Accelerating Deflation and Monetary Policy

Similar documents
On Abenomics and the Japanese Economy. Motoshige Itoh Member, Council on Economic and Fiscal Policy and Professor, University of Tokyo

The Battle Against Deflation:

The Government Deficit and the Financial Crisis

Japan Economic Recovery from the lost Decade: Presented by: Cicik Yuniarsih, Gek Hsien Tang & Yosamartha. Towards Stability or Volatility

Japan's Growth Potential and Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing

Investment Newsletter September 2012

Financial Strains and the Zero Lower Bound: the Japanese Experience by Mitsuhiro Fukao, Keio University March 2, 2003

Japan s Public Pension: The Great Vulnerability to Deflation

b. Financial innovation and/or financial liberalization (the elimination of restrictions on financial markets) can cause financial firms to go on a

International Money and Banking: 14. Real Interest Rates, Lower Bounds and Quantitative Easing

Observation. January 18, credit availability, credit

The yellow highlighted areas are bear markets with NO recession.

Monthly Report of Prospects for Japan's Economy

Why will the exit from the current monetary policy cause losses to the BOJ? Since the beginning of QQE in April 2013, the BOJ has supplied the monetar

FISCAL POLICY* Chapt er. Key Concepts

Lessons from Japan: How Abenomics Can Provide Solutions for Advanced Countries

SME Finance in Japan

How Successful is China s Economic Rebalancing?*

Deflation? Yes. Deflationary spiral? No.

The Bank of Japan s Experience with Non-Traditional Monetary Policy. October 2010 Kazuo Ueda The University of Tokyo

Indonesia: Changing patterns of financial intermediation and their implications for central bank policy

Sustainability of Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing

International Monetary and Financial Committee

Ryuzo Miyao: Economic activity and prices in Japan and monetary policy

Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices (October 2017)

Ensuring Escape from the Deflationary Spiral and to Again Increase Consumption Tax

THE NEW ECONOMY RECESSION: ECONOMIC SCORECARD 2001

CRS Report for Congress

APPENDIX: Country analyses

Summary of Opinions at the Monetary Policy Meeting 1,2 on December 17 and 18, 2015

Financial Market Outlook & Strategy: Stocks Bottoming On Track to Recovery. Near-term Risks

Antonio Fazio: Overview of global economic and financial developments in first half 2004

Normalizing Monetary Policy

University of Toronto July 15, 2016 ECO 209Y L0101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2

Haruhiko Kuroda: Quantitative and qualitative monetary easing and the financial system toward realisation of a vigorous financial system

Ghana: Implications of the Rising Interest Costs to Government

ECONOMY. The High-Growth Era. Japan s economy in an era of globalization

Joseph S Tracy: A strategy for the 2011 economic recovery

Economic Activity, Prices, and Monetary Policy in Japan

Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices (April 2017) Summary

Deflation, the Labor Market, and QQE

Japan s Economy: Monthly Review

Data Brief. Dangerous Trends: The Growth of Debt in the U.S. Economy

The U.S. Economy After the Great Recession: America s Deleveraging and Recovery Experience

Haruhiko Kuroda: Overcoming deflation and quantitative and qualitative monetary easing

Summary of Opinions at the Monetary Policy Meeting 1,2 on June 15 and 16, 2017

OECD Economic Outlook. Randall S. Jones Head, Japan/Korea Desk 25 November 2014

Projections for outstanding government debt in Japan

Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices (January 2019)

Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices (October 2014)

Haruhiko Kuroda: How to overcome deflation

Outlook 2013: China. Growth expected to accelerate again

Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices

Outlook for the Japanese Economy in 2007

Masaaki Shirakawa: The transition from high growth to stable growth Japan s experience and implications for emerging economies

Fiscal 2010 Economic Outlook and Basic Stance for Economic and Fiscal Management

Haruhiko Kuroda: Moving forward Japan s economy under Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing

Summary of Opinions at the Monetary Policy Meeting 1,2 on October 30 and 31, 2017

Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices (January 2018)

Summary of Opinions at the Monetary Policy Meeting 1,2 on April 26 and 27, 2018

Japan's Economy and Monetary Policy

Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices (July 2018)

Japan s Economic Outlook No. 190 Update (Summary)

Lecture 12: Too Big to Fail and the US Financial Crisis

Economic Activity, Prices, and Monetary Policy in Japan

Reconciling FOMC Forecasts and Forward Guidance. Mickey D. Levy Blenheim Capital Management

THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND MONETARY POLICY Macroeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.)

