle filtering algorithms. 2 Construct a multinomial recombining tree to compute the option prices.

Option Pricing In practice, we have access to discrete-time observations of historical stock prices, while the volatility is unobserved. Two-steps 1 Estimate the empirical stochastic volatility distribution. Through adjusted particle filtering algorithms. 2 Construct a multinomial recombining tree to compute the option prices.

Option Pricing In practice, we have access to discrete-time observations of historical stock prices, while the volatility is unobserved. Two-steps 1 Estimate the empirical stochastic volatility distribution. Through adjusted particle filtering algorithms. 2 Construct a multinomial recombining tree to compute the option prices.

Option Pricing In practice, we have access to discrete-time observations of historical stock prices, while the volatility is unobserved. Two-steps 1 Estimate the empirical stochastic volatility distribution. Through adjusted particle filtering algorithms. 2 Construct a multinomial recombining tree to compute the option prices.

Multinomial Recombining Tree (i) At each step, a value for the volatility is drawn from the volatility filter. (ii) A standard pricing technique using backward induction can be used to compute the option price. (iii) We iterate this procedure by using N repeated volatility samples, constructing a different tree with each sample and averaging over all prices.

Multinomial Recombining Tree (i) At each step, a value for the volatility is drawn from the volatility filter. (ii) A standard pricing technique using backward induction can be used to compute the option price. (iii) We iterate this procedure by using N repeated volatility samples, constructing a different tree with each sample and averaging over all prices.

Multinomial Recombining Tree (i) At each step, a value for the volatility is drawn from the volatility filter. (ii) A standard pricing technique using backward induction can be used to compute the option price. (iii) We iterate this procedure by using N repeated volatility samples, constructing a different tree with each sample and averaging over all prices.

S&P 500 Data Option Price 0 100 200 300 400 500 800 1000 1200 1400 1600 1800 Strike Price

Statistical Inference

Inference for FSV Models { ( ) dy t = µ σ2 (X t) 2 dt + σ(x t ) dw t, dx t = α (m X t ) dt + β dbt H We can also assume that Corr(B H t, W t ) = ρ (leverage effects). Parameters to estimate: θ = (α, m, β, µ, ρ) and H.

Inference for FSV Models Remark The estimation of H is decoupled from the estimation of the drift components, but not from the estimation of the diffusion terms. Framework Observations: Historical stock prices Discrete, even when in high-frequency. Unobserved State: Stochastic Volatility with non-markovian structure is hidden.

Inference for FSV Models Extension of classical statistical methods For H known: µ, m, α and β can be estimated with standard techniques (Fouque, Papanicolaou and Sircar, 2000) using high-frequency data. For H unknown: Traditional volatility proxies: Squared returns, logarithm of squared returns. Use a non-parametric method to estimate H through the squared returns and then go back to classical techniques and estimate the remaining parameters.

Inference for FSV Models Extension of classical statistical methods For H known: µ, m, α and β can be estimated with standard techniques (Fouque, Papanicolaou and Sircar, 2000) using high-frequency data. For H unknown: Traditional volatility proxies: Squared returns, logarithm of squared returns. Use a non-parametric method to estimate H through the squared returns and then go back to classical techniques and estimate the remaining parameters.

Inference for FSV Models Extension of classical statistical methods For H known: µ, m, α and β can be estimated with standard techniques (Fouque, Papanicolaou and Sircar, 2000) using high-frequency data. For H unknown: Traditional volatility proxies: Squared returns, logarithm of squared returns. Use a non-parametric method to estimate H through the squared returns and then go back to classical techniques and estimate the remaining parameters.

Inference for FSV Models Extension of classical statistical methods For H known: µ, m, α and β can be estimated with standard techniques (Fouque, Papanicolaou and Sircar, 2000) using high-frequency data. For H unknown: Traditional volatility proxies: Squared returns, logarithm of squared returns. Use a non-parametric method to estimate H through the squared returns and then go back to classical techniques and estimate the remaining parameters.

Inference for FSV Models Simulation Based Methods Employ a Sequential Monte Carlo (SMC) method to estimate the unobserved state along with the unknown parameters. Denote θ the vector of all parameters, except for H. Observation equation: f(y t X t; θ) State equation: f(x t X t 1,..., X 1; θ) Key Idea: Sequentially compute f(x 1:t; θ Y 1:t) f(x 1) f(x 2 X 1; θ)... f(x n X n 1,..., X 1; θ) t f(y i X i; θ) f(θ Y t), i=1

Inference for FSV Models Simulation Based Methods Employ a Sequential Monte Carlo (SMC) method to estimate the unobserved state along with the unknown parameters. Denote θ the vector of all parameters, except for H. Observation equation: f(y t X t; θ) State equation: f(x t X t 1,..., X 1; θ) Key Idea: Sequentially compute f(x 1:t; θ Y 1:t) f(x 1) f(x 2 X 1; θ)... f(x n X n 1,..., X 1; θ) t f(y i X i; θ) f(θ Y t), i=1

