Do Bank Branches Matter Anymore?

Similar documents
ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Americans Cut Their Debt Yuliya Demyanyk and Matthew Koepke

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Three Myths about Peer-to-Peer Loans. Yuliya Demyanyk, Elena Loutskina, and Daniel Kolliner

Which Estimates of Metropolitan-Area Jobs Growth Should We Trust?

Home Financing in Kansas City and Its Contribution to Low- and Moderate-Income Neighborhood Development

Commercial Lending Distance and Historically Underserved Areas

Out of the Shadows: Projected Levels for Future REO Inventory

The Role of Soft Information in a Dynamic Contract Setting:

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE. September 4, 2001 COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION CITIZENS BANK OF EDMOND RSSD#

Summary. The importance of accessing formal credit markets

-Evidence shows that by focusing on

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. When Might the Federal Funds Rate Lift Off? Edward S. Knotek II and Saeed Zaman

Household Finance Session: Annette Vissing-Jorgensen, Northwestern University

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Unemployment after the Recession: A New Natural Rate? Murat Tasci and Saeed Zaman

The Evolution of Household Leverage During the Recovery

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Income Inequality Matters, but Mobility Is Just as Important. Daniel R. Carroll and Anne Chen

Don t Raise the Federal Debt Ceiling, Torpedo the U.S. Housing Market

A Steadier Course for Monetary Policy. John B. Taylor. Economics Working Paper 13107

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Wage Growth after the Great Recession Roberto Pinheiro and Meifeng Yang

America s Changing Tastes Income Growth and the Impact of Relative Price Changes on Age-based Consumption Patterns Income Growth

Labor Market Tightness across the United States since the Great Recession

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. An Unstable Okun s Law, Not the Best Rule of Thumb. Brent Meyer and Murat Tasci

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

Why is the Country Facing a Financial Crisis?

COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS ABOUT THE NEW HMDA DATA. General Background

The U.S. Economy and Monetary Policy. Esther L. George President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

An introduction to the Community Reinvestment Act. John Meeks Atlanta Region FDIC Community Affairs

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Reassessing the Effects of Extending Unemployment Insurance Benefits Pedro Amaral and Jessica Ice


PUBLIC DISCLOSURE COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

A LOOK BEHIND THE NUMBERS

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

The Relationship Between Small Business Loans and Wages

February 14, Dear Ms. Naulty:

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE. December 6, 2004 COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION BANK OF EUFAULA RSSD#

Compliance Challenges in a Changing Economic Environment

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE AUGUST 16, 2010 COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION AMERICAN HERITAGE BANK RSSD#

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

Some Facts about Bank Branches and LMI Customers

FICO Score Open Access Consumer Credit Education US Version. Frequently Asked Questions about FICO Scores

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Labor s Declining Share of Income and Rising Inequality. Margaret Jacobson and Filippo Occhino

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

LUNCHEON ADDRESS: SMALL BUSINESS ACCESS TO CAPITAL AND CREDIT

2018 National Survey of Community Banks

Goal-Based Monetary Policy Report 1

The Effect of GSEs, CRA, and Institutional. Characteristics on Home Mortgage Lending to. Underserved Markets

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

Executive Summary Chapter 1. Conceptual Overview and Study Design

Reflections in the Mirror: Defined contribution plan participants

REDUCING DEFAULT RATES OF REVERSE MORTGAGES

COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

Is the Fed's Seasonal Borrowing Privilege Justified? (p. 9)

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

Now What? Key Trends from the Mortgage Crisis and Implications for Policy

COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT PLAN

Written Testimony By Anthony M. Yezer Professor of Economics George Washington University

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

Roger W Ferguson, Jr: Economic progress and small business

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

Productivity Growth and Real Interest Rates in the Long Run

Fixing Bad Credit and Solving Credit Problems 1

Community Investments Vol. 9, Issue 1 Monetary Policy, Low-Income Communities, and the Federal Reserve System

The High Cost of Segregation: Exploring the Relationship Between Racial Segregation and Subprime Lending

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

Monetary Policy Revised: January 9, 2008

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Identifying Opportunities. Aligning Resources. Community Commitment Plan Summary Report. Measuring Outcomes. Advancing What Works

CRA for Community-Based Organizations. An Introduction to the Community Reinvestment Act

ECONOMICS WITH FINANCIAL LITERACY CURRICULUM MAP

Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 17 Sections 17.1 and 17.2 Asymmetric information can cause a competitive equilibrium allocation to be inefficient.

