Optimal Capital Income Taxes in an Infinite-lived Representative-agent Model with Progressive Tax Schedules

Similar documents
Optimal Capital Income Taxes in A Representative-agent Model with Progressive Tax Schedules

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

Macroeconomic Theory Part II

ECON 5402:F Public Economics: Taxation Carleton University, 2012 Fall

Problem set Fall 2012.

Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation

Capital Taxation, Intermediate Goods, and Production

Department of Economics Course Outline

Income Inequality and Economic Growth: A Simple Theoretical Synthesis *

Labor-dependent Capital Income Taxation That Encourages Work and Saving

Macroeconomic Theory I Professor George Alogoskoufis Winter Semester Course Structure

Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model

A Re-examination of Economic Growth, Tax Policy, and Distributive Politics

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Econ 210C: Macroeconomic Theory

ECON 5402-W Public Economics: Taxation Carleton University, 2018 Winter

On the Optimality of Age-Dependent Taxes and the Progressive U.S. Tax System

HETEROGENEITY AND REDISTRIBUTION: BY MONETARY OR FISCAL MEANS? BY PETER N. IRELAND 1. Boston College and National Bureau of Economic Research, U.S.A.

Nonlinear Tax Structures and Endogenous Growth

How Should Capital Be Taxed? Theory and Evidence from Sweden

Welfare-maximizing tax structure in a model with human capital

Monetary Economics Semester 2, 2003

Endogenous Growth with Public Capital and Progressive Taxation

How Should Capital Be Taxed? Theory and Evidence from Sweden

Land is back and it must be taxed

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Optimal Capital Taxation with Entrepreneurial Risk

Department of Economics Course Outline

APPENDIX A: Income inequality literature review

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 9: Dynamic Taxation II Optimal Capital Taxation

Using the Relation between GINI Coefficient and Social Benefits as a Measure of the Optimality of Tax Policy

Economics of Taxation: Theory and Policy

Research Summary and Statement of Research Agenda

Helmuth Cremer Winter 2018 M2, TSE Public Economics

Optimal taxation in a growth model with public consumption and home production

In the Name of Allah

A note on testing for tax-smoothing in general equilibrium

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

BGSE Macroeconomics I

Monetary and Fiscal Policy Issues in General Equilibrium

Endogenous Growth, Inequality and the Composition of Government Expenditures

Course Outline and Reading List

Estate Taxation, Social Security and Annuity: the Trinity and Unity?

CAN CAPITAL INCOME TAX IMPROVE WELFARE IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET ECONOMY WITH A LABOR-LEISURE DECISION?

National Debt and Economic Growth with Externalities and Congestions

Advanced Macroeconomics I ECON 525a, Fall 2009 Yale University. Syllabus

Unfunded Pension and Labor Supply: Characterizing the Nature of the Distortion Cost

Optimal Capital Taxation Revisited. Staff Report 571 September 2018

Limited Market Participation, Financial Intermediaries, And Endogenous Growth

Economic growth with an optimal public spending composition

Firouz Gahvari Economics of Taxation Fall D DKH ( ) (E512) M-W 3:00-4:50 225D DKH

On Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Rule-of-Thumb Consumers

Credit, externalities, and non-optimality of the Friedman rule

Tax Policy Under Keeping Up with the Joneses and Imperfect Competition *

Working Paper Series* Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware

Working Paper No. 241

Optimal Taxation in Overlapping Generations Economies with Aggregate Risk

Intergenerational transfers, tax policies and public debt

The Macroeconomics e ects of a Negative Income Tax

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Optimal Taxation: Merging Micro and Macro Approaches

Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev

Oil Monopoly and the Climate

The Impact of Tax Policies on Economic Growth: Evidence from Asian Economies

Part 1: Welfare Analysis and Optimal Taxation (Hendren) Basics of Welfare Estimation. Hendren, N (2014). The Policy Elasticity, NBER Working Paper