Inference for FSV Models Simulation Based Methods Employ a Sequential Monte Carlo (SMC) method to estimate the unobserved state along with the unknown parameters. Denote θ the vector of all parameters, except for H. Observation equation: f(y t X t; θ) State equation: f(x t X t 1,..., X 1; θ) Key Idea: Sequentially compute f(x 1:t; θ Y 1:t) f(x 1) f(x 2 X 1; θ)... f(x n X n 1,..., X 1; θ) t f(y i X i; θ) f(θ Y t), i=1

Inference for FSV Models Simulation Based Methods Employ a Sequential Monte Carlo (SMC) method to estimate the unobserved state along with the unknown parameters. Denote θ the vector of all parameters, except for H. Observation equation: f(y t X t; θ) State equation: f(x t X t 1,..., X 1; θ) Key Idea: Sequentially compute f(x 1:t; θ Y 1:t) f(x 1) f(x 2 X 1; θ)... f(x n X n 1,..., X 1; θ) t f(y i X i; θ) f(θ Y t), i=1

Inference for FSV Models Simulation Based Methods Employ a Sequential Monte Carlo (SMC) method to estimate the unobserved state along with the unknown parameters. Denote θ the vector of all parameters, except for H. Observation equation: f(y t X t; θ) State equation: f(x t X t 1,..., X 1; θ) Key Idea: Sequentially compute f(x 1:t; θ Y 1:t) f(x 1) f(x 2 X 1; θ)... f(x n X n 1,..., X 1; θ) t f(y i X i; θ) f(θ Y t), i=1

Learning θ sequentially Filtering for states and parameter(s): Learning X t and θ sequentially. Posterior at t : f(x t θ, Y t ) f(θ Y t ) Prior at t + 1 : f(x t+1 θ, Y t ) f(θ Y t ) Posterior at t + 1 : f(x t+1 θ, Y t+1 ) f(θ Y t+1 ) Advantages 1 Sequential updates of f(θ Y t ), f(x t Y t ) and f(θ, X t Y t ). 2 Sequential h-step ahead forecasts f(y t+h Y t ) 3 Sequential approximations for f(y t Y t 1 ).

Learning θ sequentially Filtering for states and parameter(s): Learning X t and θ sequentially. Posterior at t : f(x t θ, Y t ) f(θ Y t ) Prior at t + 1 : f(x t+1 θ, Y t ) f(θ Y t ) Posterior at t + 1 : f(x t+1 θ, Y t+1 ) f(θ Y t+1 ) Advantages 1 Sequential updates of f(θ Y t ), f(x t Y t ) and f(θ, X t Y t ). 2 Sequential h-step ahead forecasts f(y t+h Y t ) 3 Sequential approximations for f(y t Y t 1 ).

Learning θ sequentially Filtering for states and parameter(s): Learning X t and θ sequentially. Posterior at t : f(x t θ, Y t ) f(θ Y t ) Prior at t + 1 : f(x t+1 θ, Y t ) f(θ Y t ) Posterior at t + 1 : f(x t+1 θ, Y t+1 ) f(θ Y t+1 ) Advantages 1 Sequential updates of f(θ Y t ), f(x t Y t ) and f(θ, X t Y t ). 2 Sequential h-step ahead forecasts f(y t+h Y t ) 3 Sequential approximations for f(y t Y t 1 ).

Artificial Evolution of θ Draw θ from a mixture of Normals: t update f(θ Y t) Compute a Monte Carlo approximation of f(θ Y t), by using samples θ (j) t and weights w (j) t. Smooth kernel density approximation f(θ Y t) N j=1 ω (j) t N (θ m (j) t, h 2 V t)

Artificial Evolution of θ Draw θ from a mixture of Normals: t update f(θ Y t) Compute a Monte Carlo approximation of f(θ Y t), by using samples θ (j) t and weights w (j) t. Smooth kernel density approximation f(θ Y t) N j=1 ω (j) t N (θ m (j) t, h 2 V t)

Artificial Evolution of θ Draw θ from a mixture of Normals: t update f(θ Y t) Compute a Monte Carlo approximation of f(θ Y t), by using samples θ (j) t and weights w (j) t. Smooth kernel density approximation f(θ Y t) N j=1 ω (j) t N (θ m (j) t, h 2 V t)

Artificial Evolution of θ Draw θ from a mixture of Normals: t update f(θ Y t) Compute a Monte Carlo approximation of f(θ Y t), by using samples θ (j) t and weights w (j) t. Smooth kernel density approximation f(θ Y t) N j=1 ω (j) t N (θ m (j) t, h 2 V t)

Filter convergence Let φ : X R be an appropriate test function and assume that we want estimate φ t = φ t (x 1:t )p(x 1:t, θ (t) Y 1:t )dx 1:t dθ (t). The SISR algorithm provides us with the estimator N ˆφ N t = φ t (x 1:t )π N (dx 1:t ) = i=1 W i t φ t ( X (i) 1:t 1,t 1 ) (i), X t,t CLT for the filter (C. and Spiliopoulos) N ( ˆφN t φ t ) N ( 0, σ 2 (φ t ) ) as N.