Product Guide. What is the Platinum Discount Network? FIVE STAR PASS. TheCreditPros Services. Advantages: Selling Platinum Discount Network

International Finance

Randall S Kroszner: Legislative proposals on reforming mortgage practices

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE. July 16, 2002 COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION UINTA COUNTY STATE BANK RSSD# 85052

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

The state of the nation s Housing 2013

Cambridge University Press Getting Rich: America s New Rich and how they Got that Way Lisa A. Keister Excerpt More information

FEEDBACK TUTORIAL LETTER

Data Point: The Geography of Credit Invisibility

Take control of your auto loan

PROPERTY INVESTING. Practical advice from a professional property investment consultancy on what to consider when investing in property

The Regional Economist January Inflation: Ijrooo.Ijror ijnouani. By William T. Gavin and Rachel J. Mandal

First-time Homebuyer s Guide: Follow These Steps to Get Your First Mortgage

Investment in Indian Country: How Investments in Tribal Infrastructure and Other Tribal Projects May Qualify for Community Reinvestment Act Credit

A Closer Look: Credit-risk Transfer to Private Investors

The Hard Lessons of Stock Market History

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

Revising the Texas Index of Leading Indicators By Keith R. Phillips and José Joaquín López

GREENPATH FINANCIAL WELLNESS SERIES

Quick Credit Repair Guide

BUYING YOUR FIRST HOME

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

Home Mortgage Disclosure Act Report ( ) Submitted by Jonathan M. Cabral, AICP

STOP RENTING AND OWN A HOME FOR LESS THAN YOU ARE PAYING IN RENT WITH VERY LITTLE MONEY DOWN

1. Introduction to Macroeconomics

Unaffordable, Unavailable, Uncovered. The State of Working Virginia. Part Two: Health Insurance. The Commonwealth Institute

Transcription:

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY Number 211-13 August 4, 211 Do Bank Branches Matter Anymore? O. Emre Ergungor and Stephanie Moulton Bank branches have been disappearing in some major metropolitan areas, as their populations and economic activity decline. Our research suggests that brick-and-mortar branches provide tangible benefi ts to consumers, especially in low- and moderate-income neighborhoods. When branches are located in these areas, borrowers living there default less and have greater access to credit. The United States has a decades-old tradition of encouraging banks to keep their branches open in low- and moderate-income areas. Under the Community Reinvestment Act, banks are not only encouraged to maintain branch presence in such locations, but they are also expected to meet the credit, investment, and banking services needs of the lowand moderate-income areas around those branches. However, as populations and economic activity decline in some areas, banks face a special problem. Even if every bank is acting responsibly under the CRA and trying to treat communities consistently by maintaining the same branch density (number of branches per capita), the number of branches will inevitably decline in sync with the decline in population and profitable business opportunities. This means that the access to banking services may degrade for some members of the community as they have to travel greater distances to find a bank branch. While this is surely inconvenient, our research suggests that greater distance from a bank has implications that go beyond mere inconvenience. Unlike cars or groceries, loan products are special in that pricing them properly in lowand moderate-income areas may require an intimate knowledge of the community and its people. As we explain in this Commentary, the lending market in these neighborhoods can fail without a lender with local experience; that is, some creditworthy people may not be able to get credit even if they travel to the next bank branch miles away. Thus, brickand-mortar branches provide tangible benefits to consumers, especially in low- and moderate-income neighborhoods. A physical bank presence leads to at least two measurable benefits: It makes it possible for creditworthy borrowers living there to obtain loans, and it leads to lower rates of default among them. Increasing distance between consumers and bank branches can have real social costs if these benefits are lost. Yet providing a policy solution to this problem is tricky. Like any other business, banks are guided by the profit motive, and branches move over time from areas where the business is shrinking to where it is growing. Because this is a slow-moving process, it is difficult to pin the responsibility for the loss of lending services in a low-to-moderate- income area on the shutdown of any particular branch in the neighborhood. In other words, the straw that broke the camel s back is probably not the closing of the last few remaining branches. This is not to say that policymakers should coerce banks to remain in declining neighborhoods. Such a response would be unwise from a safety and soundness perspective if the area no longer has the population density to support profitable banking operations. However, if as a society we care about the lost opportunities of creditworthy low-income individuals, we would benefit from identifying ways to overcome the financial disincentives banks may face in serving these distressed areas. ISSN 428-1276