Fiscal Policy in a Small Open Economy with Endogenous Labor Supply * 1

Unemployment, Income Growth and Social Security

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

WORKING PAPER NO OPTIMAL CAPITAL INCOME TAXATION WITH HOUSING. Makoto Nakajima Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

Final Exam Solutions

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

Trade effects based on general equilibrium

Optimal Contingent Fiscal Policy in a Business Cycle Model *

Journal of Central Banking Theory and Practice, 2017, 1, pp Received: 6 August 2016; accepted: 10 October 2016

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity

Automatic Stabilization and Labor Supply

Optimal Capital Taxation Revisited. Working Paper 752 July 2018

The Liquidity Effect in Bank-Based and Market-Based Financial Systems. Johann Scharler *) Working Paper No October 2007

Review of Economic Dynamics. The stationary wealth distribution under progressive taxation

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

B r i e f T a b l e o f C o n t e n t s

International Finance: Reading List Economics 642: Winter 2004 Linda Tesar

5 New Dynamic Public Finance: A User s Guide

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007

Retirement Financing: An Optimal Reform Approach

Optimal Taxation with Optimal Tax Complexity: The Case of Estate Taxation. John D. Wilson* and Paul Menchik** Michigan State University.

), is described there by a function of the following form: U (c t. )= c t. where c t

Syllabus of EC6102 Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES POLITICAL ECONOMY OF RAMSEY TAXATION. Daron Acemoglu Mikhail Golosov Aleh Tsyvinski

Public Investment, Life Expectancy and Income Growth

Public Economics. Level / Semester - Niveau /semestre

On the Business Cycle Effects of Government Spending

Macroeconomic Theory I: Growth Theory

Advanced Macroeconomics

Transcription:

Optimal Capital Income Taxes in an Infinite-lived Representative-agent Model with Progressive Tax Schedules Been-Lon Chen Academia Sinica Chih-Fang Lai * National Taiwan University February 2014 Abstract In an infinite-lived representative-agent model with linear capital and labor income taxes, the influential studies by Chamley (1986) and Judd (1985) showed that the optimal capital tax should be zero in the long run. Our paper shows that in the same model, if the capital income tax rate is sufficiently progressive, the optimal capital tax is positive in the long run. Our findings justify a system of graduated marginal income tax rates adopted in most of the developed countries since the second half of the 19 th century. Keywords: one-sector model, optimal capital income taxation, non-linear tax. JEL classification: E62; H21, H22, O41 Earlier versions have benefitted from discussions with Yili Chien, Jang-Ting Guo and Kevin Lansing. Corresponding address: Been-Lon Chen, the Institute of Economics, Academia Sinica, 128 Academia Road Section 2, Taipei 11529, TAIWAN. Phone: (886-2)27822791 ext. 309; Fax: (886-2)2785-3946; email: bchen@econ.sinica.edu.tw. *Department of Economics, National Taiwan University, 21 Hsu-Chow Road, Taipei 10055, TAIWAN; email: d96323001@ntu.edu.tw.

