GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

Similar documents
Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

ECON 815. Uncertainty and Asset Prices

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

One-Period Valuation Theory

Lecture 12. Asset pricing model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: June 15, 2017

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Portfolio Investment

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Lecture 3 Conduct of Monetary Policy: Goals, Instruments, and Targets; Asset Pricing; Time Inconsistency and Inflation Bias

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Consumption and Savings (Continued)

Dynamic Asset Pricing Model

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

1 Dynamic programming

Economics 8106 Macroeconomic Theory Recitation 2

Topic 7: Asset Pricing and the Macroeconomy

Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 2

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

Consumption and Asset Pricing

The stochastic discount factor and the CAPM

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Real Business Cycles (Solution)

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

Basics of Asset Pricing. Ali Nejadmalayeri

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Slides III - Complete Markets

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Stock Prices and the Stock Market

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 7

ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 6a

The Equity Premium. Blake LeBaron Reading: Cochrane(chap 21, 2017), Campbell(2017/2003) October Fin305f, LeBaron

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Microeconomics 3. Economics Programme, University of Copenhagen. Spring semester Lars Peter Østerdal. Week 17

Reviewing Income and Wealth Heterogeneity, Portfolio Choice and Equilibrium Asset Returns by P. Krussell and A. Smith, JPE 1997

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model

Money in a Neoclassical Framework

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

Household Finance in China

Macroeconomics and finance

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY ECONOMICS NOTE 8b

Lecture 4A The Decentralized Economy I

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Macroeconomics: Fluctuations and Growth

Hedge Portfolios, the No Arbitrage Condition & Arbitrage Pricing Theory

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Advanced Macroeconomics 6. Rational Expectations and Consumption

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

A numerical analysis of the monetary aspects of the Japanese economy: the cash-in-advance approach

ECON385: A note on the Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH). In this note, we will try to understand the permanent income hypothesis (PIH).

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

Tries to understand the prices or values of claims to uncertain payments.

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

Influence of Real Interest Rate Volatilities on Long-term Asset Allocation

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

EC 324: Macroeconomics (Advanced)

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

Monetary/Fiscal Interactions: Cash in Advance

14.05 Lecture Notes. Labor Supply

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods

Equilibrium Asset Returns

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Valuation Models and Asset Returns

Optimizing Portfolios

Dynamic AD and Dynamic AS

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Lecture 1: Lucas Model and Asset Pricing

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Mean-Variance Analysis

III: Labor Supply in Two Periods

Financial Econometrics

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

Lecture 14 Consumption under Uncertainty Ricardian Equivalence & Social Security Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

Intertemporal macroeconomics

Topic 2: Consumption

Course information FN3142 Quantitative finance

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Technical Appendix to Asset Prices in a Huggett Economy

Transcription:

GMM Estimation 1 Introduction Modern macroeconomic models are typically based on the intertemporal optimization and rational expectations. The Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) is an econometric framework which allows to estimate the parameters of such models. As an example, we consider consumption based asset pricing models. 2 Consumption-CAPM Consider a model where a representative agent lives for two periods, t and t + 1, and maximizes life-time utility: u(c t ) + βe t u(c t+1 ), where E t is the expectation conditional on period 1 information. 1 The representative agent can buy an asset at price p t which pays a dividend of d t+1 in the second period. So the expected return earned on this asset is E t (R t+1 ) = E[(p t+1 + d t+1 )/p t ]. In the first period, the following budget constraint has to hold: c t + a t = w t, (1) where a t denotes asset holdings which are carried into the second period and w t is initial wealth in the first period. A similar constraint applies in the second period: Combining these two constraints gives c t+1 = R t+1 a t. (2) c t + c t+1 R t+1 = w t, (3) 1 So strictly speaking, we have u(c t ) + βe(u(c t+1 ) Ω t ), where Ω t is the information set available in the first period. 1