Figure 1. Branch Openings and Closings in Four Ohio Counties Cuyahoga County Franklin County Lucas County Mahoning County Branch closings New branches County administration building Low-income areas Note: Low-income areas are Census tracts that qualify for the low-income housing tax credit (LIHTC). Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Summary of Deposits. Bank Branches in Declining Markets As an example of recent trends in bank branches, consider what s been happening in four major population centers in Ohio. Over the last eight years, Cuyahoga County lost a net total of 7 bank branches out of 43, Lucas County lost 5 out of 127, and Mahoning County lost 5 out of 84. But not all areas were net losers. For example, Franklin County added 34 to its 31. In all these counties, the average number of residents served per branch remained essentially unchanged. In other words, branch gains and losses went hand-in-hand with population gains and losses. In sync with deep population losses, branches that closed in the lowest-income areas, tended not to be replaced with a new branch in the same neighborhood or any nearby (figure 1). It is worth emphasizing that our naming of these counties is for illustration purposes and does not mean that these areas are now underserved, as we do not have any evidence to make such a case. To get a more accurate view, we plot in figure 2 the number of branches at various distances from the county administrative building, which we assume to be the city center. In Franklin County the number of net new branches increased at almost all distances from the county seat from 21 to 21. In Cuyahoga, Mahoning, and Lucas Counties, however, banks tended to close their branches in city centers. The population trends in figure 3 and other county characteristics in table 1 provide a glimpse into why banks may have behaved this way. Unlike Franklin County, Cuyahoga, Mahoning, and Lucas Counties have been losing population for many decades. A greater percentage of the population lives in poverty in those three counties, wages are growing more slowly, business establishments are closing, unemployment is higher, citizens are less educated, and the housing stock is much older. All in all, these characteristics suggest that Cuyahoga, Mahoning, and Lucas Counties may no longer be able to provide to banks the business opportunities that they used to, which could explain the closing of bank branches. But what are the implications for people who live in areas that lost a bank branch? How are they affected by access to fewer and more distant branches? These are the questions we turn to next. Why Do Bank Branches Matter? Economists have long theorized that a bank with a brickand-mortar presence can develop valuable know-how about the credit risk and business opportunities in its market by interacting with consumers and businesses as it delivers loan and deposit products. The idea is that a physical presence is key because the bank has to interact repeatedly with the community to develop the necessary relationships. For example, imagine a simple world in which there are only two mortgage applicants, both with credit troubles in their past. The first applicant now prioritizes her expenses so that she can pay her mortgage first, the other applicant has trouble setting her priorities in a responsible manner;