1 Introduction Capital income is taxed in the US and the tax rate is progressive. Corporate profits in the US are first taxed at a flat rate of 40% at a corporate level. Then, when these profits are distributed as dividends, the income is taxed again at progressive rates from 10% to 35% at the household level. In fact, most developed countries have adopted comprehensive income tax systems with graduated marginal tax rates that date back as early as the second half of the 19 th century. 1 With progressive income taxes in most of the developed countries, an important question in tax policy analysis is whether it is optimal to tax capital income. In an infinite-lived representative-agent model with only linear capital and labor income taxes, Chamley (1986) and Judd (1985) found that, in the long run, the optimal capital tax should be zero. 2 The purpose of our paper is to show that, in the same model, if there is an income tax system with progressive capital income taxes, a positive capital tax is optimal in the long run. Our result is not only in sharp contrast to the zero capital tax result of Chamley (1986) and Judd (1985), but also particularly lends support to a system of graduated marginal income tax rates adopted in most of the developed countries since the second half of the 19 th century. Our result is understood as follows. In the long run, the Ramsey planner chooses capital such that the time-preference rate equals the post-tax marginal product of capital, which includes post-tax returns to capital, plus gains in utility from increases in capital income tax revenues adjusted by the social shadow price of capital, minus losses in utility from decreases in post-tax returns to capital due to progressive tax rates adjusted by the social shadow price of capital. Moreover, in the long run the household chooses capital such that the time-preference rate equals the post-tax marginal product of capital from the household s perspective, which includes only post-tax returns to capital. For the Ramsey planner s choice to be consistent with the household s choice, gains in utility from increases in capital income tax revenues minus losses in utility from decreases in post-tax returns to capital due to progressive tax rates must be zero. In the case of linear capital income tax rates, there is no loss of utility from decreases in post-tax returns to capital arising from progressive tax rates and thus gains in utility from increases in capital income tax revenues must be zero, thereby implying a zero capital tax in the long run. Yet, in the case of progressive capital tax rates, there is a loss in utility due to decreases in post-tax returns to capital arising from progressive tax rates. In this case, under a zero capital tax rate, if the schedule of the capital income tax rate is sufficiently progressive, the gain in utility from increases in capital income tax 1 According to Saez (2013), the German states such as Prussia and Saxony introduced the modern income tax during the second half of the 19th century, Japan in 1887, the UK in 1909, the US in 1913 and France in 1914. 2 Several studies revisited the issue by relaxing key assumptions and proved the zero capital tax result to be robust. See Lucas (1990), Jones et al (1993, 1997), Chari et al. (1994), Chari and Kehoe (1999) and Atkeson et al. (1999). 1

revenues is smaller than the loss in utility due to decreases in post-tax returns to capital arising from progressive tax rates. Then, the post-tax marginal product of capital from the Ramsey planner s perspective is smaller than its counterpart from the household s perspective. As a result, the modified golden rule condition indicates that the level of capital chosen by the Ramsey planner is smaller than the level of capital chosen by the household and there is over-accumulation of capital from the social perspective. An increase in capital income tax rates enlarges the increase in income tax revenues and decreases the loss in utility due to decreases in post-tax returns to capital arising from progressive tax rates. Therefore, it is optimal to tax capital income. Our paper is valuable as it justifies a positive capital tax even if there are no inherent distortions in an economy. Existing infinite-lived representative-agent models relied on inherent distortions to obtain a positive flat capital tax. 3 To the best of our knowledge, the only exceptions are Lansing (1999), Chen and Lu (2013) and Lu and Chen (2013). First, Lansing (1999) studied the Judd (1985) model and found a long-run positive capital tax, but his result requires a logarithmic capitalists utility and a zero government debt issue. Next, in a two-sector model with physical and human capital, Chen and Lu (2013) showed that the long-run capital tax is positive, but their result involves a specific learning technology wherein agent s learning time and human capital are inseparable as it was in Lucas (1988) and Bond, Wang and Yip (1996), as opposed to the learning technology in Lucas (1990). Finally, in an infinite-lived representative-agent model, Lu and Chen (2013) also found a long-run positive capital tax, but their result is obtained under a fixed share of government expenditure in output as opposed to fixed government expenditure. Moreover, these three existing models all study linear capital and labor income taxes. Our model contributes to these existing studies in that it obtains a positive capital income tax rate without relying on any one assumption of a zero debt issue, a particular form of preferences and technologies, and a fixed share of government expenditure in output. 4 Our paper also add values to existing models that explored optimal progressive capital income taxes put forth by Saez (2013), Conesa et al. (2009) and Farhi et al. (2012). First, Saez (2013) analyzed optimal progressive capital income taxation in an infinite-horizon heterogeneous-agent model and found that progressive capital income taxation is more effective than linear taxation to redistribute wealth. Our model is important in that it yields a positive capital tax in the long run, but the Saez model 3 For infinite-lived representative-agent models that found positive optimal capital taxes based on inherent distortions, see Guo and Lansing (1999) and Chen (2007) which incorporated market imperfections and productive public capital, and Aiyagari (1995) and Chamley (2001) which considered credit constraints. 4 Another strand of the literature has used overlapping generations (OLG) models to study optimal capital income taxes. In the OLG model without bequests, when taxes are linear, capital taxes are in generally positive in the long-run, simply because capital accumulation is due uniquely to life-cycle savings for retirement. See Atkinson and Sandmo (1980), Garriga (2001) and Erosa and Gervais (2002). 2