ECONOMY REPORT - CHINESE TAIPEI

CONTENTS FACT BOOK 2014 Overview Ⅰ Economy and Market Trends Ⅱ Securities Industry Overview Statistical Data

Debt Sustainability in Japan. Jun Saito Cabinet Office, Japan December 9 th, 2011 at Asia Europe Economic Forum Conference Seoul, Korea

Economic & Capital Market Outlook Fourth Quarter, 2018

7 January Affordability of housing

Provisional Translation Economic Outlook for FY2005 and Basic Economic and Fiscal Management Measures

Table 1: Economic Growth Measures

Japan's Economy and Monetary Policy

Economic and Financial Developments and Monetary Policy in Japan

University of Toronto December 3, 2010 ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY. Term Test #2 L0101 L0301 L0401 M 2-4 W 2-4 R 2-4

Summary of Opinions at the Monetary Policy Meeting 1,2 on September 20 and 21, 2017

BOJ's communication strategy of policy normalization

Price stability means that the general price level in an economy increases at a low, stable and expected rate. [1]

JAPAN S ECONOMY FROM BOOM TO BUST

ECONOMY. The High-Growth Era. Japan s economy in an era of globalization

Japan's Economy and Monetary Policy: Toward Overcoming Deflation

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast March 2015

Gundlach: The Goldilocks Era is Over

READ CAREFULLY Failure to read has been a problem on the exams

Objectives for Chapter 24: Monetarism (Continued) Chapter 24: The Basic Theory of Monetarism (Continued) (latest revision October 2004)

Risks from Extending the QQE Policy. Bank of Japan s JGB Purchases to reach Limits in June 2017

History Repeats Itself in Different Hues Japan vs. United States December 19, Highlights of Japan s Economic History

Nobuyasu Atago Chief Forecaster, Japan Center for Economic Research

Summary of Opinions at the Monetary Policy Meeting 1,2 on March 14 and 15, 2019

Key Points of Today's Policy Decisions

Summary of Opinions at the Monetary Policy Meeting 1,2 on July 30 and 31, 2018

Market Insight Economy and Asset Classes December Oil Prices Downtrending: The Real Global Economic Stimulus

Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices (April 2010)

Reforming Social Security in Japan: Is NDC the Answer?

Five key investment themes for 2015

Upcoming Changes in Japanese Society and the Future Shape of the Nation

Monetary and Fiscal Policy During the Great Recession: Old Challenges and New Insights

Expansions (periods of. positive economic growth)

Transcription:

Accelerating Deflation and Monetary Policy Summary Deflation is proceeding at an accelerated pace due to the widening deflationary GDP gap. Eliminating deflation through economic stimulus by increasing the issuance of government bonds, or an increased amount of buying operations by the Bank of Japan (BOJ) is very difficult in this economic environment. We need to look at new and creative measures such as the buying operations of stocks or real estate by BOJ. Further, if this also fails to eliminate deflation, then we will need to consider some more powerful measures such as levying a tax on cash and deposits (in effect a negative interest rate policy). According to Japan s GDP (gross domestic product) deflator -- an indicator of the price changes in the economy as a whole -- price levels began to decline from about 1994. It has been close to ten years since then. If we take away the effects of the hikes in the consumption tax, then the GDP deflator has fallen by a total of about 10% in this time. In this financial report, we estimate how deflation may accelerate in the future by finding the function between the GDP gap (difference between actual GDP and potential GDP, if the former is lower than the other, than the gap is deflationary) that is the cause of deflation, and price changes. Then, we examine the monetary policies that were implemented after the burst of the economic bubble to find why the easing of monetary policy by the Bank of Japan (BOJ) has been unable to stem deflation. Deflationary Gap, Now about 25 trillion yen We examined the relationship between price changes and the GDP Gap in the 1990s, and we found that even under the same environment of a deflationary gap, prices were rising in the first half of the 1990s and falling in the second half, and there was a difference in the acceleration of price changes. We separated the data into periods when price changes were positive and when they were negative to conduct our estimates. We found that although in both periods the deflationary gap was of the same scale, the price changes in the latter period accelerated at a rate of about one-fourth that of the first period. This can be explained by the fact that for companies with excess labor, it is easier to lower the rate of wage increase rather than expand the rate of wage decrease. As we see in Figure 1, after the GDP gap marked the largest level we have 1