Convergence of the Parameter θ N (t) = N i=1 W (i) t θ (N,i) (t), where θ (N,i) (t) with m N t 1 = αθ(n,i) (t 1) + (1 α) θ N (t 1), V N t 1 = 1 N 1 N (m (N,i) t 1 h2 Vt 1) N N i=1 (W (i) t 1 θ(n,i) (t 1) θ 2. (t 1)) N CLT for the parameter Assuming that E π θ t W t 2+δ < : N ( θ(n) (t) θ (t) ) N ( 0, σ 2 (θ (t) ) ), as N (1) Moreover, if the model P θ is identifiable, then the posterior mean θ (t) consistently estimates the true parameter value θ, as t.

S& P 500: Volatility Particle Filter Density 0 10 20 30 40 0.31 0.32 0.33 0.34 0.35 0.36 0.37

S& P 500: Parameter Estimators alpha 2 4 6 8 10 mu 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 0 200 400 600 800 1000 0 200 400 600 800 1000 (a) Estimator of µ (b) Estimator of α 4 6 8 10 sigma 2 4 6 8 m 0 200 400 600 800 1000 0 200 400 600 800 1000 (c) Estimator of m (d) Estimator of β

Model Validation: 1-Step Ahead Prediction

Model Validation: Residuals (a) Residuals (b) ACF of Residuals

Hedging

Hedging Conditionally on the past and the entire volatility path ln S T /S t N ( T r (1/2) t σ 2 s ds, T t σ 2 s ds ). So, { ( C t = S t E [Φ Q xt + V )] [ ( t,t e xt E Q xt Φ V )]} t,t, V t,t 2 V t,t 2 where x t = ln ( e rt S t /K ) and V t,t = ( T t σ 2 sds) 1/2. Imperfect Delta-Sigma hedging strategy ( t (x t, σ t ) = E [Φ Q xt + V )] t,t V t,t 2

Hedging Conditionally on the past and the entire volatility path ln S T /S t N ( T r (1/2) t σ 2 s ds, T t σ 2 s ds ). So, { ( C t = S t E [Φ Q xt + V )] [ ( t,t e xt E Q xt Φ V )]} t,t, V t,t 2 V t,t 2 where x t = ln ( e rt S t /K ) and V t,t = ( T t σ 2 sds) 1/2. Imperfect Delta-Sigma hedging strategy ( t (x t, σ t ) = E [Φ Q xt + V )] t,t V t,t 2

Hedging Conditionally on the past and the entire volatility path ln S T /S t N ( T r (1/2) t σ 2 s ds, T t σ 2 s ds ). So, { ( C t = S t E [Φ Q xt + V )] [ ( t,t e xt E Q xt Φ V )]} t,t, V t,t 2 V t,t 2 where x t = ln ( e rt S t /K ) and V t,t = ( T t σ 2 sds) 1/2. Imperfect Delta-Sigma hedging strategy ( t (x t, σ t ) = E [Φ Q xt + V )] t,t V t,t 2

Hedging Two notions of Implied Volatility 1 Black-Scholes Implied Volatility: The unique solution to C t (x, σ) = Ct BS (x, σ i (x, σ)), i.e. the volatility parameter that equates the BS price to the HW. 2 Hedging Volatility: The unique solution to t (x, σ) = BS t (x, σ h (x, σ)) i.e. the volatility parameter that equates the BS hedge ratio against the underlying asset variations to the HW one.

Hedging Two notions of Implied Volatility 1 Black-Scholes Implied Volatility: The unique solution to C t (x, σ) = Ct BS (x, σ i (x, σ)), i.e. the volatility parameter that equates the BS price to the HW. 2 Hedging Volatility: The unique solution to t (x, σ) = BS t (x, σ h (x, σ)) i.e. the volatility parameter that equates the BS hedge ratio against the underlying asset variations to the HW one.

Hedging Hedging Bias (Definition) The difference between the BS implied volatility-based hedging ratio and the HW one: Bias = BS t (x, σ i (x, σ)) t (x, σ)

Hedging Theorem (a) Sign of Hedging Bias: σ h ( x, σ) σ i ( x, σ) = σ i (x, σ) σ h (x, σ) (b) Accuracy of approximation of partial hedging ratio by the BS implicit volatility-based hedging ratio: BS (x, σ) (x, σ) BS ( x, σ) ( x, σ) BS (0, σ) = (0, σ)

Hedging Theorem (a) Sign of Hedging Bias: σ h ( x, σ) σ i ( x, σ) = σ i (x, σ) σ h (x, σ) (b) Accuracy of approximation of partial hedging ratio by the BS implicit volatility-based hedging ratio: BS (x, σ) (x, σ) BS ( x, σ) ( x, σ) BS (0, σ) = (0, σ)

Thank you!