retains the long-run vanishing capital tax result as in Chamley (1986) and Judd (1985). 5 Next, in an OLG model with linear capital and progressive labor income taxes wherein agents are heterogeneous in different initial endowment and abilities, Conesa et al. (2009) uncovered that the optimal capital tax is positive when there are borrowing constraints. Our model augments values to Conesa et al. (2009) in that it finds optimal progressive capital income taxes without assuming heterogeneous agents and borrowing constraints. Finally, in another OLG model with non-linear taxation of labor and capital income and political economy constraints, Farhi et al. (2012) discovered that it is optimal to tax a progressive capital income tax when policies are not committed, but the capital income tax is zero with a non-linear tax on labor income when policies are fully committed. Our model adds values to Farhi et al. (2012) in that we find a progressive capital income tax when policies are fully committed. Moreover, all these three papers introduce heterogeneous agents and there is a tension between equity and efficiency of capital accumulation. 6 Even though the efficiency of capital accumulation is the only tension in our model, we find that a positive progressive capital tax is optimal. Finally, we also study a quantitative version of our model that is calibrated to the system of progressive capital and labor income taxes in the US with initial average capital and labor income tax rates equal to those in the current tax code. We find that if the tax schedule is sufficiently progressive, the optimal capital tax rate is positive. In the baseline parameterization with a 30% average capital tax rate and a 20% average labor tax rate in the US during 1960-2007, our revenue-neutral factor income tax incidence exercises indicate that the optimal income tax features a slightly decreasing average capital income tax rate and a largely decreasing average labor income tax rate. Such a tax reform increases consumption, labor supply and capital accumulation and lead to a considerable welfare gain that is larger than those obtained in existing literature. By changing the degree of the tax progressivity, we find that the optimal capital tax rate is increasing in the degree of the tax progressivity. We organize this paper as follows. In Section 2, we set up a model with non-linear factor income tax schedules and analyze households optimizations. In Section 3, we study the optimal factor income tax incidence in the Ramsey second-best problem. Finally, concluding remarks are offered in Section 4. References 5 There are infinite-lived agent models that incorporated progressive income taxes but did not analyze optimal capital taxes. See Carroll and Young (2009) which studied non-degenerated long-run distribution of capital holdings in a heterogeneous-agent model. See also representative-agent models by Guo and Lansing (1998) which explored the effect of the tax progressivity on the dynamic stability and by Li and Sarte (2004) which analyzed the effect of the tax progressivity on long-run economic growth. 6 See also the heterogeneous-agent model by Benabou (2002) that constructed a model with human capital, instead of physical capital, and studied non-linear taxation of income and the heterogeneous-agent model by Farhi et al. (2012) that explored the related issue of non-linear estate taxation. 3