measured here during the bubble period at an inflationary gap of 2.3%, it has been on a steady declining trend, and it is now at a 7.0 percentage points lower level than the peak. The size of the deflationary gap is now 4.8% and amounts to 25 trillion yen. In theory, if we were to fill this gap funded by a tax cut, then we would need a permanent tax cut of at least the scale of the gap itself, which is 25 trillion yen. In the current situation where national tax revenue is only about 42 trillion yen, this would be impossible. According to the results of our forecast of price changes, the GDP deflator will continue to fall with the growing GDP gap. In the October-December quarter of 2004, prices will fall over the previous quarter at an annualized rate of 3.5%. This current deflation is quite severe, and the rate of deflation will continue to accelerate under current circumstances. Even if the government were able to fill the gap completely with fiscal spending, this would only result in stopping the rate of acceleration of deflation, and actually eliminating deflation is extremely difficult. Figure 1. GDP Gap Forecast 2

Money supply measures ineffective due to the Liquidity Trap Since July of 1991, the BOJ has lowered interest rates multiple times, implemented the zero interest rate policy in 1999, and in 2001 went as far as to adopt quantitative easing. Due to this quantitative easing measure, private financial institutions have increased the outstanding balances in current accounts they keep with the BOJ. This has risen from the 4 trillion yen it had been previously to 20 trillion yen. However, although the monetary base (the total of cash and BOJ current account) has greatly increased through quantitative easing, lending has not expanded, and nominal GDP continues to decline. In Figure 2, we see the relationship between the monetary base and short-term interest rates. We observe that the monetary base as a share of nominal GDP was about 7-9% before the zero interest rate policy, but this has grown under the zero interest rate polity and while nominal interest rates have fallen to zero, the ratio has continued to increase and is now about 18%. Japan s economy is in a liquidity trap whereby even when money supply is increased, it does not lead to declining interest rates, and there is little effect on the economy. Even if the nominal interest rates are at zero, if nominal GDP continues to decline due to deflation, the bad loan situation will become worse as the debt burden of companies increase relative to the sales revenue they earn. Moreover, if short-term interest rates fall to zero, the effects of conventional buying operations of short-term assets will deteriorate. Even if through market operations, short-term government bonds with zero interest rates are exchanged for bank notes with zero interest rates, this will not result in any stimulus for the economy. Quantitative easing from increasing the buying operations of long-term government bonds may have lowered long-term interest rates slightly, but the effect of this is almost at its limit. In order to come up with a countermeasure against deflation, we need to correctly assess the current environment of the Japanese economy. The authors believe that currently the Japanese economy is in a cash, deposit and government bond bubble. People are selling their real assets in real estate and stocks, and moving their funds into cash, deposits and government bonds whose values are guaranteed by the government. However, the creditworthiness of the government in question is declining as the fiscal deficit balloons. Although the government may be heading towards bankruptcy if the situation is not corrected, people and companies continue to depend on the creditworthiness of the government. This indeed is a bubble. The first way of resolving this bubble situation is for the BOJ to supply large quantities of cash (the subject of speculation), and buy large amounts of stocks and real estate that are currently being sold off. In this serious deflationary environment, we believe that the BOJ should be conducting buying operations of about 5 trillion 3