Figure 2. Number of Bank Branches in the County by Distance to the County Administrative Building 6 5 Cuyahoga County 22 21 4 35 3 Franklin County 22 21 4 25 3 2 2 15 1 1 5-1 2-3 4-5 6-7 8-9 1-11 12-13 14-15 16-17 18-19 2-21 -1 2-3 4-5 6-7 8-9 1-11 12-13 14-15 16-17 18 16 14 Lucas County 22 21 25 2 Mahoning County 22 21 12 1 15 8 6 1 4 5 2-1 3-4 6-7 9-1 12-13 15-16 18-19 21-22 24-25 -1 3-4 6-7 9-1 12-13 15-16 18-19 21-22 24-25 27-28 Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Summary of Deposits. she enjoys splurging once in a while, even if that means she might miss a mortgage payment or two or perhaps even default. Neither applicant can provide a down payment, and the lender cannot determine which applicant is the creditworthy one by looking at the tainted credit scores or the limited financial information they can provide. If it could, then the responsible applicant would get a lowerinterest loan reflecting her lower risk, and the other would get a higher-cost loan or be denied. But here is the problem. If the lender charges a low interest rate on mortgages to make them affordable to the creditworthy applicant, it will lose money because the other applicant will also get the same mortgage and potentially default. If the interest rate is high enough so that the lender is compensated for the likely credit loss, then the loan becomes unaffordable to the creditworthy applicant and only the applicant who does not mind missing payments shows up at the branch. Thus the lender finds itself in a bind; no matter what the interest rate is, it is never profitable to lend in this market; as a result, creditworthy borrowers cannot get credit. Economists refer to this problem as adverse selection. Bank-customer relationships can overcome this obstacle. For banks, interactions with customers allow them to gather information on a customer, so-called soft information, which is not easily captured in a credit score. For example, if the prospective loan customer has a checking account with the bank, then the bank can glean information from that account on how well the loan applicant manages her money.

Things like an average account balance, propensity to overdraw the account, and the regularity of deposits signal information to the bank about the customer. This is the kind of information that only the bank with the checking account relationship could easily collect. Indeed, a recent study has found that banks that have access to this sort of usage information from their loan customers other accounts are able to identify the more creditworthy borrowers. Banks operating in a local market are also more likely to have information on the local economy, giving them a context from which they can evaluate the future prospects of a borrower that is not readily available to an out-of-market lender. For instance, a bank with close ties to your market may know that your employer is having financial difficulties and that it was turned down for a loan. This would make you, its employee, a high-risk borrower. Alternatively, you may be a temporary worker, but your banker may have heard from your employer during a game of golf that the business is expanding and will need new employees. This means that your temporary position may become permanent. You are in fact a lower-risk borrower than it may seem to a distant lender, who evaluates you based on the job title written on your paystub. Because the gathering of soft information is difficult to do without a physical presence in a local market, the closing of a bank branch is different from the closing of a grocery store. One can still buy oranges, perhaps at a higher cost, by traveling farther to a different grocery store. But one cannot always get a loan by traveling to a distant lender. This may sound like the George Bailey-style relationshipbased lending that you may have seen in the movie It s a Wonderful Life, rather than the modern banking of the 21st century. There is some truth to that belief. Over the last 3 years, banking has moved away from the intimate relationships described above to a more arm s-length business model based on complex risk estimations (credit scores) and other automated underwriting (origination) rules. Those new tools have freed banks to lend wherever they want without relying on branch presence. Credit bureaus can supply lenders with information about your past borrowing and repayment habits, which are a good indicator of your future behavior. They may not be as good of an indicator as really getting to know the borrower, but obtaining a credit score is so much cheaper than maintaining a branch that the cost savings are worth the higher risk. Both lenders and borrowers have benefited in some ways from this shift in business practices. A mortgage that took 9 days to close in the old days now takes less than a month for most borrowers. Lenders can originate loans at a higher volume without charging higher interest rates an upward shift in the supply curve, as economists would call it so more credit is available. Research does indeed show that the broader adoption of credit scoring among lenders has been associated with an increase in the overall supply of credit, along with an increasing distance between lenders and borrowers. Figure 3. Population Trends Number of people, thousands 2, 1,8 1,6 1,4 1,2 1, 8 6 4 2 Franklin 195 196 197 198 199 2 21 22 23 Source: Census Bureau. Table 1. County Statistics Percent below poverty level Percent change in private sector business establishments (23 29) Percent change in average employment (23 29) Percent change in average weekly wage (23 29) Cuyahoga Lucas Mahoning Franklin Cuyahoga Mahoning Lucas 15.8 16.4 16.8 17.3.9 2.6 1.7 2.1 1.2 4.3 3.5 5.6 17.5 17.2 12.7 1.3 Unemployment rate 7.3 7.9 9.4 9.3 Percent with high 38.5 45.3 54.5 47.8 school degree or less Median year 1972 1953 1958 1957 house built Vacant housing units (percent) 11.9 12.7 11.9 11.6 Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Census Bureau. Forecast