Aiyagari, S.R. (1995) Optimal capital income taxation with incomplete markets, borrowing constraint, and constant discounting. Journal of Political Economy 103, 1158-1175. Atkeson, A., V.V. Chari and P.J. Kehoe (1999) Taxing capital income: a bad idea. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 23, 3-17. Atkinson, A.B. and A. Sandmo (1980) Welfare implications of the taxation of savings. Economic Journal 90, 529-549. Benabou, R. (2002) Tax and education policy in a heterogeneous-agent economy: what levels of redistribution maximize growth and efficiency. Econometrica 70, 481 517. Bond, E.W., P. Wang and C.K. Yip (1996) A general two sector model of endogenous growth with human and physical capital: balanced growth and transitional dynamics. Journal of Economic Theory 68, 149-173. Carroll, D.R. and E.R. Young (2009) The stationary wealth distribution under progressive taxation. Review of Economic Dynamics 12, 469-478. Chamley, C. (1986) Optimal taxation of capital income in general equilibrium with infinite lives. Econometrica 54, 607-622. Chamley, C. (2001) Capital income taxation, wealth distribution and borrowing constraints. Journal of Public Economics 79, 55 69. Chari, V.V. and P.J. Kehoe (1999) Optimal fiscal and monetary policy. In: Taylor, J.B., Woodford, M. (Eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics 1C. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, North-Holland, 1671-1745. Chari, V.V., L.J. Christiano and P.J. Kehoe (1994) Optimal fiscal policy in a business cycle model. Journal of Political Economy 102, 617-652. Chen, B.L. (2007) Factor taxation and labor supply in a dynamic one-sector growth model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 31, 3941-3964. Chen, B.L. and C.H. Lu (2013) Optimal factor tax incidence in two-sector human capital-based models. Journal of Public Economics 97, 75-94. Conesa, J.C. and D. Krueger (2006) On the optimal progressivity of the income tax code. Journal of Monetary Economics 53, 1425-1450. Conesa, J.C., S. Kitao and D. Krueger (2009) Taxing capital? Not a bad idea after all! American Economic Review 99, 25-48. Erosa, A. and M. Gervais (2002) Optimal taxation in life cycle economies. Journal of Economic Theory 105, 338-369. Farhi, E. and I. Werning (2012) Capital taxation: quantitative explorations of the inverse Euler equation. Journal of Political Economy 120, 398-445. Farhi, E., C. Sleet, I. Werning and S. Yeltekin (2012) Non-linear capital taxation without commitment 4

Review of Economic Studies 79, 1469-1493. Garriga, C. (2001) Optimal fiscal policy in overlapping generations models. working papers in Economic 66, Universitat de Barcelona. Espai de Recerca en Economia January 2001. Guo, J.T. and K.J. Lansing (1998) Indeterminacy and Stabilization Policy. Journal of Economic Theory 82, 481-490. Guo, J.T. and K.J. Lansing (1999) Optimal taxation of capital income with imperfectly competitive product markets. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 23, 967-995. Jones, L.E., R.E. Manuelli and P.E. Rossi (1993) Optimal taxation in models of endogenous growth. Journal of Political Economy 101, 485-517. Jones, L.E., R.E. Manuelli and P.. Rossi (1997) On the optimal taxation of capital income. Journal of Economic Theory 73, 93-117. Judd, K.L. (1985) Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model. Journal of Public Economics 28, 59-83. King, R.G. and S.T. Rebelo (1999) Restructuring real business cycles. Handbook of Macroeconomics 1, 927-1006. Lansing, K.J. (1999) Optimal redistributive capital taxation in a neoclassical growth model. Journal of Public Economics 73, 423-453. Li, W. and P.-D. Sarte (2004) Progressive Taxation and Long-Run Growth. American Economic Review 94, 1705-1716. Ljungqvist, L. and T. Sargent (2004), Recursive Macroeconomic Theory, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press. Lu, C.H. and B.L. Chen (2013) Optimal capital taxation in a neoclassical growth model. Journal of Public Economic Theory (forthcoming). Lucas, R.E., Jr. (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics 22, 3-42. Lucas, R.E. Jr. (1990) Supply-side economics: an analytical review, Oxford Economic Papers 42, 293-316. McDaniel, C. (2007) Average tax rates on consumption, investment, labor and capital in the OECD 1950-2003. Manuscript, Arizona State Univ. Saez, E. (2013) Optimal progressive capital income taxes in the infinite horizon model. Journal of Public Economics 97, 61-74. 5