yen per month in Exchange Traded Funds (ETFs), and Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs). In one year, they would be buying the equivalent of one quarter of the market value of the stock market including REITs. Buying operations of the BOJ to buy stocks and real estate will, naturally, push up the stock and land prices in the short term. An increase in stock and land prices will improve the balance sheets of corporations and households, and will enhance their collateral for loans. Moreover, it will make the cleaning up the bad loans much easier. If the people can realize the meaninglessness of continuing to depend on the credit of the government that continues to have massive budget deficits, the deflation will end. However, so long as people keep their money in cash, deposits and government bonds, a deflationary bubble will begin again. If despite large-scale buying operations of stocks and real estate after one year do not bring about any results in eliminating deflation, then the more powerful negative interest rate policy is necessary. Balances of financial assets whose principals are guaranteed by the government such as cash, yen deposits, government bonds, government-backed bonds, local government bonds, postal savings, and postal life insurance should be taxed at a rate of the deflation rate plus a margin. If the government announces that it will tax financial assets and keep their promise as many times as it takes to end deflation, then assets will be transferred to stocks, real estate, corporate bonds, loans, foreign currencies and durable goods that are not taxed. Banks as well will begin to actively lend more as funds that are kept in current accounts, at the Bank of Japan will be taxed. If funds are taken out of cash and government bonds and into real assets and goods and services, then the economy will expand. In order to tax bank notes, they would have to be reprinted and a fee must be levied to be exchanged. The total taxable amount would exceed 1,500 trillion yen, comprised of 600 trillion yen in deposits, 240 trillion yen in postal savings, and 120 trillion yen in postal life insurance. For the current situation, where the deflation rate is over 2%, we would need a tax rate of slightly over this in the 2-3% range. Tax revenue would exceed 30 trillion yen. Since cash would also be taxable, there would be no need to freeze deposits. However, a tax on all financial assets including cash would invite very strong resistance from the public. This will not be successfully implemented unless politicians clearly understand the huge risks associated with letting deflation continue, and they have the strong leadership to convince the public that this measure is necessary. 4

Figure 2. Monetary Base and Short-tern Interest Rates lowering of interest rates begins 91Q3 91Q 86Q1 95Q4 88Q2 99Q1 (zero interest rate policy implemented) 2001Q1 quantitative easing policy implemented 2002Q Interest rates rise significantly during period of deflation elimination. If we can eliminate deflation and the inflation rate rises to 2%, then long-term interest rates will rise by over 4%. As a result of this, the price of the ten-year government bond will fall by about 40%. Also, the government s interest expenses will also increases rapidly. Once the government realizes the elimination of deflation, then at that stage, they must implement a large-scale tax increase. The Bank of Japan as well, must get back its base money that has been flooding the market in its selling operations to prevent inflation from accelerating. The reason for this is, as we saw in Figure 2, when interest rates are in the 3-5% range, the demand for base money is about 8% of GDP (about 40 trillion yen). There is a grave risk that if the Bank of Japan conducts massive buying operations of government bonds in the 100 trillions of yen, the credit of the BOJ may be seriously compromised. For example, let us take the case where the Bank of Japan is to increase its holding of long-term government bonds in the amount of 50% of the amount outstanding in the market, say about 150 trillion yen. If the long-term interest rates rise by 5%, then the holdings of the BOJ s government bonds will mark a loss of about 60 trillion yen. Thus, even if the BOJ were to sell all of the government bonds that it bought, it will be unable to collect on the excess current 5

deposits at the BOJ, and they will be forced to collect them through the issuance of bills sold (interest bearing documents of obligation) (Table 1). Table 1. Bank of Japan s Balance Sheet on a Rising Interest Rate Before interest rates rise: (Using as at end of January 2003 figures, if the BOJ buys 150 trillion yen of long-term government bonds from the market) Assets Liabilities Long-term government bonds 57 + 150 Bank Notes 70 Short-term government bonds 26 Current Accounts 20 + 150 Other assets 42 Other liabilities 33 Capital 2 Total 275 Total 275 Interest rates rise 5%. (After government bond prices decline, BOJ absorbs excess current account through selling operations) Assets Liabilities Long-term government bonds 0 Bank Notes 35 Short-term government bonds 0 Current Accounts 5 Other assets 0 Other liabilities 14 Capital -54 Total 0 Total 0 Units: Source: Trillions of yen Bank of Japan Accounts, Bank of Japan If this is the case then the assets of the BOJ will be zero, the liabilities will be bank bills sold that are interest bearing and bank notes and a deficit will occur on the interest payments and expenses incurred. The BOJ will then have to depend on the government to provide them with subsidies every year. Compared to this, if the BOJ conducts buying operations in stocks and real estate, then when the economy is finally out of deflation, the Bank of Japan will have a huge profit, and the credit of the BOJ will be enhanced. So long as elimination deflation results in a higher interest rate, then for both the BOJ and the government, depending on a further issuance of government bonds and further buying operations of the BOJ to eliminate deflation is a mistaken policy to take that will lead to serious problems in the future. 6