which is the lifetime budget constraint. The representative consumer maximizes utility subject to this constraint. The necessary condition is the following Euler equation: u (c t ) = βe t [R t+1 u (c t+1 )], (4) or E t (R t+1 M t+1 ) = 1, (5) where M t+1 = βu (c t+1 )/u (c t ) is the marginal rate of substitution of current for future consumption. In the context of asset pricing models the marginal rate of substitution is usually called a stochastic discount factor. Note that (5) has to hold for any asset with a potentially stochastic return R t+1. Suppose we also have an asset with a risk free return, R f. Then we have R f = 1/E t (M t+1 ). Equation (5) can be rewritten as: 2 Using the risk-free return, R f, we obtain E t (R t+1 )E t (M t+1 ) + cov t (M t+1, R t+1 ) = 1, (6) E t (R t+1 ) = 1 cov t(m t+1, R t+1 ). (7) E t (M t+1 ) E t (R t+1 ) = (1 cov t (M t+1, R t+1 ))R f, (8) or E t (R t+1 R f ) = cov t (M t+1, R t+1 )R f, (9) which can be rewritten more explicitly in terms of consumption E t (R t+1 R f ) = cov t (M t+1, R t+1 )R f = cov t (βu (c t+1 )/u u (c t ) (c t ), R t+1 ) βe t u (c t+1 ), (10) Since β and u (c t+1 ) are known in period t the expression on the right-hand-side can be written as 3 cov t (βu (c t+1 )/u u (c t ) (c t ), R t+1 ) βu (c t+1 ) = cov t(u β u (c t ) (c t+1 )), R t+1 ) u (c t ) βu (c t+1 ). (11) 2 For any two random variables X and Y, E(XY ) = E(X)E(Y ) + Cov(X, Y ). 3 Recall that cov(ax, by ) = ab cov(x, Y ) for any constants, a and b. 2

And therefore we obtain E t (R t+1 R f ) = cov t(u (c t+1 )), R t+1 ). (12) u (c t+1 ) Equation (12) holds that equilibrium excess returns of any asset is determined by the covariance between the expected return of the asset and the marginal utility of consumption in the next period. How is the C-CAPM related to the CAPM? Recall that according to the CAPM the return of an asset depends on how it covaries with the market return. The C-CAPM basically replaces the return on the market with the marginal utility of consumption. However, the intuition is essentially the same. The return on an asset depends on how well the asset can be used to insure against changes in future consumption (instead of market risk in the CAPM). If cov t (u (c t+1 ), R t+1 )) > 0, then the asset return is high when consumption is low (under the standard assumptions that u > 0 and u < 0). In this case the asset can be used to insure or hedge fluctuations in consumption, and in this sense the asset is not risky! Therefore the equilibrium return is below the risk-free rate, since investors can reduce their consumption risks by holding this asset. 3 GMM Estimation The C-CAPM has been estimated and tested using a wide range of methodologies. One way to test the C-CAPM is to estimate the Euler equation underlying the asset pricing equation using the generalized method of moments (GMM) estimator. In general, GMM is a method for estimating models by exploiting moment conditions. Consider a model with m parameters collected in the vector θ and data X t, where specific combinations of θ and X t should be equal to zero on average. This condition be equal on average is the moment condition we exploit. More specifically: E[f i (θ, X t )] = 0, (13) for i = 1,..., n. So (13) represents n orthogonality conditions. To derive the GMM estimator, replace (13) by its empirical counterpart: m i = 1 T T [f i (θ, X t )] = 0. (14) t=1 3

So we have n sample moment conditions. If n > m, we have more moment conditions then parameters to estimate. Therefore, we will not obtain a unique solution for θ. The GMM estimator is defined as ˆθ = argmin{ m(θ) W 1 m(θ)}, (15) where m = ( m 1, m 2,..., m n ) and W is a weighting matrix. The minimization is usually done numerically. GMM is an extremely general framework. Many estimators you are familiar with can be viewed as special cases of GMM. So how can we use GMM to estimate the Euler equation. First, we have to assume a specific utility function: So the Euler equation becomes u(c) = c1 σ 1 σ. (16) c σ t = βe t (R t+1 c σ t+1). (17) or equivalently ( ( ) ) ct+1 σ E t βr t+1 1 = 0. (18) c t Since we are assuming that expectations are formed rationally, any information contained in the information set is already used optimally to form expectations. Therefore, the term in brackets must be orthogonal to any variable in the information set. Suppose that z t Ω t, then we must have 4 E [( βr t+1 ( ct+1 c t ) σ 1) ) z t ] = 0. (19) So the key insight here is that the assumption of rational expectations gives rise to orthogonality conditions. Therefore GMM is a natural method for the estimation of models with rational expectations. Note that if n > m, we have more moment conditions then parameters to estimate. Thus, we have overidentifying restrictions. The validity of these overidentifying restriction, that is the validity of the instruments, can be assessed using the J-test. A valid instrumental variable has to satisfy the orthogonality condition. EViews reports a J-value 4 More formally, the unconditional moment condition is implied by the Law of Iterated Expectations. 4

which is the minimized value of the objective function. 5 The appropriate test statistic can be constructed as the J-value multiplied by the number of observations. Under the null hypothesis that the overidentifying restrictions are satisfied, the J-statistic times the number of observations is asymptotically χ 2 with degrees of freedom equal to the number of overidentifying restrictions. 5 See also the Eviews manual or help for more details. 5