It was once thought that there was no role left for lenders like George Bailey in the mortgage markets. Lenders who use credit scores and other hard information like paystubs and bank statements were thought to have driven out the neighborhood banker who knew your father and his father before that. As it turns out, while credit scores are great tools to separate people with past credit problems from those with spotless balance sheets, they are not a perfect screening device when it comes to separating people who defaulted for good reasons, such as life events, from people who defaulted for bad reasons, such as the inability to control their spending habits. Recent research finds that a physical branch presence and intimate knowledge of a neighborhood and a borrower can help creditworthy borrowers in the pool of applicants with low-credit scores. Who Benefits Most from Neighborhood Banking? The beneficial-relationships argument has some interesting implications, which can be validated with data. First, the main beneficiaries among borrowers should be the ones that find it difficult to access credit from banks that use the lower-cost automated underwriting criteria. These are people typically with low incomes, tainted credit histories, and low credit scores. Therefore, they would benefit from any additional piece of information not captured by the score. Second, if relationship lenders are better informed about borrowers creditworthiness, we should observe fewer instances of default among the loans they make. Third, with the uncertainties about borrower quality eased and default risk reduced, credit should become more abundant and cheaper if there are bank branches in low-income area. Our research revealed evidence that supports all three implications. On the default issue, we find that low-income homebuyers who obtain their mortgages from banks with branches in their neighborhoods are less likely to default than homebuyers who use banks without a branch in the area or mortgage brokers. This effect is especially strong among borrowers with low credit scores. While the average default rate for this group was around 2 percent, the default rate of those borrowers who took their loans from a local bank was up to 4.3 percentage points lower. Also as predicted, the price of mortgage credit does indeed decline, and its availability increases as there are more bank branches closer to lowmoderate income areas an effect that is too strong to be explained by increased competition alone. There is no similar effect in higher-income areas. These findings suggest that a physical presence gives banks the opportunity to get to know distressed areas better and channel resources to people who can manage them best. However, these creditworthy people are also likely to be financially constrained, and so unlikely to be able to bear the full cost of keeping a branch open in an area with declining business opportunities. Thus, they are the ones who will be worse off when branches close. Our research shows the benefits that come from creditworthy borrowers in declining low-income areas being in close physical proximity to a bank branch. The public policy challenge is to identify how to get those benefits when private markets alone do not provide them. References Bank Branch Presence and Access to Credit in Low-to- Moderate-Income Neighborhoods, by O. Emre Ergungor, 21. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 42. Benefits of Relationship Banking: Evidence from Consumer Credit Markets, by Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles, 21. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago working paper no. 21-5. Beyond the Transaction: Depository Institutions and Reduced Mortgage Default for Low Income Homebuyers, by O. Emre Ergungor and Stephanie Moulton, 211. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland working paper no. 11-15. Distance and Private Information in Lending, by Sumit Agarwal and Robert Hauswald, 21. Review of Financial Studies, vol. 23. Commercial Lending Distance and Historically Underserved Areas, by Robert DeYoung, W. Scott Frame, Dennis Glennon, Daniel P. McMillen, and Peter Nigro, 27. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta working paper no. 27-11a. Credit Scoring and the Availability, Price, and Risk of Small Business Credit, by Allen N. Berger, W. Scott Frame, and Nathan H. Miller, 25. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 37.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Research Department P.O. Box 6387 Cleveland, OH 4411 PRSRT STD U.S. Postage Paid Cleveland, OH Permit No. 385 Return Service Requested: Please send corrected mailing label to the above address. Material may be reprinted if the source is credited. Please send copies of reprinted material to the editor at the address above. O. Emre Ergungor is a senior research economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, and Stephanie Moulton is an assistant professor at the John Glenn School of Public Affairs at The Ohio State University. The views they express here are theirs and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, or Board staff. Economic Commentary is published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. To receive copies or be placed on the mailing list, e-mail your request to 4d.subscriptions@clev.frb.org or fax it to 216.579.35. Economic Commentary is also available on the Cleveland Fed s Web site at www.clevelandfed.org/research.